Jump to content

Economic history of the Netherlands (1500–1815): Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
AnomieBOT (talk | contribs)
m Dating maintenance tags: {{Lead too long}}
 
(37 intermediate revisions by 22 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|None}}
{{lead too long|date=May 2022}}
[[File:Jacob Knyff English and dutch ships taking on stores at a port.jpg|thumb|250px|English and Dutch ships taking on stores at port, by [[Jacob Knyff]]]]
{{Short description|Aspect of history}}
{{see also|Financial history of the Dutch Republic|Dutch gulden#History}}
[[File:Aernout Smit Table Bay, 1683 William Fehr Collection Cape Town.jpg|thumb|200px|View of [[Table Bay]] (overlooked by [[History of Cape Town|Kaapstad]], [[Dutch Cape Colony]]) with ships of the [[Dutch East India Company]], c. 1683. In the 17th century, the size of the Dutch merchant fleet probably exceeded the combined fleets of England, France, Spain, Portugal, and Germany. "By seventeenth century standards," as [[Richard Unger]] affirms, Dutch shipbuilding "was a massive industry and larger than any shipbuilding industry which had preceded it."<ref>Lunsford, Virginia W.: ''Piracy and Privateering in the Golden Age Netherlands''. (Palgrave Macmillan, 2005), p. 69</ref><ref>[[Immanuel Wallerstein|Wallerstein, Immanuel]] (2011). ''The Modern World-System II: Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European World-Economy, 1600–1750''. (New York: Academic Press, 1980), p. 43–44. As [[Immanuel Wallerstein]] (1980) remarked, the Dutch shipbuilding industry was "of modern dimensions, inclining strongly toward standardised, repetitive methods. It was highly mechanized and used many labor-saving devices – wind-powered sawmills, powered feeders for saw, block and tackles, great cranes to move heavy timbers – all of which increased productivity."</ref><ref>Moore, Jason W. (2010). "'Amsterdam is Standing on Norway' Part II: The Global North Atlantic in the Ecological Revolution of the Long Seventeenth Century," Journal of Agrarian Change, 10, 2, p. 188–227</ref>]]
[[File:Voc.jpg|thumb|upright|The [[shipyard]] of the Dutch East India Company (VOC) in Amsterdam (1726 engraving by [[Joseph Mulder]]). The [[shipbuilding]] district of [[Zaan]], near Amsterdam, became one of the world's earliest known [[industrialization|industrialized]] areas, with around 900 wind-powered [[sawmills]] at the end of the 17th century. By the early 17th century Dutch shipyards were producing a large number of ships to a standard design, allowing extensive [[division of labour]], a specialization which further reduced [[unit cost]]s.<ref>Zahedieh, Nuala (2010). ''The Capital and the Colonies: London and the Atlantic Economy 1660–1700'' (Cambridge University Press), p. 152</ref>]]
[[File:Jan Brueghel the Younger, Satire on Tulip Mania, c. 1640.jpg|thumb|upright|[[Jan Brueghel the Younger]]'s ''A Satire of Tulip Mania'' (ca. 1640) [[singerie|depicts speculators as brainless monkeys]] in contemporary upper-class dress. The ''[[Tulip Mania]]'', of the 1630s, is often considered by many as the first recorded [[economic bubble]] (also known as [[asset bubble]] or [[speculative bubble]]) in history.]]
The '''economic history of the Netherlands (1500–1815)''' is the history of an economy that American-Dutch scholar and economist [[Jan de Vries (historian)|Jan de Vries]] calls the first "modern" economy.<ref name="deVriesWoude">{{cite book | title=The First Modern Economy: Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815 | publisher=Cambridge University Press |author1=de Vries, Jan |author2=van der Woude, Ad | year=1997 | isbn=0-521-57061-1}}</ref> It covers the [[History of the Netherlands|Netherlands]] as the [[Habsburg Netherlands]], through the era of the [[Dutch Republic]], the [[Batavian Republic]] and the [[Kingdom of Holland]].
[[File:GDP per capita in the Netherlands 1500 to 1815.jpg|thumb|GDP per capita in the Netherlands 1500 to 1815]]
After becoming de facto independent from the empire of [[Philip II of Spain]] around 1585 the country experienced almost a century of explosive economic growth. A technological revolution in shipbuilding led to a [[competitive advantage]] in shipping that helped the young Republic become the dominant trade power by the mid-17th century. In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totalled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total. Pillars of this position were the dominance of the [[Amsterdam Entrepôt]] in European trade, and that of the [[Dutch East India Company|Dutch East]] and [[Dutch West India Company|West India Companies]] (VOC and WIC) in intercontinental trade. Beside trade, an early industrial revolution (powered by wind, water and peat), land reclamation from the sea, and agricultural revolution helped the Dutch economy achieve the highest standard of living in Europe (and probably the world) by the middle of the 17th century. Affluence facilitated a [[Dutch Golden Age|Golden Age]] in culture typified by the great artist [[Rembrandt|Rembrandt van Rijn (1606–1669)]].


The '''economic history of the Netherlands (1500–1815)''' covers the [[History of the Netherlands|Netherlands]] as the [[Habsburg Netherlands]], through the era of the [[Dutch Republic]], the [[Batavian Republic]] and the [[Kingdom of Holland]].
However, around 1670 a combination of politico-military upheavals (wars with France and England) and adverse economic developments (a break in the upward [[secular trend]] of price levels) brought the Dutch economic boom to an abrupt end. This caused a retrenchment of the Dutch economy in the period up to 1713, in which the industrial sector was partly dismantled and growth in trade leveled off. The economy struck out in new directions, including [[whaling]], colonial plantations in [[Suriname]], and new types of trade with Asia. However, these riskier ventures often failed to bring commensurate gains. The VOC embarked on a period of profitless growth.


After becoming de facto independent from the empire of [[Philip II of Spain]] around 1585 the country experienced almost a century of explosive economic growth. The young Republic become the dominant trade power by the mid-17th century, partly due to its shipbuilding. In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totalled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total. Pillars of this position were the dominance of the [[Amsterdam Entrepôt]] in European trade, and that of the Dutch East and West India Companies (VOC and WIC) in intercontinental trade. The Dutch society had possibly the highest standard of living in Europe (and probably in the world) by the middle of the 17th century. Affluence facilitated a [[Dutch Golden Age|Golden Age]] in culture typified by the artist [[Rembrandt|Rembrandt van Rijn (1606–1669)]].
The financial strength proved more durable, enabling the Netherlands to play the role of a major power in the European conflicts around the turn of the 18th century by hiring mercenary armies and subsidizing its allies. These conflicts put an enormous strain on the resources of the Republic, however, and for that reason the Republic (like its opponent, the France of [[Louis XIV of France|Louis XIV]]) was deeply in debt at the end of the [[War of the Spanish Succession]]. The regents of the Republic more or less abandoned its Great-Power pretensions after 1713, cutting down on its military preparedness in a vain attempt to pay down this overhang of public debt. That debt brought a significant ''rentier'' class into being that helped change the nature of the economy from one invested primarily in trade and industry into one in which a significant financial sector played a dominant role. By the end of the 18th century the Republic was the major market for [[sovereign debt]], and a major source of foreign direct investment. During the period of [[Proto-industrialization]], the empire received 50% of textiles and 80% of silks import from the India's [[Mughal Empire]], chiefly from the latter's most developed region known as [[Bengal Subah]].<ref name="tong">{{cite book |author=Junie T. Tong |year=2016 |title=Finance and Society in 21st Century China: Chinese Culture Versus Western Markets |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_UQGDAAAQBAJ&pg=PA151 |publisher=CRC Press |page=151 |isbn=978-1-317-13522-7}}</ref><ref name="esposito">{{cite book |editor1=John L. Esposito |editor1-link=John L. Esposito |year=2004 |title=The Islamic World: Past and Present |volume=1: Abba - Hist. |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=KZcohRpc4OsC&pg=PT190 |publisher=Oxford University Press |page=174 |isbn=978-0-19-516520-3}}</ref><ref>Nanda, J. N (2005). {{cite book |year=2005 | title=Bengal: the unique state | publisher=Concept Publishing Company. p. 10. | isbn=978-81-8069-149-2 | quote=Bengal [...] was rich in the production and export of grain, salt, fruit, liquors and wines, precious metals and ornaments besides the output of its handlooms in silk and cotton. Europe referred to Bengal as the richest country to trade with.}}</ref><ref name="Prakash">[[Om Prakash (historian)|Om Prakash]], "[http://link.galegroup.com/apps/doc/CX3447600139/WHIC?u=seat24826&xid=6b597320 Empire, Mughal]", ''History of World Trade Since 1450'', edited by John J. McCusker, vol. 1, Macmillan Reference USA, 2006, pp. 237–240, ''World History in Context''. Retrieved 3 August 2017</ref>


However, around 1670 a combination of politico-military upheavals (wars with France and England) and adverse economic developments (a break in the upward [[secular trend]] of price levels) brought the Dutch economic boom to an abrupt end. This caused a retrenchment of the Dutch economy in the period up to 1713, in which the industrial sector was partly dismantled and growth in trade leveled off. The economy struck out in new directions, including [[whaling]], colonial plantations in [[Suriname]], and new types of trade with Asia. However, these riskier ventures often failed to bring commensurate gains. The VOC embarked on a period of profitless growth. The financial strength proved more durable, enabling the Netherlands to play the role of a major power in the European conflicts around the turn of the 18th century by hiring mercenary armies and subsidizing its allies.
Wars with Great Britain and France with the Republic's Indian allies at the end of the 18th century, and attendant political upheavals, caused a financial and economic crisis from which the economy was unable to recover. After the successors of the Republic (the Batavian Republic and the Kingdom of Holland) were forced to engage in policies of economic warfare against the French Empire, which proved disastrous for Dutch trade and industry; most of the gains of the previous two centuries were rapidly lost. The newly independent [[Kingdom of the Netherlands]] was faced in 1815 with an economy that was largely deindustrialized and deurbanized, but still saddled with a crippling public debt, which it was forced to repudiate (the first time that the Dutch state defaulted since the dark pre-independence days of the Revolt).


