Jump to content

Income elasticity of demand: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
No edit summary
Add {{income_elasticity_of_demand_graph.svg}}
 
(43 intermediate revisions by 28 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Variation of demand for goods with respect to income increase}}
{{redirect|YED|Edmonton/Namao Heliport ''(IATA:YED)''|CFB Edmonton}}
{{Use American English|date = January 2019}}
{{Use American English|date = January 2019}}
{{Short description|Variation of demand for goods with respect to income increase}}
{{Use mdy dates|date = January 2019}}
{{Use mdy dates|date = January 2019}}
In economics, the '''income elasticity of demand''' ('''YED''') is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. For example, if in response to a 10% increase in income, quantity demanded for a good or service were to increase by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2.0.


== Mathematical definition ==
In economics, the '''income elasticity of demand''' is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. If a 10% increase in Mr. Ruskin Smith's income causes him to buy 20% more bacon, Smith's income elasticity of demand for bacon is 20%/10% = 2.


== Interpretation ==
[[File:Income elasticity of demand - inferior goods.svg|thumb|right|[[Inferior good]]s' demand ''Q''<sub>''X''</sub> falls as consumer income I increases.]]

* A negative income elasticity of demand is associated with [[inferior good]]s; an increase in income will lead to a fall in the demand and may lead to changes to more luxurious substitutes.
* A positive income elasticity of demand is associated with [[normal good]]s; an increase in income will lead to a rise in demand. If income elasticity of demand of a commodity is less than 1, it is a [[necessity good]]. If the elasticity of demand is greater than 1, it is a [[luxury good]] or a [[superior good]].
* A zero income elasticity of demand occurs when an increase in income is not associated with a change in the demand of a good.

Income elasticity of demand can be used as an indicator of future consumption patterns and as a guide to firms' investment decisions. For example, the "selected income elasticities" below suggest that an increasing portion of consumers' budgets will be devoted to purchasing automobiles and restaurant meals and a smaller share to tobacco and margarine.<ref>Frank, Robert (2008). p. 125</ref>

Income elasticities are closely related to the population income distribution and the fraction of the product's sales attributable to buyers from different [[income bracket]]s. Specifically, when a buyer in a certain income bracket experiences an income increase, their purchase of a product changes to match that of individuals in their new income bracket. If the income share elasticity is defined as the negative percentage change in individuals given a percentage increase in income bracken the income-elasticity, after some computation, becomes the expected value of the income-share elasticity with respect to the income distribution of purchasers of the product. When the income distribution is described by a [[gamma distribution]], the income elasticity is proportional to the percentage difference between the average income of the product's buyers and the average income of the population.<ref>Bordley and McDonald.</ref>

== Mathematical definition ==
:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\%\ \mbox{change in quantity demanded}}{\%\ \mbox{change in income}}</math>
:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\%\ \mbox{change in quantity demanded}}{\%\ \mbox{change in income}}</math>


More formally, the income elasticity of demand, <math>\ \epsilon_d</math>, for a given [[Marshallian demand function]] <math> Q(I,\vec{P}) ,</math> with arguments income and a vector of prices of all goods, for arbitrarily small changes in price and quantity of a good is
The point elasticity version, which defines it as an instantaneous rate of change of quantity demanded as income changes, is as follows. For a given [[Marshallian demand function]] <math> Q(I,\vec{P}) ,</math> with arguments income and a vector of prices of all goods,


:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\partial Q}{\partial I}\frac{I}{Q}</math>
:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\partial Q}{\partial I}\frac{I}{Q}</math>
Line 25: Line 15:
This can be rewritten in the form
This can be rewritten in the form


:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{d \ln Q}{d \ln I}</math>
:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\partial \ln Q}{\partial \ln I}</math>


For discrete changes the elasticity is
For discrete changes the elasticity is (using the [[arc elasticity]])


:<math>\epsilon_d={\Delta Q \over \Delta I} \times {(I_1 + I_2)/2 \over (Q_1 + Q_2)/2}={\Delta Q \over \Delta I}\times {I_1 + I_2 \over Q_1 + Q_2},</math>
:<math>\epsilon_d={\Delta Q \over \Delta I} \times {(I_1 + I_2)/2 \over (Q_1 + Q_2)/2}={\Delta Q \over \Delta I}\times {I_1 + I_2 \over Q_1 + Q_2},</math>


where subscripts 1 and 2 refer respectively to values before and after the change.
where subscripts 1 and 2 refer to values before and after the change.


