Jump to content

Rare disaster: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Model: Fixing line feed in ref publisher & adding archive parameters to ref for dead link
History: ref fmt, sp
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile web edit Advanced mobile edit
 
(15 intermediate revisions by 11 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Large and rare economic collapse}}
{{economics sidebar}}
{{Economics sidebar}}
A '''rare disaster''' is an economic event that is infrequent and large in magnitude, having a negative effect on an economy. Rare disasters are important because they provide an explanation of the [[equity premium puzzle]], the behavior of [[interest rates]], and other economic phenomena.
In [[economics]], a '''rare disaster''' is a [[economic collapse|collapse]] that is infrequent and large in magnitude, having a negative effect on an [[economy]]. Rare disasters are important because they provide an explanation of the [[equity premium puzzle]], the behavior of [[interest rates]], and other [[economic history|economic phenomena]].


The parameters for a rare disaster are a substantial drop in [[GDP]] and at least a 10% decrease in [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]]. Examples include financial disasters: [[The Great Depression]] and the [[Asian Financial Crisis]]; wars: [[World War I]], [[World War II]] and regional conflicts; epidemics: Influenza outbreaks and the Asian Flu; and weather events: Tsunamis and Earthquakes; however, any event that has a substantial impact on GDP and consumption could be considered a rare disaster.
The parameters for a rare disaster are a substantial drop in [[GDP]] and at least a 10% decrease in [[consumption (economics)|consumption]]. Examples include [[financial crisis|financial disaster]]s: the [[Great Depression]] and the [[1997 Asian financial crisis]]; wars: [[World War I]], [[World War II]], and regional conflicts; [[epidemic]]s: influenza outbreaks and the Asian Flu; weather events; and [[earthquake]]s and [[tsunami]]s; however, any event that has a substantial impact on GDP and consumption could be considered a rare disaster.


The idea was first proposed by [[Rietz]] in 1988,<ref name="The equity risk premium a solution">{{cite journal|last1=Rietz|first1=Thomas|title=The equity risk premium a solution|journal=Journal of Monetary Economics|date=1988|volume=22|issue=1|pages=117–131|url=http://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/0304393288901729|doi=10.1016/0304-3932(88)90172-9}}</ref> as a way to explain the equity premium puzzle. Since then, other economists have added to and strengthened the idea with evidence, but many economists are still skeptical of the theory.
The idea was first proposed by [[Rietz]] in 1988,<ref name="The equity risk premium a solution">{{cite journal|last1=Rietz|first1=Thomas|title=The equity risk premium a solution|journal=Journal of Monetary Economics|date=1988|volume=22|issue=1|pages=117–131|doi=10.1016/0304-3932(88)90172-9}}</ref> as a way to explain the equity premium puzzle. Since then, other economists have added to and strengthened the idea with evidence, but many economists are still skeptical of the theory.


==Model==
==Model==
The model set forth by [[Robert Barro|Barro]] is based upon the Lucas's fruit tree model of asset pricing with exogenous, stochastic production. The economy is closed, the amount of trees is fixed, output equals consumption ( {{math|<VAR>A</VAR> <sub>''t'' + 1</sub> {{=}} <VAR>C</VAR> <sub>''t''</sub>}} ) and there is no investment or depreciation. As ( {{math|<VAR>A</VAR> <sub>''t'' + 1</sub>}} ) is the output of all the trees in the economy and ( <math>{P_t}</math> ) is the price of the periods fruit (the equity claim). The equation below shows the gross return on the fruit tree in one period.<ref name= "Barro10">{{cite web|last=Barro|first=Robert|title= Rare Disasters and Asset Markets in the Twentieth Century|url=http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/files/equity%20premium%2012-1-05.pdf|publisher=The Quarterly Journal of Economics|pages =10–20.|work=|accessdate=2009-03-09|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100709152623/http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/files/equity%20premium%2012-1-05.pdf |archive-date=9 July 2010 |dead-url=true}}</ref>
The model set forth by [[Robert Barro|Barro]] is based upon the Lucas's fruit tree model of asset pricing with exogenous, stochastic production. The economy is closed, the number of trees is fixed, output equals consumption ( {{math|<VAR>A</VAR> <sub>''t'' + 1</sub> {{=}} <VAR>C</VAR> <sub>''t''</sub>}} ) and there is no investment or depreciation. As ( {{math|<VAR>A</VAR> <sub>''t'' + 1</sub>}} ) is the output of all the trees in the economy and ( <math>{P_t}</math> ) is the price of the periods fruit (the equity claim). The equation below shows the gross return on the fruit tree in one period.<ref name= "Barro10">{{cite web|last=Barro|first=Robert|title= Rare Disasters and Asset Markets in the Twentieth Century|url=http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/files/equity%20premium%2012-1-05.pdf|publisher=The Quarterly Journal of Economics|pages= 10–20|accessdate=2009-03-09|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100709152623/http://www.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/barro/files/equity%20premium%2012-1-05.pdf |archive-date=9 July 2010 |url-status=dead}}</ref>