These conflicts put an enormous strain on the resources of the Republic, however, and for that reason the Republic (like its opponent, the France of [[Louis XIV of France|Louis XIV]]) was deeply in debt at the end of the [[War of the Spanish Succession]]. The regents of the Republic more or less abandoned its Great-Power pretensions after 1713, cutting down on its military preparedness in a vain attempt to pay down this overhang of public debt. That debt brought a significant ''rentier'' class into being that helped change the nature of the economy from one invested primarily in trade and industry into one in which a significant financial sector played a dominant role. By the end of the 18th century the Republic was the major market for [[sovereign debt]], and a major source of foreign direct investment.
In the 17th century, Amsterdam became the leading commercial and financial centre of the world. It held this position for more than a century,<ref>Kennedy, Paul (1989). ''The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers''</ref><ref>Bindemann, Kirsten (1999). ''The Future of European Financial Centres''</ref><ref>Cassis, Youssef (2010). ''Capitals of Capital: The Rise and Fall of International Financial Centres 1780–2009''. Translated by Jacqueline Collier. (Cambridge University Press, 2010), p. 9</ref> and was the first modern model of an international financial centre.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.cscollege.gov.sg/Knowledge/Pages/Hub-Cities-London.aspx |title=Hub Cities – London: Why did London lose its preeminent port hub status, and how has it continued to retain its dominance in marine logistics, insurance, financing and law? (Civil Service College of Singapore) |publisher=[[Civil Service College Singapore]] (cscollege.gov.sg) |author=Wu, Wei Neng |quote=As Wu Wei Neng (2012) notes: "17th century Amsterdam was the world's first modern financial centre – the city hall, Wisselbank, Beurs (stock exchange), Korenbeurs (commodities exchange), major insurance, brokerage and trading companies were located within a few blocks of each other, along with coffee houses which served as informal trading floors and exchanges that facilitated deal-making. [[Financial innovation]]s such as maritime insurance, retirement pensions, annuities, futures and options, transnational securities listings, mutual funds and modern investment banking had their genesis in 17th and 18th century Amsterdam."|date=26 February 2014 |access-date=26 February 2017 }}{{dead link|date=November 2018}}</ref> As [[Richard Sylla]] (2015) noted, "In modern history, several nations had what some of us call [[financial revolution]]s. These can be thought of as creating in a short period of time all the key components of a modern [[financial system]]. The first was the [[Dutch Republic]] four centuries ago."<ref>[[Richard Sylla|Sylla, Richard]] (2015). "[http://www.thebhc.org/sites/default/files/Sylla_BEHO_Final%20Draft_0.pdf Financial Development, Corporations, and Inequality]". (BHC-EBHA Meeting)</ref><ref>{{cite journal|last1=Gelderblom|first1= Oscar|last2= Jonker|first2= Joost|title = Completing a Financial Revolution: The Finance of the Dutch East India Trade and the Rise of the Amsterdam Capital Market, 1595–1612 |journal = The Journal of Economic History|date= 2004|volume= 64|issue= 3|pages= 641–72|doi= 10.1017/S002205070400292X|hdl= 1874/386215|s2cid= 54700710|hdl-access= free}}</ref><ref>Tracy, James D.: ''A Financial Revolution in the Habsburg Netherlands: Renten and Renteniers in the County of Holland, 1515–1565''. (University of California Press, 1985, 300 pp)</ref> Amsterdam – unlike its predecessors such as [[Bruges]], [[Antwerp]], [[Republic of Genoa|Genoa]], and [[Republic of Venice|Venice]] – controlled crucial resources and markets directly, sending its fleets to all quarters of the world.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.businessinsider.com/700-years-of-government-bond-yields-2013-12 |author=Taylor, Bryan |title=''How 3 Countries Lost Their Position As The World's Dominant Financial Power Over The Last 800 Years'' |publisher=Global Financial Data |date=8 December 2013 |access-date=14 May 2014 }}</ref>


Wars with Great Britain and France at the end of the 18th century, and attendant political upheavals, caused a financial and economic crisis from which the economy was unable to recover. After the successors of the Republic (the Batavian Republic and the Kingdom of Holland) were forced to engage in policies of economic warfare against the French Empire, which proved disastrous for Dutch trade and industry; most of the gains of the previous two centuries were rapidly lost. The newly independent [[Kingdom of the Netherlands]] was faced in 1815 with an economy that was largely deindustrialized and deurbanized, but still saddled with a crippling public debt, which it was forced to repudiate (the first time that the Dutch state defaulted since the dark pre-independence days of the Revolt).
From about the early 1600s to about the mid-18th century, the Dutch Republic's economic, business [[Financial history of the Dutch Republic|and financial systems]] were the most advanced and sophisticated ever seen in history.<ref>In [[Karl Marx]]'s own words, "Its [17th-century Dutch Republic's] fisheries, marine, manufactures, surpassed those of any other country. The total capital of the Republic was probably more important than that of all the rest of Europe put together." (''[[Das Kapital]]'')</ref><ref>[[Anatole Kaletsky|Kaletsky, Anatole]]: ''Capitalism 4.0: The Birth of a New Economy in the Aftermath of Crisis''. (PublicAffairs, 2010), pp. 109–10. [[Anatole Kaletsky]] (2010): "The bursting of the tulip bubble in 1637 did not end Dutch economic hegemony. Far from it. [[Tulipmania]] was followed by a century of Dutch leadership in almost every branch of global commerce, finance, and manufacturing."</ref><ref>Gieseking, Jen Jack; Mangold, William; et al.: ''The People, Place, and Space Reader''. (Routledge, 2014, {{ISBN|978-0415664974}}), p. 151. As [[Witold Rybczynski]] (1987) notes, the 17th-century Dutch Republic "had few natural resources—no mines, no forests—and what little land there was needed constant protection from the sea. But this "low" country surprisingly quickly established itself as a major power. In a short time it became the most advanced shipbuilding nation in the world and developed large naval, fishing, and merchant fleets. (...) The Netherlands introduced many financial innovations that made it a major economic force—and Amsterdam became the world center for international finance. Its manufacturing towns grew so quickly that by the middle of the century the Netherlands had supplanted France as the leading industrial nation of the world."</ref><ref name="JacobSoll2014">[[Jacob Soll|Soll, Jacob]]: ''The Reckoning: Financial Accountability and the Making and Breaking of Nations''. (New York: Basic Books, 2014)</ref> For example, as [[Jacob Soll]] (2014) noted, "with the complexity of the [[stock exchange]], [17th-century] Dutch merchants' knowledge of finance became more sophisticated than that of their [[Italian city-states|Italian predecessors]] or [[Holy Roman Empire|German neighbors]]."<ref name="JacobSoll2014"/> From about 1600 to about 1720 the Dutch had the highest [[per capita income]] in the world. The [[Dutch Golden Age]]'s [[Tulip Mania]] (in the mid-1630s) is generally considered as the first recorded [[asset price bubble]] (also known as [[speculative bubble]]). Similarly, early [[stock market bubble]]s [[stock market crash|and crashes]] had their roots in socio-politico-economic activities of the 17th-century Dutch Republic (the birthplace of the world's first formal [[stock exchange]] and [[stock market]]),<ref>{{Cite book | url=https://books.google.com/books?id=ZMPTAwAAQBAJ | first=John | last=Brooks | author-link=John Brooks (writer) | title=Business Adventures: Twelve Classic Tales from the World of Wall Street | publisher=Weybright & Talley | date=1968| isbn=9781497638853 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book | url=https://books.google.com/books?id=-oi7Osz2Ss0C | title=The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets | first1=William N. | last1=Goetzmann | first2=K. Geert | last2=Rouwenhorst | publisher=[[Oxford University Press]] | year=2005 | pages=165–175| isbn=9780195175714 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book | url=https://books.google.com/books?id=V8fbAgAAQBAJ | last=Petram | first=Lodewijk | title=The World's First Stock Exchange: How the Amsterdam Market for Dutch East India Company Shares Became a Modern Securities Market, 1602–1700''. Translated from the Dutch by Lynne Richards. | publisher=[[Columbia University Press]] | year=2014| isbn=9780231537322 }}</ref><ref name="Macaulay, Catherine R. 2015 p. 5">Macaulay, Catherine R. (2015). "Capitalism's renaissance? The potential of repositioning the financial 'meta-economy'". (''Futures'', Volume 68, April 2015, p. 5–18)</ref> the [[Dutch East India Company]] (the world's first formally [[listing (finance)|listed]] [[public company]]) and the [[Dutch West India Company]], in particular. At the dawn of [[modern capitalism]], wherever Dutch capital went, urban features were developed, economic activities expanded, new industries established, new jobs created, trading companies operated, swamps drained, mines opened, forests exploited, canals constructed, mills turned, and ships were built.<ref name="Brenner"/><ref name="Moore2010a">{{cite journal | last1 = Moore | first1 = Jason W | year = 2010a | title = 'Amsterdam is Standing on Norway' Part I: The Alchemy of Capital, Empire, and Nature in the Diaspora of Silver, 1545–1648 | journal = Journal of Agrarian Change | volume = 10 | issue = 1| pages = 35–71 }}</ref><ref name="Moore2010b"/><ref name="Lindblad"/><ref name="Mueller"/> In the early modern period, the Dutch were pioneering [[investor]]s and [[capitalist]]s who raised the commercial and industrial potential of underdeveloped or undeveloped lands whose resources they exploited, whether for better or worse. For example, the native economies of pre-[[Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie|VOC-era]] Taiwan and South Africa were virtually undeveloped or were in almost primitive states. In other words, the recorded [[economic history of South Africa]] [[economic history of Taiwan|and Taiwan]] both began with the VOC period. It was VOC people who established and developed first [[urban area]]s in the history of Taiwan ([[Tainan]]) and South Africa ([[Cape Town]] and [[Stellenbosch]]). In [[Werner Sombart]]'s words (1902), "in all probability the [[United Provinces of the Netherlands|United Provinces]] were the land in which the [[capitalist]] spirit for the first time attained its fullest maturity; where this maturity related to all its aspects, which were equally developed; and where this development had never been done comprehensive before. Moreover, in the Netherlands an entire people became imbued with the capitalist spirit; so much so, that in the 17th century Holland was universally regarded as the land of [[capitalism]] par excellence; it was envied by all other nations, who put forth their keenest endeavours in their desire to emulate it..."<ref>[[Werner Sombart|Sombart, Werner]]: ''The Quintessence of Capitalism: A Study of the History and Psychology of the Modern Business Man''. Translated from the German by M. Epstein. (London: T. Fisher Unwin, 1915), p. 144</ref>