== Interpretation ==
Necessity goods have an income elasticity of demand between zero and one: expenditure on these goods increases with income, but not as fast as income does, so the proportion of expenditure on these goods falls as income rises. This observation for food is known as ''[[Engel's law]]''.


[[File:Income elasticity of demand - inferior goods.svg|thumb|right|[[Inferior good]]s' demand ''Q''<sub>''X''</sub> falls as consumer income I increases.]]
==Types of income elasticity of demand==
The most commonly used elasticity in economics, the price elasticity of demand, is almost always negative, but many goods have positive income elasticities, many have negative.
There are five possible income demand curves:{{cn|date=April 2019}}


* A negative income elasticity of demand is associated with [[inferior good]]s; an increase in income will lead to a fall in the quantity demanded.
* High-income elasticity of demand:
In this case, an increase in income is accompanied by a relatively larger increase in quantity demanded.
* A positive income elasticity of demand is associated with [[normal good]]s; an increase in income will lead to a rise in quantity demanded.
**If income elasticity of demand of a commodity is less than 1, it is a [[necessity good]].
**If the elasticity of demand is greater than 1, it is a [[luxury good]] or a [[superior good]].
* A zero income elasticity of demand means that an increase in income does not change the quantity demanded of the good.


Income elasticity of demand can be used as an indicator of future consumption patterns and as a guide to firms' investment decisions. For example, the "selected income elasticities" below suggest that as incomes increase over time, an increasing portion of consumers' budgets will be devoted to purchasing automobiles and restaurant meals and a smaller share to tobacco and margarine.<ref>Frank, Robert (2008). p. 125</ref>
*Unitary income elasticity of demand:
{{income_elasticity_of_demand_graph.svg}}


=== Selected income elasticities ===
In this case, an increase in income is accompanied by the same proportionate increase in quantity demanded.
* Aluminum 1.5<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal |title=Industrialization and the Demand for Mineral Commodities |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/316657465 |journal= Journal of International Money and Finance|year=2017 |language=en |doi=10.1016/j.jimonfin.2017.04.006|last1=Stuermer |first1=Martin |volume=76 |pages=16–27 |hdl=10419/92982 |hdl-access=free }}</ref>
* A person's own life (also called "[[Value of life|value of statistical life]]") 0.50 to 0.60<ref name="The Value of a Statistical Life: A critical Review">{{cite journal|last=WK Viscusi|year=2003|title=The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world|url=https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w9487/w9487.pdf|journal=Journal of Risk and Uncertainty}}</ref>
* Automobiles 2.98<ref>Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). p.94.</ref>
* Base metals 0.9<ref>{{Cite journal |title=The role of income and substitution in commodity demand |url=https://academic.oup.com/oep/article/74/2/498/6318124 |access-date=2022-05-13 |journal=Oxford Economic Papers | year=2022 |doi=10.1093/oep/gpab029| last1=Baffes | first1=John | last2=Kabundi | first2=Alain | last3=Nagle | first3=Peter | volume=74 | issue=2 | pages=498–522 | hdl=10986/33257 | hdl-access=free }}</ref>
* Copper 1.0<ref name=":1" />
* Books 1.44{{citation needed|date=June 2024}}
* Energy 0.7<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal |title=The role of income and substitution in commodity demand |url=https://doi.org/10.1093/oep/gpab029 |access-date=2022-05-13 |journal=Oxford Economic Papers|year=2022 |doi=10.1093/oep/gpab029 |last1=Baffes |first1=John |last2=Kabundi |first2=Alain |last3=Nagle |first3=Peter |volume=74 |issue=2 |pages=498–522 |hdl=10986/33257 |hdl-access=free }}</ref>
* Margarine −0.20{{citation needed|date=June 2024}}
* Public transportation −0.36<ref>Frank (2008) 125.</ref>
* Restaurant meals 1.40{{citation needed|date=June 2024}}
* Tobacco 0.42<ref>see Gallet 2003, Health Econ.12, p.822</ref>
* Water demand 0.15 <ref>{{Cite journal|title=Measuring the Income Elasticity of Water Demand: The Importance of Publication and Endogeneity Biases|url=http://le.uwpress.org/content/94/2/259.abstract|journal=Land Economics|year=2018 |doi=10.3368/le.94.2.259 |last1=Havranek |first1=Tomas |last2=Irsova |first2=Zuzana |last3=Vlach |first3=Tomas |volume=94 |issue=2 |pages=259–283 |hdl=10419/174195 |s2cid=157363525 |hdl-access=free }}</ref>
Income elasticities of demand for gasoline and diesel have been studied extensively, however, elasticities vary widely between studies. Estimates for income elasticities of demand for gasoline in developed economies range from 0.66 to 1.26.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Dahl |first=Carol A. |date=2012-02-01 |title=Measuring global gasoline and diesel price and income elasticities |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0301421510008797 |journal=Energy Policy |series=Modeling Transport (Energy) Demand and Policies |language=en |volume=41 |pages=2–13 |doi=10.1016/j.enpol.2010.11.055 |issn=0301-4215}}</ref>