:<math>R=\frac{A_{t+1}}{P_{t1}}</math>
:<math>R=\frac{A_{t+1}}{P_{t1}}</math>


Line 21: Line 21:
The type ω (<math>\tilde{v}_{t+1}</math>) models low probability disasters and (<math>\tilde{u}_{t+1}</math>) is a random iid variable. They are assumed to be independent so they are interchangeable in the equation. Then from the above equation, the magnitude of the contraction from (<math>\tilde{v}_{t+1}</math>) is determined by the following equation.
The type ω (<math>\tilde{v}_{t+1}</math>) models low probability disasters and (<math>\tilde{u}_{t+1}</math>) is a random iid variable. They are assumed to be independent so they are interchangeable in the equation. Then from the above equation, the magnitude of the contraction from (<math>\tilde{v}_{t+1}</math>) is determined by the following equation.


:<math>\begin{cases}
:<math>\begin{cases}
1 & (e^{-p})\mbox{ no disaster} \\
1 & (e^{-p})\mbox{ no disaster} \\
1-b & (1-e^{-p})\mbox{ disaster} \\
1-b & (1-e^{-p})\mbox{ disaster} \\
\end{cases}</math>
\end{cases}</math>


Line 31: Line 31:
Since Rietz and Barro, the rare disaster framework can be used to explain many events in finance and economics.
Since Rietz and Barro, the rare disaster framework can be used to explain many events in finance and economics.


===The Equity Premium===
===Equity premium===
Much of the [[equity premium puzzle]] can be explained by the rare disaster scenarios proposed by Barro and Rietz. The basic reasoning is that if people are aware that rare disasters (i.e. the Great Depression or World War I and World War II) may occur, but the disaster never occurs during their lives, then the equity premium will appear high.
Much of the [[equity premium puzzle]] can be explained by the rare disaster scenarios proposed by Barro and Rietz. The basic reasoning is that if people are aware that rare disasters (i.e. the Great Depression or World War I and World War II) may occur, but the disaster never occurs during their lives, then the equity premium will appear high.


Barro and subsequent economists have provided historical evidence to support this claim. Using this evidence, Barro shows that rare disasters occur frequently and in large magnitude, in economies around the world from a period from the mid-19th century to the present day.
Barro and subsequent economists have provided historical evidence to support this claim. Using this evidence, Barro shows that rare disasters occur frequently and in large magnitude, in economies around the world from a period from the mid-19th century to the present day.


Further, the evidence shows that in the long run the risk premium is around 5.0% in most countries. However, if when looking at specific periods of time this premium may be higher or lower. For example, if a data set of the period of the Great Depression is observed, then the equity premium will be about 0.4%, because the Great Depression was a rare disaster.<ref name="Barro10"/>
Further, the evidence shows that in the long run the risk premium is around 5.0% in most countries. However, when looking at specific periods of time this premium may be higher or lower. For example, if a data set of the period of the Great Depression is observed, then the equity premium will be about 0.4%, because the Great Depression was a rare disaster.<ref name="Barro10"/>


===Risk-Free Interest Rate Behavior===
===Risk-free interest rate behavior===
[[File:riskfree.png|260px|right|thumb]]
[[File:riskfree.png|260px|right|thumb]]
The [[risk-free interest rate]] (the interest received on fixed income, like bonds issued by extremely safe entities, typically governments) may also be explained by rare disasters. Using data in the United States, the rare disaster model shows that the risk-free rate falls by a large margin (from 0.127 to 0.035) when a rare disaster with the probability of 0.017 is introduced into the data set.<ref name="Barro10"/>