==Development==
Historically, the Dutch were responsible for at least four major pioneering [[institutional]] [[innovation]]s{{efn|Inventions and innovations whose earliest known fully functioning historical models were first effectively institutionalized and operated by the peoples of the Netherlands.}} (in economic, business and financial history of the world):
* The foundation of the [[Dutch East India Company]] ([[Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie|VOC]]), the world's first [[publicly listed company]]<ref>Wilson, Eric Michael: ''The Savage Republic: De Indis of Hugo Grotius, Republicanism and Dutch Hegemony within the Early Modern World-System (c.1600–1619)''. (Martinus Nijhoff, 2008, {{ISBN|978-9004167889}}), p. 215–217. Eric Michael Wilson (2008): "The defining characteristics of the modern corporation, all of which emerged during the [[world-systems theory|Dutch cycle]], include: limited liability for investors, free transferability of investor interests, legal personality and centralised management. Although some of these characteristics were present to a certain extent in the fourteenth-century Genoese ''[[societas comperarum]]'' of the [[world-systems theory|first cycle]], the first wholly cognisable modern limited liability public company was the VOC."</ref><ref>Funnell, Warwick; Robertson, Jeffrey: ''Accounting by the First Public Company: The Pursuit of Supremacy''. (Routledge, 2013, {{ISBN|0415716179}})</ref> and the first historical model of the [[multinational corporation]] (or [[transnational corporation]]) in its modern sense,{{efn|It is important to note the difference between a "[[corporation]]" and a "[[company]]" in general, hence the difference between a "multinational corporation" and a "multinational company" in its modern sense.}}<ref name="Sayle2001">{{cite news|url=http://www.lrb.co.uk/v23/n07/murray-sayle/japan-goes-dutch |title=Japan goes Dutch |newspaper=[[London Review of Books]]|volume= 23|pages=3–7 |number = 7|author=Sayle, Murray |quote=[[Murray Sayle]] (2001): "The Netherlands United East Indies Company (Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie, or VOC), founded in 1602, was the world's first multinational, joint-stock, limited liability corporation – as well as its first government-backed trading cartel. [[British East India Company|Our own East India Company]], founded in 1600, remained a coffee-house clique until 1657, when it, too, began selling shares, not in individual voyages, but in the Company itself, by which time its Dutch rival was by far the biggest commercial enterprise the world had known." |date=5 April 2001 |author-link=Murray Sayle }}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/roadshow/fts/corpuschristi_201205A19.html |author=Phelan, Ben |title=Dutch East India Company: The World's First Multinational |publisher=[[PBS.org]] |date=7 January 2013 |access-date=18 March 2018 }}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.businessinsider.com/rise-and-fall-of-united-east-india-2013-11 |author= Taylor, Bryan |title=The Rise and Fall of the Largest Corporation in History |publisher=[[Business Insider]] |date=6 November 2013 |access-date=18 March 2018 }}</ref><ref>[[Timothy Brook|Brook, Timothy]]: ''[[Vermeer's Hat|Vermeer's Hat: The Seventeenth Century and the Dawn of the Global World]]''. (Bloomsbury Press, 2008, pp. 288, {{ISBN|978-1596915992}})</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=https://moneyweek.com/20-march-1602-dutch-east-india-company-formed/ |author=Partridge, Matthew |title=This day in history: 20 March 1602: Dutch East India Company formed |publisher=[[MoneyWeek]] |date=20 March 2015 |access-date=20 May 2018 }}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url= https://www.lowyinstitute.org/the-interpreter/starting-point-first-global-supply-chain |author=Grenville, Stephen |title=The first global supply chain |publisher=[[Lowy Institute]] |date=3 November 2017 |access-date=28 May 2018 }}</ref> in 1602. Historically, the VOC played a crucial role in the rise of [[corporate globalization|corporate-led globalization]],<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/global-opinions/wp/2017/03/12/the-netherlands-was-once-liberal-has-the-country-lost-its-way/ |author=Molavi, Afshin |title=The Netherlands was once a liberal force for globalization. Has the country lost its way? |work=[[The Washington Post]] |date=12 March 2017|access-date=7 July 2017 }}</ref> [[corporate identity]],<ref>{{cite web |url=https://www.zenogroup.com/dutch-courage-modern-pr-lessons-from-the-worlds-first-corporation/ |author=Earl, Steve |title=Dutch courage: modern PR lessons from the world's first corporation |publisher=Zeno Group (zenogroup.com) |date=29 October 2012 |access-date=7 July 2017 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170807112259/https://www.zenogroup.com/dutch-courage-modern-pr-lessons-from-the-worlds-first-corporation/ |archive-date=7 August 2017 |url-status=dead }}</ref> [[corporate governance]], [[corporate finance]], and [[corporate capitalism]]. The birth of the VOC is often considered by many to be the official beginning of corporate-led globalization with the rise of modern corporations (multinational corporations in particular) as a highly significant socio-politico-economic force that affect human lives in every corner of the world today. As the first company to be [[Listing (finance)|listed]] on an official [[stock exchange]], the VOC was the first company to issue [[stock]] and [[Bond (finance)|bonds]] to the general public. With its pioneering features, the VOC is generally considered a major institutional breakthrough and the model for modern [[corporation]]s (large-scale [[business enterprise]]s in particular). It is important to note that most of the largest and most influential companies of the modern-day world are [[public company|publicly-traded]] multinational corporations, including ''[[Forbes Global 2000]]'' companies. Like present-day publicly-listed multinational companies, in many ways, the post-1657 [[British East India Company|English/British East India Company]]'s operational structure was a historical derivative of the earlier VOC model.<ref name="Sayle2001"/><ref name="Macaulay2015">Macaulay, Catherine R. (2015), 'Capitalism's renaissance? The potential of repositioning the financial 'meta-economy,'. Futures 68: 5–18. {{doi|10.1016/j.futures.2014.10.016}}. As Catherine Macaulay (2015) notes, "(...) Meanwhile in England, the [[English East India Company|EIC]] repeatedly issued new [[corporate bond|bond]]s for the term of single voyages until 1657 and each of the six fleets sailing between 1610 and 1612 provided a profit between 50 and 200% (Dari-Mattiacci et al., 2013, p. 18). (...) The EIC's bond format, used successfully for over 50 years, has been criticised for preventing capital accumulation as bonds were liquidated quickly after each voyage and a new company effectively established for the next expedition. (...) The evolution of company bonds, adapting arrangements to suit new goals, was cut short when the EIC adopted the VOC share model in 1657."</ref>
* The establishment of the [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] (or [[:nl:Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser|Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser]] in Dutch), the world's first official [[stock exchange]],{{efn|The concept of the [[exchange (organized market)|bourse]] (or the [[exchange (organized market)|exchange]]) was 'invented' in the medieval [[Low Countries]], most notably in predominantly Dutch-speaking cities like [[Bruges]] and [[Antwerp]], before the birth of formal stock exchanges in the 17th century. From Flemish cities the term 'beurs' spread to other European states where it was corrupted into 'bourse', 'borsa', 'bolsa', 'börse', etc. In Britain, too, the term 'bourse' was used between 1550 and 1775, eventually giving way to the term 'royal exchange'. Until the early 1600s, a bourse was not exactly a [[stock exchange]] in its modern sense. With the founding of the [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC) in 1602 and the rise of Dutch capital markets in the early 17th century, the 'old' bourse (a place to trade [[Commodity market|commodities]], [[government bond|government]] and [[municipal bond]]s) found a new purpose – a formal exchange that specialize in creating and sustaining [[secondary market]]s in the [[Security (finance)|securities]] (such as [[corporate bond|bond]]s and [[share (finance)|share]]s of [[stock]]) issued by corporations – or a stock exchange as we know it today.<ref>Neal, Larry (2005). "Venture Shares of the Dutch East India Company", in Goetzmann & Rouwenhorst (eds.), pp. 165–175</ref>}} in 1611, along with the birth of the first fully functioning [[capital market]] in the early 1600s.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.ifa.com/articles/amsterdam_exchange |title=Amsterdam: Where It All Began |publisher=IFA.com (Index Fund Advisors, Inc.) |date=12 August 2012 |access-date=21 January 2017 }}</ref> While the [[Italian city-states]] produced the first transferable [[government bond]]s, they didn't develop the other ingredient necessary to produce the fully fledged [[capital market]] in its modern sense: a formal [[stock market]].<ref>[[John Brooks (writer)|Brooks, John]]: ''The Fluctuation: The Little Crash in '62'', in ''Business Adventures: Twelve Classic Tales from the World of Wall Street''. (New York: Weybright & Talley, 1968)</ref><ref name="Macaulay, Catherine R. 2015 p. 5"/><ref>Stringham, Edward Peter; Curott, Nicholas A.: ''On the Origins of Stock Markets'' [Part IV: ''Institutions and Organizations''; Chapter 14], pp. 324–344, in ''The Oxford Handbook of Austrian Economics'', edited by [[Peter J. Boettke]] and Christopher J. Coyne. (Oxford University Press, 2015, {{ISBN|978-0199811762}}). [[Edward Stringham|Edward P. Stringham]] & Nicholas A. Curott: "Business ventures with multiple shareholders became popular with ''commenda'' contracts in medieval Italy (Greif, 2006, p. 286), and Malmendier (2009) provides evidence that shareholder companies date back to ancient Rome. Yet the title of the world's first stock market deservedly goes to that of seventeenth-century Amsterdam, where an active secondary market in company shares emerged. The two major companies were the [[Dutch East India Company]] and the [[Dutch West India Company]], founded in 1602 and 1621. Other companies existed, but they were not as large and constituted a small portion of the stock market (Israel [1989] 1991, 109–112; Dehing and 't Hart 1997, 54; dela Vega [1688] 1996, 173)."</ref> The Dutch were the first to use a fully fledged capital market (including the [[bond market]] and stock market) to finance public companies (such as the [[Dutch East India Company|VOC]] and [[Dutch West India Company|WIC]]). This set a precedent for the global [[securities market]] in its modern form. In the early 1600s the VOC established an [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange|exchange in Amsterdam]] where VOC stock and bonds could be traded in a [[secondary market]]. The establishment of the Amsterdam Stock Exchange by the VOC has long been recognized as the origin of modern-day stock exchanges<ref>Neal, Larry (2005). "Venture Shares of the Dutch East India Company",, in ''The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets'', Goetzmann & Rouwenhorst (eds.), Oxford University Press, 2005, pp. 165–175</ref><ref>Petram, Lodewijk: ''The World's First Stock Exchange: How the Amsterdam Market for Dutch East India Company Shares Became a Modern Securities Market, 1602–1700''. Translated from the Dutch by Lynne Richards. (Columbia University Press, 2014, {{ISBN|9780231163781}})</ref> that specialize in creating and sustaining secondary markets in the [[Security (finance)|securities]] issued by corporations. The process of buying and selling [[share (finance)|shares]] (of stock) in the VOC became the basis of the first formal stock market.<ref>[[Robert Shiller|Shiller, Robert]] (2011). ''Economics 252, Financial Markets: Lecture 4 – Portfolio Diversification and Supporting Financial Institutions (Open Yale Courses) [Transcript]''</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.cnbc.com/id/101773977 |title=Is Asia the next financial center of the world? |publisher=[[CNBC.com]] |last=Murphy |first=Richard McGill |date=1 July 2014 |access-date=13 March 2018}}</ref> The Dutch pioneered [[Futures contract|stock futures]], [[stock options]], [[short selling]], [[bear raid]]s, debt-equity swaps, and other [[speculation|speculative instruments]]. Amsterdam businessman [[Joseph de la Vega]]'s ''Confusion of Confusions'' (1688) was the earliest book about [[stock trading]].<ref>[[Joseph de la Vega|De la Vega, Joseph]]: ''Confusión de confusiones (1688): Portions Descriptive of the Amsterdam Stock Exchange''. Selected and translated by Hermann Kellenbenz. ([[Cambridge, MA]]: Baker Library, Harvard Graduate School of Business Administration, 1957)</ref>
* The establishment of the [[Bank of Amsterdam]] ([[Amsterdamsche Wisselbank]]), often considered to be the first historical model of the [[central bank]],<ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2005). ''The Big Problem of Large Bills: The Bank of Amsterdam and the Origins of Central Banking''. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta (Working Paper 2005–16)</ref><ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William: ''An Economic Explanation of the Early Bank of Amsterdam, Debasement, Bills of Exchange, and the Emergence of the First Central Bank''. Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta (Working Paper 2006–13), 2006</ref><ref>Van Nieuwkerk, Marius (ed.): ''The Bank of Amsterdam: On the Origins of Central Banking''. (Amsterdam: Sonsbeek Publishers, 2009)</ref> in 1609. The birth of the Amsterdamsche Wisselbank led to the introduction of the concept of [[bank money]]. Along with a number of subsidiary local banks, it performed many functions of a [[central banking]] system.<ref>Kuzminski, Adrian: ''The Ecology of Money: Debt, Growth, and Sustainability''. (Lexington Books, 2013), p. 38</ref><ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2007). ''The Bank of Amsterdam and the Leap to Central Bank Money''. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 97, p262-5</ref><ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2008). ''Domestic Coinage and the Bank of Amsterdam''. (August 2008 Draft of Chapter 7 of the Wisselbankboek)</ref><ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2010). ''How Amsterdam Got Fiat Money''. (Working Paper 2010–17, December 2010)</ref><ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2012). ''The Bank of Amsterdam through the Lens of Monetary Competition''. (Working Paper 2012–14, September 2012)</ref> It occupied a central position in the financial world of its day, providing an effective, efficient and trusted system for national and international payments, and introduced the first ever [[international reserve currency]], the [[Dutch guilder|bank guilder]].<ref>Quinn, Stephen; Roberds, William (2014). ''Death of a Reserve Currency'', Atlanta Fed Working Paper 2014–17</ref> Lucien Gillard calls it the ''European guilder'' (''le florin européen''),<ref>Gillard, Lucien: ''La Banque d'Amsterdam et le florin européen au temps de la République néerlandaise, 1610–1820''. (Paris: Editions de l'Ecole des Hautes Etudes en Sciences Sociales, 420 p., 2004)</ref> and [[Adam Smith]] devotes many pages to explaining how the bank guilder works (Smith 1776: 446–455). The model of the Wisselbank as a [[state bank]] was adapted throughout Europe, including the [[Bank of Sweden]] (1668) and the [[Bank of England]] (1694).
* The formation of the first recorded professionally managed [[collective investment scheme]]s (or [[investment fund]]s), such as [[mutual fund]]s,<ref name="Goetzmann, William N. 2005">Goetzmann, William N.; Rouwenhorst, K. Geert (2005). ''The Origins of Value: The Financial Innovations that Created Modern Capital Markets''. (Oxford University Press, {{ISBN|978-0195175714}}))</ref><ref>Goetzmann, William N.; Rouwenhorst, K. Geert (2008). ''The History of Financial Innovation'', in ''Carbon Finance, Environmental Market Solutions to Climate Change''. (Yale School of Forestry and Environmental Studies, chapter 1, pp. 18–43). As Goetzmann & Rouwenhorst (2008) noted, "The 17th and 18th centuries in the Netherlands were a remarkable time for finance. Many of the financial products or instruments that we see today emerged during a relatively short period. In particular, merchants and bankers developed what we would today call [[securitization]]. Mutual funds and various other forms of structured finance that still exist today emerged in the 17th and 18th centuries in Holland."</ref> in 1774. Amsterdam-based businessman Abraham van Ketwich (also known as Adriaan van Ketwich) is often credited as the originator of the world's first mutual fund. In response to the [[crisis of 1772|financial crisis of 1772–1773]], Van Ketwich formed a trust named "Eendragt Maakt Magt" ("Unity Creates Strength"). His aim was to provide small investors with an opportunity to diversify.<ref name="Goetzmann, William N. 2005"/><ref name=geert>K. Geert Rouwenhorst (December 12, 2004), [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=636146 "The Origins of Mutual Funds"], Yale ICF Working Paper No. 04-48.</ref> Today the global funds industry is a multi-[[trillion]]-[[US dollar|dollar]] business.