== Income elasticities and budget shares ==
* Low-income elasticity of demand:


Being a normal good (elasticity > 0) means that with higher income, consumption of the good will rise, but it does not mean that the good's share of the consumer's budget will rise with income. That depends on whether the elasticity is below or above +1. If the elasticity is negative, such as margarine's -.20 (from the [[#Selected income elasticities|"Selected income elasticities"]] section of this article), then it is obvious that margarine's share of the consumer's budget will fall if his income rises 10%. If the elasticity is tobacco's +.42, however, an income increase of 10% generates a spending increase of 4.2%, so tobacco's share of the budget falls. His purchases of books, with an elasticity of +1.44, will rise 14.4%, however, and so will have a higher budget share after his income rises.
In this case, an increase in income is accompanied by a less than proportionate increase in quantity demanded.


In aggregate, food has an income elasticity of demand between zero and one, so expenditure increases with income, but not as fast as income does. This observation is known as [[Engel's law]].
*Zero income elasticity of demand:


Income elasticities are closely related to the population [[income distribution]] and the fraction of the product's sales attributable to buyers from different [[income bracket]]s. When buyers in a certain income bracket get a pay raise, the income elasticity can be used to predict how much more the market will consume of that product. If the income share elasticity is defined as the negative percentage change in individuals given a percentage increase in income bracken the income-elasticity, after some computation, becomes the expected value of the income-share elasticity with respect to the income distribution of purchasers of the product. When the income distribution is described by a [[gamma distribution]], the income elasticity is proportional to the percentage difference between the average income of the product's buyers and the average income of the population.<ref>Bordley and McDonald.</ref>
In this case, the quantity bought is constant regardless of changes in income.


*Negative income elasticity of demand:
== Income-varying elasticities of demand ==
Income elasticities can vary as household income changes, particularly in the case of goods and commodities such as food and energy.<ref name=":0" /> At low levels of per capita income, elasticities of demand for food, energy, or other products can be high. As per capita income increases, however, income elasticities fall. At high levels, the marginal elasticities may go to zero, or even negative.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Commodity Markets: Evolution, Challenges, and Policies |url=https://openknowledge.worldbank.org/bitstream/handle/10986/37404/Commodity-Markets.pdf |access-date=2022-05-13 |website=World Bank |language=en}}</ref> These differences can be observed by comparing countries at different income levels. For example, estimates of the income elasticity of cereals ranges from 0.62 in Tanzania to 0.47 in Georgia, 0.28 in Slovenia, and 0.05 in the United States.<ref>{{Cite web |last1=Muhammad |first1=rew |last2=Seale |first2=James L. Jr. |last3=Meade |first3=Birgit |last4=Regmi |first4=Anita |title=International Evidence on Food Consumption Patterns: An Update Using 2005 International Comparison Program Data |url=http://www.ers.usda.gov/publications/pub-details/?pubid=47581 |access-date=2022-05-13 |website=www.ers.usda.gov |language=en}}</ref>


The decline in elasticities as income increases is a form of [[Kuznet's curve]]. As economies industrialize and get wealthier, consumer demand changes. At low levels of income, demand for energy or other goods increases very rapidly. However, as income rises further, consumption requirements (e.g. for food or energy) are increasingly satisfied. In addition, consumption patterns shift toward services rather than goods, which require fewer commodities to produce.
In this case, an increase in income is accompanied by a decrease in quantity demanded.