Furthermore, Barro defends the criticisms about the behavior of the risk free rate raised by Mehra with respect to the Great Depression and events such as dropping the Atom Bomb in World War II. He reasons that two effects go into people's expectation of rare disasters-the probability of a rare disaster and the [[probability of default]]. In an event that has the possibility of nuclear war (like the Cuban Missile Crisis or World War II), the probability of a disaster would rise and therefore, decrease interest rates. However, the probability of government default on bonds also increases, because of the possible destruction of countries, which raises the rate on bonds. These two forces counteract which leads to ambiguity. As shown left with the risk free rate rising before and falling after the Great Depression, then falling initially during World War II and then rising afterward.<ref name="Barro10"/>
The [[risk-free interest rate]] (the interest received on fixed income, like bonds) may also be explained by rare disasters. Using data in the United States, the rare disaster model shows that the risk-free rate falls by a large margin (from .127 to .035) when a rare disaster with the probability of .017 is introduced into the data set.<ref name="Barro10" />

Furthermore, Barro defends the criticisms about the behavior of the risk free rate raised by Mehra with respect to the Great Depression and events such as dropping the Atom Bomb in World War II. He reasons that two effects go into people's expectation of rare disasters-the probability of a rare disaster and the [[probability of default]]. In an event that has the possibility of nuclear war (like the Cuban Missile Crisis or World War II), the probability of a disaster would rise and therefore, decrease interest rates. However, the probability of government default on bonds also increases, because of the possible destruction of countries, which raises the rate on bonds. These to forces counteract and lead to ambiguity. As shown left with the risk free rate before and falling after the Great Depression, then falling initially during World War II and then rising afterward.<ref name="Barro10"/>


==History==
==History==
[[Edward C. Prescott]] and [[Rajnish Mehra]] first proposed the Equity Premium Puzzle in 1985. In 1988, Rietz<ref name="The equity risk premium a solution"/> suggested that large and infrequent economic shocks could explain the equity premium (the premium of securities over fixed income assets). However, it was not deemed feasible at the time, because it seemed that such events were too rare and could not occur in reality.<ref>pp. 2–3</ref> The theory was forgotten until 2005, when [[Robert Barro]] provided evidence of nations from around the world from the 19th and 20th century, showing that these events were possible and have happened. Since his papers, others have submitted different ideas regarding rare disasters' impact on other economic phenomenon.<ref>pp. 4–11</ref> However, many economists remain skeptical of how much rare disasters really explain the equity premium and Mehra still expresses doubt as to the validity of the theory.<ref name="MehraHist">* {{cite web|author=Ranjish Mehra|title=The Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review|url=http://www.academicwebpages.com/preview/mehra/pdf/FIN%200201.pdf|publisher=Foundations and Trends in Finance: 2008 Vol. 2: No 1, pp 1–81.|work=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}</ref>
[[Edward C. Prescott]] and [[Rajnish Mehra]] first proposed the equity premium puzzle in 1985. In 1988, Rietz<ref name="The equity risk premium a solution"/> suggested that large and infrequent economic shocks could explain the equity premium (the premium of equity securities over fixed income assets). However, it was not deemed feasible at the time, because it seemed that such events were too rare and could not occur in reality.<ref>pp. 2–3</ref> The theory was forgotten until 2005, when [[Robert Barro]] provided evidence of nations from around the world from the 19th and 20th century, showing that these events were possible and have happened. Since his papers, others have submitted different ideas regarding rare disasters' impact on other economic phenomenon.<ref>pp. 4–11</ref> However, many economists remain skeptical of how much rare disasters really explain the equity premium and Mehra still expresses doubt as to the validity of the theory.<ref name=MehraHist>{{cite web|author=Rajnish Mehra|title=The Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review|url=http://www.academicwebpages.com/preview/mehra/pdf/FIN%200201.pdf|journal=Foundations and Trends in Finance|date=2008|volume=2|issue=1|pp=1–81|website=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}</ref>