The [[economic history]] of the Netherlands may be written from different perspectives. The following section approaches it as a [[Economic development|developing economy]], going through several stages, resembling a life-cycle. A sectoral approach may be found in other articles, such as [[Maritime history of the Netherlands]], [[Dutch East India Company]] and [[Dutch West India Company]] for trade; [[History of whaling#Spitsbergen|the Greenland and Spitsbergen Fishery]] for whaling; and [[Financial history of the Dutch Republic]] for banking and finance, plus sundry articles on the history of industries.
In many respects, the Dutch Republic's pioneering institutional innovations greatly helped revolutionize and shape the foundations of the economic and financial system of the modern-day world, and significantly influenced many English-speaking countries, especially the [[United Kingdom]] and [[United States]].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.newsweek.com/walter-russell-mead-why-lula-was-right-77431 |title=Walter Russell Mead on Why Lula Was Right (The Debt We Owe the Dutch: Blue-Eyed Bankers Have Given Us More Than the Current Financial Crisis) |publisher=Newsweek Magazine ([[newsweek.com]]) |author=Mead, Walter Russell |quote=[[Walter Russell Mead]] (2009): "[...] The modern [[financial system]] grows out of a series of innovations in 17th-century Netherlands, and the Dutch were, on the whole, as [[Luiz Inácio Lula da Silva|Lula]] describes them. From the Netherlands, what the English called "Dutch finance" traveled over the English Channel, as the English borrowed Dutch ideas to build a stock market, promote global trade and establish the [[Bank of England]]..." |date=18 April 2009 |access-date=28 January 2021 |author-link=Walter Russell Mead }}</ref><ref name="RDore">[[Ronald P. Dore|Dore, Ronald]]: ''Stock Market Capitalism, Welfare Capitalism: Japan and Germany versus the Anglo-Saxons''. (Oxford University Press, 2000) {{ISBN|978-0199240616}}</ref><ref>Sobel, Andrew C.: ''Birth of Hegemony: Crisis, Financial Revolution, and Emerging Global Networks''. (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2012)</ref>

==First modern economy==
[[File:Vereenigde Oostindische Compagnie spiegelretourschip Amsterdam replica.jpg|thumb|right|Replica of an [[East Indiaman]] of the [[Dutch East India Company]]/United East India Company ([[Verenigde Oostindische Compagnie|VOC]]). The VOC is often considered by many to be the world's first formally [[listing (finance)|listed]] [[public company]] and the first historical model of the multinational corporation (or [[transnational corporation]]) in its modern sense.]]
{{multiple image
| align = right
| direction = vertical
| header = The [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC) was an early corporate pioneer of [[List of countries by FDI abroad|outward foreign direct investment]] at the dawn of modern capitalism.<ref name="Brenner">[[Reuven Brenner|Brenner, Reuven]] (1994). ''Labyrinths of Prosperity: Economic Follies, Democratic Remedies''. (University of Michigan Press, 1994), p. 57-60</ref><ref name="Moore2010b">Moore, Jason W. (2010b). "'Amsterdam is Standing on Norway' Part II: The Global North Atlantic in the Ecological Revolution of the Long Seventeenth Century," Journal of Agrarian Change, 10, 2, p. 188–227</ref>
| width = 200
| image1 = Atlas Blaeu-Van der Hem - Taioan.jpg
| alt1 =
| caption1 = Overview of [[Fort Zeelandia (Taiwan)|Fort Zeelandia]] in [[Dutch Formosa]] (in the 17th-century). It was in [[Dutch Formosa|the Dutch rule period of Taiwan]] that [[Vereenigde Oostindische Compagnie|the VOC]] began to encourage large-scale [[mainland Chinese]] immigration.<ref>Chen, Piera; Gardner, Dinah: ''Lonely Planet: Taiwan'' [10th edition]. (Lonely Planet, 2017, {{ISBN|978-1786574398}}).</ref> The VOC's economic activities changed significantly the demographic and [[economic history of Taiwan|economic history of the island]].<ref name="Shih">Shih, Chih-Ming; Yen, Szu-Yin (2009). ''The Transformation of the Sugar Industry and Land Use Policy in Taiwan'', in ''Journal of Asian Architecture and Building Engineering'' [8:1], pp. 41–48</ref><ref name="Tseng">Tseng, Hua-pi (2016). ''Sugar Cane and the Environment under [[Dutch Formosa|Dutch Rule in Seventeenth Century Taiwan]]'', in ''Environmental History in the Making'', pp. 189–200</ref>

| image2 = Vignoble de Groot Constantia Afrique du Sud.jpg
| alt2 =
| caption2 = [[Groot Constantia]], the oldest [[wine estate]] in South Africa. The [[South African wine]] industry ([[New World wine]]) is among the lasting legacy of the [[Dutch Cape Colony|VOC era]].<ref name="Estreicher">Estreicher, Stefan K. (2014), 'A Brief [[History of South African wine|History of Wine in South Africa]],'. European Review 22(3): pp. 504–537. {{doi|10.1017/S1062798714000301}}</ref><ref name="Fourie&vonFintel">Fourie, Johan; von Fintel, Dieter (2014), 'Settler Skills and Colonial Development: The [[Huguenots in South Africa|Huguenot]] [[Winemaker|Wine-Maker]]s in Eighteenth-Century [[History of South Africa|Dutch South Africa]],'. The Economic History Review 67(4): 932–963. {{doi|10.1111/1468-0289.12033}}</ref> Like [[economic history of Taiwan|native economy of Taiwan in pre-VOC era]],<ref>Thompson, Laurence G. (1964), 'The Earliest Chinese Eyewitness Accounts of the [[Taiwanese indigenous peoples|Formosan Aborigines]],'. ''[[Monumenta Serica]]'' 23(1): 163–204. Laurence G. Thompson (1964) noted, "The most striking fact about the historical knowledge of [[History of Taiwan|Formosa]] is the lack of it in Chinese records. It is truly astonishing that this very large island, so close to the mainland that on exceptionally clear days it may be made out from certain places on the [[Fujian|Fukien]] coast with the unaided eye, should have remained virtually beyond the ken of Chinese writers down until late [[Ming dynasty|Ming times]] (seventeenth century)."</ref> [[History of South Africa|pre-1652 South Africa]] was virtually undeveloped or was in almost primitive state. In other words, the recorded [[economic history of South Africa]] [[economic history of Taiwan|and Taiwan]] both began with the VOC period.
}}
[[File:David Beck - Louis De Geer d.ä. 1587-1657.jpg|thumb|upright=0.9|In the early modern period, [[Walloons|Walloon]]-Dutch-Swedish businessman [[Louis De Geer (1587–1652)|Louis De Geer]] (1587–1652) was a pioneering [[entrepreneur]] and [[industrialist]] at the dawn of [[modern capitalism]].<ref name="Lindblad">Lindblad, J. Thomas (1995), 'Louis de Geer (1587–1652): Dutch Entrepreneur and the Father of Swedish Industry,'; in Clé Lesger & Leo Noordegraaf (eds.), ''Entrepreneurs and Entrepreneurship in Early Modern Times: Merchants and Industrialists within the Orbit of the Dutch Staple Markets''. (The Hague: Stichting Hollandse Historische Reeks, 1995), pp. 77–85</ref><ref name="Mueller">Müller, Leos (2005), 'The Dutch Entrepreneurial Networks and Sweden in the Age of Greatness,'; in Hanno Brand (ed.), ''Trade, Diplomacy and Cultural Exchange: Continuity and Change in the North Sea Area and the Baltic, c. 1350–1750''. (Hilversum: Verloren, 2005), pp. 58–74</ref>]]
While the inland provinces retained their premodern character for much longer, the Dutch Republic by about 1600 had maritime provinces [[Holland]], [[Zeeland]], [[Friesland]], [[Groningen (province)|Groningen]], and a part of [[Utrecht (province)|Utrecht]] that possessed:

* Reasonably pervasive and [[free market]]s for both [[Commodity|commodities]] and [[factors of production]]
* An agricultural import and [[agricultural productivity]] sufficient to sustain a far-reaching [[division of labor]]
* A political structure that guaranteed [[Property|property rights]], enforcement of contracts, and freedom of movement
* A level of technology and organization capable of sustained [[economic development]] and of supporting a material culture that could sustain [[market economy|market-oriented consumer behavior]]

The Dutch economy established a leadership role in Europe that was widely admired, and copied in part in England.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 693</ref>

Through productivity-enhancing investments in [[fixed capital]], the use of a large amount of energy (heat energy from [[peat]] as an industrial fuel, [[wind power]]) per worker, and a substantial investment in [[human capital]] (as witnessed by the high literacy rate), the Dutch managed to raise [[labor productivity]] above the levels prevailing in other European countries. This is illustrated by the fact that in the mid-17th century the agricultural sector, employing less than 40 percent of the labor force, could already almost be a net food exporter (which it became by 1800), and the fact that [[Real versus nominal value (economics)|nominal wage]]s between 1600 and 1800 were the highest in Europe. In the [[open economy]] of the Republic such a [[Economic inequality|wage gap]] could only be sustained by enduring productivity differences.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 694–95</ref>

[[File:Beursvankeyser.jpg|thumb|upright|[[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] (or [[:nl:Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser|Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser]] in Dutch)]]
[[File:Emanuel de Witte - De binnenplaats van de beurs te Amsterdam.jpg|thumb|upright|Courtyard of the [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] (or [[:nl:Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser|Beurs van Hendrick de Keyser]] in Dutch), the world's first official [[stock exchange]]. The [[Dutch Republic]]'s [[Financial history of the Dutch Republic|pioneering institutional innovations]] greatly helped revolutionize and shape the foundations of modern-day global investing. The formal [[stock market]], in its modern sense, was an institutional innovation by the [[Dutch East India Company|VOC]] managers and shareholders in the early 17th century. The first recorded professionally managed [[collective investment scheme]]s (or [[investment fund]]s), such as [[mutual fund]]s, were formed in the 18th-century Dutch Republic.]]

Another essential characteristic of a modern economy: the continuous accumulation and effective preservation of capital by a broad array of [[investment]] options, mediated by the ''[[Amsterdam Stock Exchange|Beurs]]'', and later the [[merchant bank]]s. Eventually, these financial structures proved unable to withstand the crises of the [[French Revolution|Revolutionary]] and [[Napoleonic era]], but the determining criterion here is that they were at least present during the period in question.

A defining characteristic of a modern economy is [[Diversification (finance)|diversification]] and an advanced [[division of labor]]. By the mid-17th century, under 40 percent of the labor force was employed in agriculture; whereas 30 percent was engaged in a highly diversified industrial sector, and the balance of the labor force was engaged in commerce and other service industries. The numerous cities formed a complex web of interdependencies, with the lesser ports performing specialized functions to the major ones; the industrial towns specializing in specific types of production; the countryside becoming highly differentiated by agricultural specialization, with the villages evolving into service centers (or later sometimes centers of [[Outsourcing|outsourced]] industrial production). The integration of specialized agriculture and industry with the growing [[entrepôt]] functions of the ports (at least before these functions became disaggregated again in the 18th century) imparted a special dynamism to the Dutch economy during the Golden Age economy.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 696–97</ref>

The decline in per capita income growth at the end of the 18th century may appear as a counterargument against the modernity of the Dutch economy. However, at closer inspection this was actually a modern process of restructuring in the face of adverse circumstances, as may be seen in current modern economies like the United States and European countries, that also undergo major structural upheavals. The 18th-century [[deindustrialization]] was in large part a consequence of a too-high [[real wage]] level, combined with [[protectionist]] policies of foreign governments, closing access to major markets. The agricultural depression was a general European phenomenon. The crisis in foreign trade was answered, and partly parried, with commercial innovations. The financial and fiscal crisis that proved the Republic's undoing was altogether modern in nature (unlike the comparable crises that regularly brought the [[Philip II of Spain|Spanish Crown]] to its knees), but simply happened before the modern means of dealing with it (expansion of the [[Tax|tax base]] and/or [[monetary inflation]]) were at hand.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 698–99</ref>

==Stages of development==

The [[economic history]] of the Netherlands may be written from different perspectives. The following section approaches it as a [[Economic development|developing economy]], going through several stages, resembling a life-cycle. A sectoral approach may be found in other articles, such as [[Maritime history of the Netherlands]], [[Dutch East India Company]] and [[Dutch West India Company]] for trade; [[History of whaling#The Greenland .26 Spitsbergen Fishery|the Greenland and Spitsbergen Fishery]] for whaling; and [[Financial history of the Dutch Republic]] for banking and finance, plus sundry articles on the history of industries.


===Pre-Revolt economy===
===Pre-Revolt economy===
Line 71: Line 20:
The territory of the northern maritime provinces that would later constitute the Dutch Republic (previously disparate [[Fiefdom|fief]]s of the [[Holy Roman Empire]]) were gathered together under the [[suzerainty]] of the [[Duchy of Burgundy]] in the late 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 29–35</ref> In the late [[Middle Ages]] these territories already formed part of a premodern economic system with its own measure of integration, brought about by intensive trade relations. That economic system formed the matrix in which the later economic development took place. The territory that would become the [[Southern Netherlands]] held a central position in this trade network at the time, while the provinces formed a periphery. [[Flanders]] and the [[Duchy of Brabant]] were further advanced industrially than Holland and Zeeland, and the metropolitan port city of [[Antwerp]] held the position of main entrepôt in northwestern Europe, as the hub in a far-flung trade web that spanned the whole known world. The ports in the northern provinces had only a regional importance, though [[Amsterdam]] had already built up a preponderant position in the [[Baltic region|Baltic]] trade, after making inroads on the monopoly of the [[Hanseatic League]] in the late 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 9–21</ref>
The territory of the northern maritime provinces that would later constitute the Dutch Republic (previously disparate [[Fiefdom|fief]]s of the [[Holy Roman Empire]]) were gathered together under the [[suzerainty]] of the [[Duchy of Burgundy]] in the late 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 29–35</ref> In the late [[Middle Ages]] these territories already formed part of a premodern economic system with its own measure of integration, brought about by intensive trade relations. That economic system formed the matrix in which the later economic development took place. The territory that would become the [[Southern Netherlands]] held a central position in this trade network at the time, while the provinces formed a periphery. [[Flanders]] and the [[Duchy of Brabant]] were further advanced industrially than Holland and Zeeland, and the metropolitan port city of [[Antwerp]] held the position of main entrepôt in northwestern Europe, as the hub in a far-flung trade web that spanned the whole known world. The ports in the northern provinces had only a regional importance, though [[Amsterdam]] had already built up a preponderant position in the [[Baltic region|Baltic]] trade, after making inroads on the monopoly of the [[Hanseatic League]] in the late 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 9–21</ref>


Although the northern provinces had an as yet subordinate position in the aggregate economy of the Habsburg Netherlands, let alone in the entire [[Charles V, Holy Roman Emperor|Habsburg empire]], they possessed economic features that set them apart from the rest of Europe, and presented them with opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Unlike other parts of Europe these lands had not been ravaged severely by the [[Black Death|plague]] of the 14th century, though like elsewhere that catastrophe contributed to scarcity of labor in the 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', p. 14</ref> The region also faced catastrophe of an ecological nature: the low-lying area was yet insufficiently protected against the sea and was repeatedly subjected to major flooding, of which the [[St. Elizabeth's flood (1421)]] was only one, although outstanding example. This resulted in a major permanent loss of arable land.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 27</ref> In addition, the land in the maritime provinces consisted mostly of peat bogs, which form poor land for agriculture, and were at the time extensively exploited for the fuel peat. This resulted again in extensive permanent loss of arable land.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 37–38</ref> Because of these losses many people were driven from the land and forced to seek employment in urban centers. This caused a degree of [[urbanization]] even larger than that in Flanders, but also a [[labor supply]] for non-agricultural purposes that was more [[Labour economics|elastic]] than elsewhere in Europe.<ref name="De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666">De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666</ref>
Although the northern provinces had an as yet subordinate position in the aggregate economy of the Habsburg Netherlands, let alone in the entire [[Charles V, Holy Roman Emperor|Habsburg empire]], they possessed economic features that set them apart from the rest of Europe, and presented them with opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Unlike other parts of Europe these lands had not been ravaged severely by the [[Black Death|plague]] [[pandemic]] of the 14th century, though like elsewhere that catastrophe contributed to scarcity of labor in the 15th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', p. 14</ref> The region also faced catastrophe of an ecological nature: the low-lying area was yet insufficiently protected against the sea and was repeatedly subjected to major flooding, of which the [[St. Elizabeth's flood (1421)]] was only an outstanding example. This resulted in a major permanent loss of arable land.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 27</ref> In addition, the land in the maritime provinces consisted mostly of peat bogs, which form poor land for agriculture, and were at the time extensively exploited for the fuel peat. This resulted again in extensive permanent loss of arable land.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 37–38</ref> Because of these losses many people were driven from the land and forced to seek employment in urban centers. This caused a degree of [[urbanization]] even larger than that in Flanders, but also a [[labor supply]] for non-agricultural purposes that was more [[Labour economics|elastic]] than elsewhere in Europe.<ref name="De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666">De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666</ref>


[[File:Papyrer-1568.png|thumb|250px|Paper maker]]
[[File:Papyrer-1568.png|thumb|250px|Paper maker]]