==Selected income elasticities==

* Automobiles 2.98<ref>Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). p.94.</ref>
* Books 1.44
* A person's own life (also called "[[Value of life|value of statistical life]]") 0.50 to 0.60<ref name="The Value of a Statistical Life: A critical Review">{{cite journal|last=WK Viscusi|title=The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world|journal=Journal of Risk and Uncertainty|year=2003|url=http://lsr.nellco.org/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1180&context=harvard_olin&sei-redir=1&referer=http%3A%2F%2Fscholar.google.com%2Fscholar%3Fq%3Dvalue%2Bof%2Ba%2Blife%2Bto%2Bsociety#search=%22value%20life%20society%22}}</ref>
* Restaurant meals 1.40
* Tobacco 0.42<ref>see Gallet 2003, Health Econ.12, p.822</ref>
* Margarine −0.20
* Public transportation −0.36<ref>Frank (2008) 125.</ref>
* Water demand 0.15 <ref>{{Cite web|url=http://le.uwpress.org/content/94/2/259.abstract|title=Measuring the Income Elasticity of Water Demand: The Importance of Publication and Endogeneity Biases|website=Land Economics}}</ref>

Income elasticities are notably stable over time and across countries due to the [[law of one price]].<ref>Perloff, J. (2008). p.105.</ref>


== See also ==
== See also ==
Line 87: Line 82:


{{Refend}}
{{Refend}}
{{Microeconomics}}

[[Category:Demand]]
[[Category:Demand]]
[[Category:Elasticity (economics)]]
[[Category:Elasticity (economics)]]

Latest revision as of 00:05, 14 June 2024

In economics, the income elasticity of demand (YED) is the responsivenesses of the quantity demanded for a good to a change in consumer income. It is measured as the ratio of the percentage change in quantity demanded to the percentage change in income. For example, if in response to a 10% increase in income, quantity demanded for a good or service were to increase by 20%, the income elasticity of demand would be 20%/10% = 2.0.

Mathematical definition

[edit]

The point elasticity version, which defines it as an instantaneous rate of change of quantity demanded as income changes, is as follows. For a given Marshallian demand function with arguments income and a vector of prices of all goods,

This can be rewritten in the form

For discrete changes the elasticity is (using the arc elasticity)

where subscripts 1 and 2 refer to values before and after the change.

Interpretation

[edit]
Inferior goods' demand QX falls as consumer income I increases.

The most commonly used elasticity in economics, the price elasticity of demand, is almost always negative, but many goods have positive income elasticities, many have negative.

  • A negative income elasticity of demand is associated with inferior goods; an increase in income will lead to a fall in the quantity demanded.
  • A positive income elasticity of demand is associated with normal goods; an increase in income will lead to a rise in quantity demanded.
  • A zero income elasticity of demand means that an increase in income does not change the quantity demanded of the good.

Income elasticity of demand can be used as an indicator of future consumption patterns and as a guide to firms' investment decisions. For example, the "selected income elasticities" below suggest that as incomes increase over time, an increasing portion of consumers' budgets will be devoted to purchasing automobiles and restaurant meals and a smaller share to tobacco and margarine.[1]

Engels curves showing income elasticity of demand (YED) of normal goods (comprising luxury (red) and necessity goods (yellow)), perfectly inelastic (green) and inferior goods (blue)

Selected income elasticities

[edit]

Income elasticities of demand for gasoline and diesel have been studied extensively, however, elasticities vary widely between studies. Estimates for income elasticities of demand for gasoline in developed economies range from 0.66 to 1.26.[10]

Income elasticities and budget shares

[edit]

Being a normal good (elasticity > 0) means that with higher income, consumption of the good will rise, but it does not mean that the good's share of the consumer's budget will rise with income. That depends on whether the elasticity is below or above +1. If the elasticity is negative, such as margarine's -.20 (from the "Selected income elasticities" section of this article), then it is obvious that margarine's share of the consumer's budget will fall if his income rises 10%. If the elasticity is tobacco's +.42, however, an income increase of 10% generates a spending increase of 4.2%, so tobacco's share of the budget falls. His purchases of books, with an elasticity of +1.44, will rise 14.4%, however, and so will have a higher budget share after his income rises.