==Controversy==
==Controversy==
Rajnish Mehra was skeptical of Reitz's claim that rare disasters explain the equity premium and real interest rate behavior, because the rare disaster that Rietz had specified had never occurred in the U.S. Rietz suggested 25-97% drops, but this has never happened in the United States. Even if this were true, there are several other flaws regarding his model, parameters,
Rajnish Mehra was skeptical of Reitz's claim that rare disasters explain the equity premium and real interest rate behavior, because the rare disaster that Rietz had specified had never occurred in the U.S. Rietz suggested 25 to 97% drops, but this has never happened in the United States. Even if this were true, there are several other flaws regarding his model, parameters, and supporting evidence. The model Rietz presented did not compensate for a partial default on bond holders due to rapid inflation. Further, the risk aversion parameter was used inconsistently in his analysis. For example, a value of 10 was used to show a 25% drop in consumption, but a value of 1 is used to explain stock returns and consumption. Finally, more historical evidence was said to have been needed to give the theory proper support. For example, the perceived probability of a rare disaster should have been low before the atomic bomb was dropped and must have been higher before the [[Cuban Missile Crisis]] than after. Therefore, real interest rates should have correlated with these events, but they did not. Mehra concluded that Rietz's scenario was far too extreme to resolve the puzzle.<ref name=MehraHist/>
and supporting evidence. The model Rietz presented did not compensate for a partial default on bond holders do due
rapid inflation. Further, the risk aversion in parameter was used inconsistently in his analysis. For example, a
value of 10 was used to show a 25% drop in consumption, but a value of 1 is used to explain stock returns and
consumption. Finally, more historical evidence was said to have been needed to give the theory proper support. For
example, the perceived probability of a rare disaster should have been low before the atomic bomb was dropped and
must have been higher before the [[Cuban Missile Crisis]] than after. Therefore, real interest rates should have
correlated with these events, but they did not. Mehra concluded that Rietz's scenario was far too extreme to
resolve the puzzle.<ref name="MehraHist"/>


==References==
==See also==
*[[Rare events]]


===Notes===
==References==
{{reflist|2}}
{{Reflist}}


===Bibliography===
===Bibliography===
* {{cite web|author=Ranjnish Mehra(2003)|title=The Equity Premium: Why Is It a Puzzle?|url=http://wwwdocs.fce.unsw.edu.au/economics/news/VisitorSeminar/RMehra.pdf|publisher=|work=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}
*{{cite web|author=Rajnish Mehra|date=February 2003|title=The Equity Premium: Why Is It a Puzzle?|url=http://wwwdocs.fce.unsw.edu.au/economics/news/VisitorSeminar/RMehra.pdf|website=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}
* {{cite web|author=New Economist(2005)|title=New Economist on Barro and the Equity Premium Puzzle|url=http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2005/09/new_economist_o.html|publisher=Mehra|work=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}
*{{cite web|author=New Economist|date=September 30, 2005|title=New Economist on Barro and the Equity Premium Puzzle|url=http://economistsview.typepad.com/economistsview/2005/09/new_economist_o.html|publisher=Mehra|website=|accessdate=2009-03-09}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Rare Disasters}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Rare Disasters}}
[[Category:Economic disasters]]
[[Category:Economic collapses]]

Latest revision as of 00:01, 13 March 2024

In economics, a rare disaster is a collapse that is infrequent and large in magnitude, having a negative effect on an economy. Rare disasters are important because they provide an explanation of the equity premium puzzle, the behavior of interest rates, and other economic phenomena.

The parameters for a rare disaster are a substantial drop in GDP and at least a 10% decrease in consumption. Examples include financial disasters: the Great Depression and the 1997 Asian financial crisis; wars: World War I, World War II, and regional conflicts; epidemics: influenza outbreaks and the Asian Flu; weather events; and earthquakes and tsunamis; however, any event that has a substantial impact on GDP and consumption could be considered a rare disaster.

The idea was first proposed by Rietz in 1988,[1] as a way to explain the equity premium puzzle. Since then, other economists have added to and strengthened the idea with evidence, but many economists are still skeptical of the theory.

Model

[edit]

The model set forth by Barro is based upon the Lucas's fruit tree model of asset pricing with exogenous, stochastic production. The economy is closed, the number of trees is fixed, output equals consumption ( A t + 1 = C t ) and there is no investment or depreciation. As ( A t + 1 ) is the output of all the trees in the economy and ( ) is the price of the periods fruit (the equity claim). The equation below shows the gross return on the fruit tree in one period.[2]

In order to model rare disasters, Barro introduces the equation below, which is a stochastic process for aggregate output growth. In the model, there are three types of economic shocks:

a.) Normal iid shocks
b.) Type () disasters which involve sharp contractions in output, but no default on debt.
c.) Type () disasters which involve sharp contractions in output and at least a partial default on debt.

The type ω () models low probability disasters and () is a random iid variable. They are assumed to be independent so they are interchangeable in the equation. Then from the above equation, the magnitude of the contraction from () is determined by the following equation.

In this equation, p is the probability per unit of time that a disaster will occur in each period. If the disaster occurs, b is the factor by which consumption will shrink. The model requires a p that is small and a b that large to correctly model rare disasters. In Barro's analysis, d is also used to deal with the problem of the partial default on bonds.