Although the immediate result of this [[elastic supply]] was downward pressure on wages, it also presented an opportunity for explosive growth when [[Aggregate demand|aggregate consumer demand]] in Europe finally rebounded from the long [[Recession|depression]] caused by the population losses of the pandemic. Besides, there were alternative employment opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Technological developments in fisheries (new methods of cleaning and preserving [[herring]] developed in the maritime provinces around this time) caused a major change in the economics of fisheries.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 243–44, 666</ref> Similar developments in shipping technology led to an explosion in seagoing trade. Finally, the development of dikes and drainage techniques ([[windmill]]s, [[sluice]]s) laid down the basis for new forms of agriculture ([[dairy]] farming) in the maritime provinces. These developments did not result directly in a major change in the economic structure of the Habsburg Netherlands. However, they provided a springboard for the developments that would follow the political upheaval that would become known as the [[Dutch Revolt]]<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 169–241</ref> in the second part of the 16th century.<ref name="De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666"/>
Although the immediate result of this [[elastic supply]] was downward pressure on wages, it also presented an opportunity for explosive growth when [[Aggregate demand|aggregate consumer demand]] in Europe finally rebounded from the long [[Recession|depression]], caused by the population losses of the pandemic. Besides, there were alternative employment opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Technological developments in fisheries (new methods of cleaning and preserving [[herring]] developed in the maritime provinces around this time) caused a major change in the economics of fisheries.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 243–44, 666</ref> Similar developments in shipping technology led to an explosion in seagoing trade. Finally, the development of dikes and drainage techniques ([[windmill]]s, [[sluice]]s) laid the base for new forms of agriculture ([[dairy]] farming) in the maritime provinces. These developments did not result directly in a major change in the economic structure of the Habsburg Netherlands. However, they provided a springboard for the developments that would follow the political upheaval that would become known as the [[Dutch Revolt]]<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 169–241</ref> in the second part of the 16th century.<ref name="De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666"/>


This political development had a number of important economic consequences. First of all, it led to an economic rupture with the [[Habsburg monarchy|Habsburg Empire]], seen as a loose economic entity. By the time the Revolt erupted the disadvantages of being part of this empire (heavy taxation to finance the military adventures of the Habsburg rulers) began to outweigh the advantages of belonging to its trade network. One of these advantages had been enjoying the services of the Antwerp entrepôt.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 667</ref>
This political development had a number of important economic consequences. First of all, it led to an economic rupture with the [[Habsburg Monarchy|Habsburg Empire]], seen as a loose economic entity. By the time the Revolt erupted the disadvantages of being part of this empire (heavy taxation to finance the military adventures of the Habsburg rulers) began to outweigh the advantages of belonging to its trade network. One of these advantages had been enjoying the services of the Antwerp entrepôt.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 667</ref>


In the economic and technological circumstances of the time such an [[entrepôt]] (or to use the Dutch term: ''stapelmarkt'') fulfilled important functions. The word has connotations of a duty-free port, but in an economic sense, a ''stapelmarkt'' was a place where commodities were temporarily physically stocked for future reexport. This was viable because of a legal monopoly for stockpiling a single commodity (wool), granted by a political ruler (like the [[staple port]]s designated by the kings of England in medieval times), but also more generally because of technical and economic reasons that still give certain advantages to a [[spoke-hub distribution paradigm]]. An important ancillary function of such a physical stock of commodities is that it makes it easier for merchants to even out supply fluctuations, and hence to control price gyrations in thin and [[Volatility (finance)|volatile]] markets. Finally, where a physical market forms, [[Efficient market hypothesis|market information]] can more easily be gathered. This was actually the most important economic function of a ''stapelmarkt'' in the circumstances of limited communication speed of the late 16th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 670, 690–92</ref>
In the economic and technological circumstances of the time such an [[entrepôt]] (or to use the Dutch term: ''stapelmarkt'') fulfilled important functions. The word has connotations of a duty-free port, but in an economic sense, a ''stapelmarkt'' was a place where commodities were temporarily physically stocked for future reexport. This was viable because of a legal monopoly for stockpiling a single commodity (wool), granted by a political ruler (like the [[staple port]]s designated by the kings of England in medieval times), but also more generally because of technical and economic reasons that still give certain advantages to a [[spoke-hub distribution paradigm]]. An important ancillary function of such a physical stock of commodities is that it makes it easier for merchants to even out supply fluctuations, and hence to control price gyrations in thin and [[Volatility (finance)|volatile]] markets. Finally, where a physical market forms, [[Efficient market hypothesis|market information]] can more easily be gathered. This was actually the most important economic function of a ''stapelmarkt'' in the primitive circumstances of the late 16th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 670, 690–92</ref>


Antwerp as entrepôt was already in decline before the Revolt, and before the [[Fall of Antwerp]], which sealed its fate as a major commercial center. But its demise started a scramble of other ports that wanted to take over its essential economic function, and Amsterdam (and to a lesser extent other major Dutch ports like [[Rotterdam]] and [[Enkhuizen]]) succeeded in doing so, though it was not a foregone conclusion that this prize would not go to London, [[Bremen]] or [[Hamburg]]. However, the political circumstances of the Revolt probably helped the displaced [[Calvinism|Calvinist]] merchants of Antwerp settle near their northern colinguals, and bring their money with them. More important, however, must have been the advantages of Amsterdam, which already gave it a strong position in the Baltic trades: elastic supplies of shipping and labor, low [[transaction cost]]s, and efficient markets.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 668</ref>
Antwerp-as-entrepôt was already in decline before the Revolt, and before the [[Fall of Antwerp]] that sealed its fate as a major commercial center. But its demise started a scramble of other ports that wanted to take over its essential economic function, and Amsterdam (and to a lesser extent other major Dutch ports like [[Rotterdam]] and [[Enkhuizen]]) succeeded in doing so, though it was not a foregone conclusion that this prize would not go to London, [[Bremen]] or [[Hamburg]]. However, the political circumstances of the Revolt probably helped the displaced [[Calvinism|Calvinist]] merchants of Antwerp settle near their northern coreligionists, and bring their money with them. More important, however, must have been the advantages of Amsterdam, which already gave it a strong position in the Baltic trades: elastic supplies of shipping and labor, low [[transaction cost]]s, and efficient markets.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 668</ref>


===The Golden Age===
===The Golden Age===
[[File:Een aantal Oostindiëvaarders voor de kust Rijksmuseum SK-A-3108.jpeg|thumb|250px|Dutch East-India Men by [[Hendrick Cornelis Vroom]]]]
[[File:Een aantal Oostindiëvaarders voor de kust Rijksmuseum SK-A-3108.jpeg|thumb|250px|Dutch East Indiamen by [[Hendrick Cornelisz Vroom]]]]
[[File:1 ducaton Utrecht, 1772.jpg|thumb|left|250px|[[Silver coin]]: 1 ducaton [[Utrecht]] - 1772]]
These developments set the stage for the era of explosive economic growth that is roughly coterminous with the period of social and cultural bloom that has been called the [[Dutch Golden Age]], and formed the material basis for that cultural era. During the numerous years of Dutch economic growth the average GDP per capita increased by 0.18 percent per annum; by about 1810 the growth rate was about 1 percent annually.<ref>{{cite book|author=Baten, Jörg |title=A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present.|date=2016|publisher=Cambridge University Press|page=15|isbn=9781107507180}}</ref> Amsterdam became the hub of world trade,<ref>Charles R. Boxer, ''The Dutch Seaborne Empire 1600–1800'' (1965)</ref> the center into which staples such as rye and luxuries flowed for sorting, processing, and distribution, and then were reexported around Europe and the world.<ref>{{cite book|author=Joost Jonker|title=Merchants, bankers, middlemen: the Amsterdam money market during the first half of the 19th century|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8xwWAQAAMAAJ|year=1996|publisher=NEHA|page=32|isbn=9789057420016}}</ref>


These developments set the stage for the era of explosive economic growth that is roughly coterminous with the period of social and cultural bloom that has been called the [[Dutch Golden Age]], and formed the material basis for that cultural era. During the numerous years of Dutch economic growth the average GDP per capita increased by 0.18 percent per annum; at about 1810 the growth rate was about 1 percent annually.<ref>{{cite book|author=Baten, Jörg |title=A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present.|date=2016|publisher=Cambridge University Press|page=15|isbn=9781107507180}}</ref> Amsterdam became the hub of world trade,<ref>Charles R. Boxer, ''The Dutch Seaborne Empire 1600–1800'' (1965)</ref> the center into which staples such as rye and luxuries flowed for sorting, processing, and distribution, and then were reexported around Europe and the world.<ref>{{cite book|author=Joost Jonker|title=Merchants, bankers, middlemen: the Amsterdam money market during the first half of the 19th century|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=8xwWAQAAMAAJ|year=1996|publisher=NEHA|page=32|isbn=9789057420016 |access-date=2016-10-14|archive-date=2016-07-23|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160723015701/https://books.google.com/books?id=8xwWAQAAMAAJ|url-status=live}}</ref>
In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totaled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total.<ref>{{cite book|author=Tim William Blanning|title=The Pursuit of Glory: Europe, 1648–1815|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=rmkcaEfwcsQC&pg=PA96|year=2007|publisher=Penguin|page=96|isbn=9780670063208}}</ref>

In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totalled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total.<ref>{{cite book|author=Tim William Blanning|title=The Pursuit of Glory: Europe, 1648–1815|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=rmkcaEfwcsQC&pg=PA96|year=2007|publisher=Penguin|page=96|isbn=9780670063208 |access-date=2016-10-14|archive-date=2016-05-27|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160527211632/https://books.google.com/books?id=rmkcaEfwcsQC&pg=PA96|url-status=live}}</ref>


====First stage: 1585–1622====
====First stage: 1585–1622====
A determining trait of the 1585 through 1622 period was the rapid accumulation of trade capital. The [[seed money]] for this expansion was brought in by displaced Antwerp merchants and by other European merchants (for instance the [[New Christian]]s who were displaced from the [[Iberian Peninsula|Iberian lands]] by religious persecution) that were quickly attracted by the new opportunities in Amsterdam. These merchants often invested in high-risk ventures like pioneering expeditions to the [[Mughal Empire]] to engage in the [[spice trade]]. These ventures were soon consolidated in the [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC). There were similar ventures in different fields, however, like the trade in Russia and the [[Levant]]. The profits of these ventures were ploughed back into financing new trade, which led to an exponential growth thereof.
A determining trait of the 1585 through 1622 period was the rapid accumulation of trade capital. The [[seed money]] for this expansion was brought in by displaced Antwerp merchants and by other European merchants (for instance the [[New Christian]]s who were displaced from the [[Iberian Peninsula|Iberian lands]] by religious persecution) that were quickly attracted by the new opportunities in Amsterdam. These merchants often invested in high-risk ventures like pioneering expeditions to the [[East Indies]] to engage in the [[spice trade]]. These ventures were soon consolidated in the [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC). There were similar ventures in different fields, however, like the trade in Russia and the [[Levant]]. The profits of these ventures were ploughed back into financing new trade, which led to an exponential growth thereof.