In aggregate, food has an income elasticity of demand between zero and one, so expenditure increases with income, but not as fast as income does. This observation is known as Engel's law.

Income elasticities are closely related to the population income distribution and the fraction of the product's sales attributable to buyers from different income brackets. When buyers in a certain income bracket get a pay raise, the income elasticity can be used to predict how much more the market will consume of that product. If the income share elasticity is defined as the negative percentage change in individuals given a percentage increase in income bracken the income-elasticity, after some computation, becomes the expected value of the income-share elasticity with respect to the income distribution of purchasers of the product. When the income distribution is described by a gamma distribution, the income elasticity is proportional to the percentage difference between the average income of the product's buyers and the average income of the population.[11]

Income-varying elasticities of demand

[edit]

Income elasticities can vary as household income changes, particularly in the case of goods and commodities such as food and energy.[6] At low levels of per capita income, elasticities of demand for food, energy, or other products can be high. As per capita income increases, however, income elasticities fall. At high levels, the marginal elasticities may go to zero, or even negative.[12] These differences can be observed by comparing countries at different income levels. For example, estimates of the income elasticity of cereals ranges from 0.62 in Tanzania to 0.47 in Georgia, 0.28 in Slovenia, and 0.05 in the United States.[13]

The decline in elasticities as income increases is a form of Kuznet's curve. As economies industrialize and get wealthier, consumer demand changes. At low levels of income, demand for energy or other goods increases very rapidly. However, as income rises further, consumption requirements (e.g. for food or energy) are increasingly satisfied. In addition, consumption patterns shift toward services rather than goods, which require fewer commodities to produce.

See also

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Frank, Robert (2008). p. 125
  2. ^ a b Stuermer, Martin (2017). "Industrialization and the Demand for Mineral Commodities". Journal of International Money and Finance. 76: 16–27. doi:10.1016/j.jimonfin.2017.04.006. hdl:10419/92982.
  3. ^ WK Viscusi (2003). "The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world" (PDF). Journal of Risk and Uncertainty.
  4. ^ Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). p.94.
  5. ^ Baffes, John; Kabundi, Alain; Nagle, Peter (2022). "The role of income and substitution in commodity demand". Oxford Economic Papers. 74 (2): 498–522. doi:10.1093/oep/gpab029. hdl:10986/33257. Retrieved May 13, 2022.
  6. ^ a b Baffes, John; Kabundi, Alain; Nagle, Peter (2022). "The role of income and substitution in commodity demand". Oxford Economic Papers. 74 (2): 498–522. doi:10.1093/oep/gpab029. hdl:10986/33257. Retrieved May 13, 2022.
  7. ^ Frank (2008) 125.
  8. ^ see Gallet 2003, Health Econ.12, p.822
  9. ^ Havranek, Tomas; Irsova, Zuzana; Vlach, Tomas (2018). "Measuring the Income Elasticity of Water Demand: The Importance of Publication and Endogeneity Biases". Land Economics. 94 (2): 259–283. doi:10.3368/le.94.2.259. hdl:10419/174195. S2CID 157363525.
  10. ^ Dahl, Carol A. (February 1, 2012). "Measuring global gasoline and diesel price and income elasticities". Energy Policy. Modeling Transport (Energy) Demand and Policies. 41: 2–13. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.11.055. ISSN 0301-4215.
  11. ^ Bordley and McDonald.
  12. ^ "Commodity Markets: Evolution, Challenges, and Policies" (PDF). World Bank. Retrieved May 13, 2022.
  13. ^ Muhammad, rew; Seale, James L. Jr.; Meade, Birgit; Regmi, Anita. "International Evidence on Food Consumption Patterns: An Update Using 2005 International Comparison Program Data". www.ers.usda.gov. Retrieved May 13, 2022.

References

[edit]
  • Bordley; McDonald (1993). "Estimating Aggregate Automotive Income Elasticities From the Population Income-Share Elasticity". Journal of Business and Economic Statistics.
  • Perloff, J. (2008). Microeconomics Theory & Applications with Calculus. Pearson. ISBN 978-0-321-27794-7.
  • Samuelson; Nordhaus (2001). Microeconomics (17th ed.). McGraw-Hill.
  • Frank, Robert (2008). Microeconomics and Behavior (7th ed.). McGraw-Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-126349-8.