Applications

[edit]

Since Rietz and Barro, the rare disaster framework can be used to explain many events in finance and economics.

Equity premium

[edit]

Much of the equity premium puzzle can be explained by the rare disaster scenarios proposed by Barro and Rietz. The basic reasoning is that if people are aware that rare disasters (i.e. the Great Depression or World War I and World War II) may occur, but the disaster never occurs during their lives, then the equity premium will appear high.

Barro and subsequent economists have provided historical evidence to support this claim. Using this evidence, Barro shows that rare disasters occur frequently and in large magnitude, in economies around the world from a period from the mid-19th century to the present day.

Further, the evidence shows that in the long run the risk premium is around 5.0% in most countries. However, when looking at specific periods of time this premium may be higher or lower. For example, if a data set of the period of the Great Depression is observed, then the equity premium will be about 0.4%, because the Great Depression was a rare disaster.[2]

Risk-free interest rate behavior

[edit]

The risk-free interest rate (the interest received on fixed income, like bonds issued by extremely safe entities, typically governments) may also be explained by rare disasters. Using data in the United States, the rare disaster model shows that the risk-free rate falls by a large margin (from 0.127 to 0.035) when a rare disaster with the probability of 0.017 is introduced into the data set.[2]

Furthermore, Barro defends the criticisms about the behavior of the risk free rate raised by Mehra with respect to the Great Depression and events such as dropping the Atom Bomb in World War II. He reasons that two effects go into people's expectation of rare disasters-the probability of a rare disaster and the probability of default. In an event that has the possibility of nuclear war (like the Cuban Missile Crisis or World War II), the probability of a disaster would rise and therefore, decrease interest rates. However, the probability of government default on bonds also increases, because of the possible destruction of countries, which raises the rate on bonds. These two forces counteract which leads to ambiguity. As shown left with the risk free rate rising before and falling after the Great Depression, then falling initially during World War II and then rising afterward.[2]

History

[edit]

Edward C. Prescott and Rajnish Mehra first proposed the equity premium puzzle in 1985. In 1988, Rietz[1] suggested that large and infrequent economic shocks could explain the equity premium (the premium of equity securities over fixed income assets). However, it was not deemed feasible at the time, because it seemed that such events were too rare and could not occur in reality.[3] The theory was forgotten until 2005, when Robert Barro provided evidence of nations from around the world from the 19th and 20th century, showing that these events were possible and have happened. Since his papers, others have submitted different ideas regarding rare disasters' impact on other economic phenomenon.[4] However, many economists remain skeptical of how much rare disasters really explain the equity premium and Mehra still expresses doubt as to the validity of the theory.[5]

Controversy

[edit]

Rajnish Mehra was skeptical of Reitz's claim that rare disasters explain the equity premium and real interest rate behavior, because the rare disaster that Rietz had specified had never occurred in the U.S. Rietz suggested 25 to 97% drops, but this has never happened in the United States. Even if this were true, there are several other flaws regarding his model, parameters, and supporting evidence. The model Rietz presented did not compensate for a partial default on bond holders due to rapid inflation. Further, the risk aversion parameter was used inconsistently in his analysis. For example, a value of 10 was used to show a 25% drop in consumption, but a value of 1 is used to explain stock returns and consumption. Finally, more historical evidence was said to have been needed to give the theory proper support. For example, the perceived probability of a rare disaster should have been low before the atomic bomb was dropped and must have been higher before the Cuban Missile Crisis than after. Therefore, real interest rates should have correlated with these events, but they did not. Mehra concluded that Rietz's scenario was far too extreme to resolve the puzzle.[5]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b Rietz, Thomas (1988). "The equity risk premium a solution". Journal of Monetary Economics. 22 (1): 117–131. doi:10.1016/0304-3932(88)90172-9.
  2. ^ a b c d Barro, Robert. "Rare Disasters and Asset Markets in the Twentieth Century" (PDF). The Quarterly Journal of Economics. pp. 10–20. Archived from the original (PDF) on 9 July 2010. Retrieved 2009-03-09.
  3. ^ pp. 2–3
  4. ^ pp. 4–11
  5. ^ a b Rajnish Mehra (2008). "The Equity Premium Puzzle: A Review" (PDF). Foundations and Trends in Finance. pp. 1–81. Retrieved 2009-03-09.

Bibliography

[edit]