====Merchant capitalism====
====Merchant capitalism====
Dutch "[[merchant capitalism]]" was based on trading, shipping and finance rather than manufacturing or agriculture and marked the transition of the Dutch economy to a new stage. The accumulation of capital in the enormous amounts generated in this period caused demand for productive investment opportunities beside the immediate reinvestment in the own business. It also necessitated innovative institutional arrangements to bring demand and supply of investment funds together. From this period date the [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] and the [[Amsterdamsche Wisselbank]]. There were also innovations in [[marine insurance]] and legal structuring of firms like the [[joint stock company]]. These innovations helped manage [[risk]]. For example, ships were financed by shares, with each of, say 16 merchants, holding a 1/16 share. This minimized risk and maximized opportunity for windfall gains.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 690–93.</ref>
Dutch "[[merchant capitalism]]" was based on trading, shipping and finance rather than manufacturing or agriculture and marked the transition of the Dutch economy to a new stage. The accumulation of capital in the enormous amounts generated in this period caused demand for productive investment opportunities beside the immediate reinvestment in the own business. It also necessitated innovative institutional arrangements to bring demand and supply of investment funds together. From this period date the [[Amsterdam Stock Exchange]] and the [[Amsterdamsche Wisselbank]]. There were also innovations in [[marine insurance]] and legal structuring of firms like the [[joint stock company]]. These innovations helped manage [[risk]]. For example, ships were financed by shares, with each of 16 merchants, say, holding a 1/16 share. This minimized risk and maximized opportunity for windfall gains.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 690–93.</ref>


====Staples market====
====Staple market====
Even more important in this respect was the staples market (''stapelmarkt'') itself that helped to manage the risk of price fluctuations. Related instruments were the provision of [[trade credit]] to suppliers in order to secure favored access to raw materials (Dutch merchants routinely bought up grain harvests in the Baltic area and grape harvests in France, important in the wine trade, before they were harvested) and the financing of commodity trade with [[bill of exchange|bills of exchange]], which helped bind customers to the merchant.
Even more important in this respect was the staple market (''stapelmarkt'') itself that helped to manage the risk of price fluctuations. Related instruments were the provision of [[trade credit]] to suppliers in order to secure favored access to raw materials (Dutch merchants routinely bought up grain harvests in the Baltic area and grape harvests in France, important in the wine trade, before they were harvested) and the financing of commodity trade with [[bill of exchange|bills of exchange]], which helped bind customers to the merchant.


The system was not just geared to the reexport of commodities, but it also serviced a large domestic market, either as a final consumer, or as an intermediate user of [[raw material]]s and intermediate products for processing to finished products. The Republic was small, to be sure, but its urban population around 1650 was larger than that of the British Isles and Scandinavia combined. It was also larger than that of all German lands (admittedly devastated by the [[Thirty Years' War]] at the time).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 671</ref> This closeness to a sizable domestic market helped the Amsterdam market perform its price-stabilizing function.
The system was not just geared to reexport of commodities, but it also serviced a large domestic market, either as a final consumer, or as an intermediate user of [[raw material]]s and intermediate products for processing to finished products. The Republic was small, to be sure, but its urban population around 1650 was larger than that of the British Isles and Scandinavia combined. It was also larger than that of all German lands (admittedly devastated by the [[Thirty Years' War]] at the time).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 671</ref> This closeness to a sizable domestic market helped the Amsterdam market perform its price-stabilizing function.


====Technological innovations====
====Technological innovations====
The explosive growth in [[capital accumulation]] directly led to an equally explosive growth in investment in fixed capital for industries related to trade. Technological innovations like the wind-driven [[sawmill]] (re-invented by [[Cornelis Corneliszoon]] after the Leonardo da Vinci one), which significantly increased productivity in ship building, offered opportunities for profitable investment, as did the textile industries (mechanized [[fulling]], new [[Drapery|draperies]]) and other industries that made use of mechanization on the basis of wind power. This mechanization was based on yet another invention of Corneliszoon, for which he received a patent in 1597: a type of [[crankshaft]] that converted the continuous rotational movement of the wind (windmill) or river (water wheel) into a reciprocating one.
The explosive growth in [[capital accumulation]] directly led to an equally explosive growth in investment in fixed capital for industries related to trade. Technological innovations like the wind-driven [[sawmill]] (invented by [[Cornelis Corneliszoon]]), which significantly increased productivity in ship building, offered opportunities for profitable investment, as did the textile industries (mechanized [[fulling]], new [[Drapery|draperies]]) and other industries that made use of mechanization on the basis of wind power. This mechanization was based on yet another invention of Corneliszoon, for which he received a patent in 1597: a type of [[crankshaft]] that converted the continuous rotational movement of the wind (windmill) or river (water wheel) into a reciprocating one.


=====Shipbuilding=====
=====Shipbuilding=====
[[File:Wenceslas Hollar - A Flute (State 2).jpg|thumb|Dutch fluyt, 1677]]
[[File:Wenceslas Hollar - A Flute (State 2).jpg|thumb|Dutch fluyt, 1677]]


The Dutch built up by far the largest merchant fleet in the world. In the North Sea and Baltic there was little risk of piracy and trips shuttled between markets. In dangerous zones (where the risk of piracy or shipwreck was high) they traveled in convoys with a light guard.
The Dutch built the largest merchant fleet in the world. In the North Sea and Baltic there was little risk of piracy and trips shuttled between markets. In dangerous zones (where the risk of piracy or shipwreck was high) they traveled in convoys with a light guard.


A major technological advance was the design of the Dutch merchant ship known as the [[fluyt]]. Unlike rivals, it was not built for possible conversion in wartime to a warship, so it was cheaper to build and carried twice the cargo, and could be handled by a smaller crew. Construction by specialized shipyards using new tools made it half the cost of rival ships. The factors combined to sharply lower the cost of transportation for Dutch merchants, giving them a major competitive advantage.<ref>{{cite book|author=Jan de Vries|title=The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600–1750|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=XibqvuCdn1MC&pg=PA117|year=1976|publisher=Cambridge University Press|pages=117–18|isbn=9780521290500}}</ref>
A major technological advance was the design of the Dutch merchant ship known as the [[fluyt]]. Unlike rivals, it was not built for possible conversion in wartime to a warship, so it was cheaper to build and carried twice the cargo, and could be handled by a smaller crew. Construction by specialized shipyards using new tools made it half the cost of rival ships. The factors combined to sharply lower the cost of transportation for Dutch merchants, giving them a major competitive advantage.<ref>{{cite book|author=Jan de Vries|title=The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600–1750|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=XibqvuCdn1MC&pg=PA117|year=1976|publisher=Cambridge University Press|pages=117–18|access-date=2016-10-14|archive-date=2017-04-01|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170401065327/https://books.google.com/books?id=XibqvuCdn1MC&pg=PA117|url-status=live}}</ref>


The ship building district of [[Zaan]], near Amsterdam, became the first industrialized area in the world,<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 301–02</ref> with around 900 industrial windmills at the end of the 17th century, but there were industrialized towns and cities on a smaller scale also. Other industries that saw significant growth were [[papermaking]], [[Sugarcane|sugar refining]], printing, the [[linen]] industry (with spin-offs in vegetable oils, like [[flax]] and [[Rapeseed|rape oil]]), and industries that used the cheap peat fuel, like [[brewing]] and [[ceramic]]s ([[brickworks]], [[pottery]] and [[Smoking pipe (tobacco)|clay-pipe making]]).
The ship building district of [[Zaan]], near Amsterdam, had around 900 windmills at the end of the 17th century. Other industries that saw significant growth were [[papermaking]], [[Sugarcane|sugar refining]], printing, the [[linen]] industry (with spin-offs in vegetable oils, like [[flax]] and [[Rapeseed|rape oil]]), and industries that used the cheap peat fuel, like [[brewing]] and [[ceramic]]s ([[brickworks]], [[pottery]] and [[Smoking pipe (tobacco)|clay-pipe making]]).


====Textiles====
====Textiles====
Line 132: Line 81:
[[File:Trekschuit-nieuweramstel1730.JPG|thumb|250px|left|Horse-drawn barge]]
[[File:Trekschuit-nieuweramstel1730.JPG|thumb|250px|left|Horse-drawn barge]]


The result of worsening trade prospects between 1621 and 1663 was declining profitability, leading to reorientation of investment flows during this period. There was now much more investment in infrastructure, like the ''trekvaarten'', an extensive system of [[canal]]s that formed the basis of a sophisticated [[public transportation]] system, based on ''[[trekschuit]]en'' or [[horse-drawn boat]]s (later emulated during the industrial revolution in the [[History of the British canal system|British canal system]] and the [[Erie Canal]] in the U.S.). This was also a period of major [[land reclamation]] projects, the ''droogmakerijen'' of inland lakes like [[Beemster]] and [[Schermer]] that were drained by windmills and converted to [[polder]]s. In this way appreciable areas of fertile arable land were gained, reversing the trend of the 15th and 16th centuries. Finally, there was a tremendous boom in real estate investment, ranging from the extensions of cities like Amsterdam (where the famous [[Canals of Amsterdam|canal belts]] were built) to harbor improvements and fortifications. The total urban population was nearly doubled in the century after 1580, necessitating a commensurate boom in urban construction, which by 1640 assumed the proportions of a [[Economic bubble|speculative "bubble"]].<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 672</ref>
The result of worsening trade prospects between 1621 and 1663 was declining profitability, leading to reorientation of investment flows during this period. There was now much more investment in infrastructure, like the ''trekvaarten'', an extensive system of [[canal]]s that formed the basis of a [[public transportation]] system, based on ''[[trekschuit]]en'' or [[horse-drawn boat]]s. This was also a period of major [[land reclamation]] projects, the ''droogmakerijen'' of inland lakes like [[Beemster]] and [[Schermer]] that were drained by windmills and converted to [[polder]]s. In this way appreciable areas of fertile arable land were gained, reversing the trend of the 15th and 16th centuries. Finally, there was a tremendous boom in real estate investment, ranging from the extensions of cities like Amsterdam (where the famous [[Canals of Amsterdam|canal belts]] were built) to harbor improvements and fortifications. The total urban population was nearly doubled in the century after 1580, necessitating a commensurate boom in urban construction, which by 1640 assumed the proportions of a [[Economic bubble|speculative "bubble"]].<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 672</ref>


During the Thirty Years' War the Republic also played the role of the world's "arsenal". It had an extensive arms trade, using both the products of a sophisticated domestic arms industry (gun assembly and gun foundries), and foreign industries (the iron guns produced in the [[Wealden iron industry]] were extensively traded by the Dutch in the 1620s).<ref>Cf.{{aut|Puype, J. P., Hoeven, M. van der (ed.)}} (1996), ''The Arsenal of the World. The Dutch Arms Trade in the 17th Century'' Amsterdam, Batavian Lion International, {{ISBN|90-6707-413-6}}</ref> This trade also occasioned an episode in the industrial development of early-modern Sweden, where arms merchants like [[Louis De Geer (1587–1652)|Louis de Geer]] and the Trip brothers invested in iron mines and iron works, an early example of [[foreign direct investment]].<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 141, 378–79</ref>
During the Thirty Years' War the Republic also played the role of the world's "arsenal." It had an extensive arms trade, using both the products of a sophisticated domestic arms industry (gun assembly and gun foundries), and foreign industries (the iron guns produced in the [[Wealden iron industry]] were extensively traded by the Dutch in the 1620s).<ref>Cf.{{aut|Puype, J. P., Hoeven, M. van der (ed.)}} (1996), ''The Arsenal of the World. The Dutch Arms Trade in the 17th Century'' Amsterdam, Batavian Lion International, {{ISBN|90-6707-413-6}}</ref> This trade also occasioned an episode in the industrial development of early-modern Sweden, where arms merchants like [[Louis De Geer (1587–1652)|Louis de Geer]] and the Trip brothers invested in iron mines and iron works, an early example of [[foreign direct investment]].<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 141, 378–79</ref>


====Zenith in 1650s====
====Zenith in 1650s====
By the 1650s, when this boom period reached its zenith, the economy of the Republic achieved a classic harmony between its trading, industrial, agricultural, and fishing sectors, their interrelations cemented by productivity-enhancing investments. The gains in output had increased tremendously over the course of a century: the carrying capacity of the ocean-going fleet had increased by 1 percent annually; agricultural output per laborer had increased by 80 percent since 1500 (thanks to the pursuit of [[comparative advantage]] via agricultural specialization). The overall productivity of labor was reflected in the wage level, which was the highest in Europe at the time.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 672–73</ref>
[[File:De handelsloge van de VOC in Hougly in Bengalen Rijksmuseum SK-A-4282.jpeg|thumb|260px|[[Dutch East India Company]] factory in [[Hugli-Chuchura]], [[Mughal Bengal]]. ''Hendrik van Schuylenburgh, 1665'']]

By the 1650s, when this boom period reached its zenith, the economy of the Republic achieved a classic harmony between its trading, industrial, agricultural, and fishing sectors, their interrelations cemented by productivity-enhancing investments; and from the great investments in fixed equipment and its lucrative trade with the [[Mughal India|Mughal Empire]], it reached a period of [[proto-industrialization]]. The gains in output had increased tremendously over the course of a century: the carrying capacity of the ocean-going fleet had increased by 1 percent annually; agricultural output per laborer had increased by 80 percent since 1500 (thanks to the pursuit of [[comparative advantage]] via agricultural specialization). The overall productivity of labor was reflected in the wage level, which was the highest in Europe at the time.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 672–73</ref>


Although it is difficult to quantify concepts such as [[Gross domestic product]] and per-capita GDP in an age when reliable economic statistics were not gathered, De Vries and Van der Woude have nevertheless ventured to make a number of informed estimates, justified in their view, by the "modern" character of the Dutch economy in this period. They arrive at a size of the economy around 1660 that was approximately 45 percent of that of Britain (with two-and-a-half times the Dutch population).<ref>The preponderance of the Dutch population lived in two provinces, Holland and Zeeland. This area experienced a population explosion between 1500 and 1650, with a growth from 350,000 to 1,000,000 inhabitants. Thereafter the growth leveled off, so that the population of the whole country remained at the 2 million level throughout the 18th century; De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 51–52</ref> This works out at a per capita income that is 30 to 40 percent higher than that of Great Britain (admittedly still a premodern economy at the time).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 710</ref>
Although it is difficult to quantify concepts such as [[Gross domestic product]] and per-capita GDP in an age when reliable economic statistics were not gathered, De Vries and Van der Woude have nevertheless ventured to make a number of informed estimates, justified in their view, by the "modern" character of the Dutch economy in this period. They arrive at a size of the economy around 1660 that was approximately 45 percent of that of Britain (with two-and-a-half times the Dutch population).<ref>The preponderance of the Dutch population lived in two provinces, Holland and Zeeland. This area experienced a population explosion between 1500 and 1650, with a growth from 350,000 to 1,000,000 inhabitants. Thereafter the growth leveled off, so that the population of the whole country remained at the 2 million level throughout the 18th century; De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 51–52</ref> This works out at a per capita income that is 30 to 40 percent higher than that of Great Britain (admittedly still a premodern economy at the time).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 710</ref>
Line 145: Line 92:
===Retrenchment===
===Retrenchment===


This favorable economic constellation came to a rather abrupt end around 1670 as a consequence of two mutually reinforcing economic trends. The first was the rather abrupt closure of major European markets, especially France, for political reasons, as indicated in the previous section. This put an end to the heretofore secular increase in trade volumes for the Dutch economy. The effect of this stall probably would not have been as serious, but at approximately the same time the [[Market trends|secular trend of the price level]] had reversed from [[inflation]] to [[deflation]]. The whole of the 16th century, and the first half of the 17th century, had seen a rising price level. This now suddenly came to an end, to be replaced by deflationary tendencies that would last into the 1740s. Because of the tendency of nominal wages to be sticky downward, the already high level of real wages in the maritime provinces continued to rise, even though the business cycle went downward. This of course reinforced the trade depression in the short run, but in the longer run it caused a structural realignment of the Dutch economy.
This favorable economic constellation came to a rather abrupt end around 1670 as a consequence of two mutually reinforcing [[Economic history|economic trend]]s. The first was the rather abrupt closure of major European markets, especially France, for political reasons, as indicated in the previous section. This put an end to the heretofore secular increase in trade volumes for the Dutch economy. The effect of this stall probably would not have been as serious, but at approximately the same time the [[Macroeconomics|secular trend of the price level]] had reversed from [[inflation]] to [[deflation]]. The whole of the 16th century, and the first half of the 17th century, had seen a rising price level. This now suddenly came to an end, to be replaced by deflationary tendencies that would last into the 1740s. Because of the tendency of nominal wages to be sticky downward, the already high level of real wages in the maritime provinces continued to rise, even though the business cycle went downward. This of course reinforced the trade depression in the short run, but in the longer run it caused a structural realignment of the Dutch economy.


The reaction of Dutch industry and agriculture was a defensive realignment in three directions. First, there was a shift in the product mix to higher value products (for instance more luxury textile products, livestock fattening instead of dairy farming). This was of necessity a self-limiting solution, as it made exporting even more difficult, so this response led to a further contraction of the sectors in question. The second response was investment in labor-saving means of production. However, this required a level of technological innovation that apparently was no longer attainable. (In this respect it is remarkable that the number of patents granted in the Netherlands was remarkably lower in this period than in the first half of the 17th century.)<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 345–48</ref> Besides, this type of reorientation in investment was undercut by a third response: [[outsourcing]] of industrial production to areas with a lower wage level, like the [[Generality Lands]], which solved the high-wage problem in a different way, but also contributed to deindustralization in the maritime provinces.
The reaction of Dutch industry and agriculture was a defensive realignment in three directions. First, there was a shift in the product mix to higher value products (for instance more luxury textile products, livestock fattening instead of dairy farming). This was of necessity a self-limiting solution, as it made exporting even more difficult, so this response led to a further contraction of the sectors in question. The second response was investment in labor-saving means of production. However, this required a level of technological innovation that apparently was no longer attainable. (In this respect it is remarkable that the number of patents granted in the Netherlands was remarkably lower in this period than in the first half of the 17th century.)<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 345–48</ref> Besides, this type of reorientation in investment was undercut by a third response: [[outsourcing]] of industrial production to areas with a lower wage level, like the [[Generality Lands]], which solved the high-wage problem in a different way, but also contributed to deindustrialization in the maritime provinces.


The consequences of foreign protectionism were not all negative, however. Protectionist retaliation on the part of the Dutch government made all kinds of [[import-substitution industrialization]] possible, in for instance the production of sail cloth and the paper industry.
The consequences of foreign protectionism were not all negative, however. Protectionist retaliation on the part of the Dutch government made all kinds of [[import-substitution industrialization]] possible, in for instance the production of sail cloth and the paper industry.
Line 153: Line 100:
The main defensive response of the Dutch economy was in capital investment. The enormous capital stock amassed during the Golden Age was redirected away from investment in commerce, agricultural land (where rents went down appreciably in a short period of time), and real estate (house rents also sharply declined), and instead in the direction of other, rather high-risk investments. One of these was the [[History of whaling|whaling industry]] in which the ''[[Noordsche Compagnie]]'' had held a Dutch monopoly in the first half of the century. After its charter expired other companies entered this market, leading to an expansion of the Dutch whaling fleet from about 75 ships to 200 ships after 1660. The results were disappointing, however, due to [[overfishing]], a high [[price elasticity of demand]] due to substitutability of vegetable oils for whale oil, and the competition of foreign whalers.
The main defensive response of the Dutch economy was in capital investment. The enormous capital stock amassed during the Golden Age was redirected away from investment in commerce, agricultural land (where rents went down appreciably in a short period of time), and real estate (house rents also sharply declined), and instead in the direction of other, rather high-risk investments. One of these was the [[History of whaling|whaling industry]] in which the ''[[Noordsche Compagnie]]'' had held a Dutch monopoly in the first half of the century. After its charter expired other companies entered this market, leading to an expansion of the Dutch whaling fleet from about 75 ships to 200 ships after 1660. The results were disappointing, however, due to [[overfishing]], a high [[price elasticity of demand]] due to substitutability of vegetable oils for whale oil, and the competition of foreign whalers.


[[File:Triangular trade.png|thumb|250px|[[Triangular trade]] between western Europe, Africa and Americas]]
[[File:Triangular trade.png|thumb|250px|[[Triangular trade]] between Western Europe, Africa and Americas]]


Another important venue for investment after 1674 (when the second West India Company was launched, after the bankruptcy of its predecessor) was the [[Triangular trade|triangular]] [[slave trade]] and [[sugar]] trade, based on the plantations in recently acquired [[Suriname]] and [[Demerara]] (exchanged for [[New Amsterdam]] at the [[Treaty of Breda (1667)]]). This also gave a new impulse to the sugar refineries, which had been in a slump in 1680. This was one of the few boom sectors of the economy in this era: the slave population in Surinam quadrupled between 1682 and 1713, and the volume of sugar shipments rose from 3 to 15 million pounds per annum. This was in a period when the Dutch planters, unlike their English and French competitors, did not receive [[mercantilist]] protection.
Another important venue for investment after 1674 (when the second West India Company was launched, after the bankruptcy of its predecessor) was the [[Triangular trade|triangular]] [[History of slavery|slave trade]] and [[sugar]] trade, based on the plantations in recently acquired [[Suriname]] and [[Demerara]] (exchanged for [[New Amsterdam]] at the [[Treaty of Breda (1667)]]). This also gave a new impulse to the sugar refineries, which had been in a slump in 1680. This was one of the few boom sectors of the economy in this era: the slave population in Surinam quadrupled between 1682 and 1713, and the volume of sugar shipments rose from 3 to 15 million pounds per annum. This was in a period when the Dutch planters, unlike their English and French competitors, did not receive [[mercantilist]] protection.


Finally, a major target for investment was the [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC). The VOC encountered a rough patch around 1670, after a very profitable period up to that time. The causes were a [[price war]] for market share with the [[Honourable East India Company|English East India Company]] after the [[Third Anglo-Dutch War]], and an [[embargo]] on the export of precious metals (especially silver) by the Japanese [[Shogunate]], which ended the profitable intra-Asiatic trade the company had conducted up to that time (this business of trade within the East-Asian market had financed the spice trade of the company up to that time, and obviated the need to export European silver and gold to pay for Asian commodities it imported in Europe). The VOC now opted for a policy of great expansion of its business, by branching out to Asian bulk products, like textiles, [[coffee]], [[tea]] and [[porcelain]]. Other than the [[Black pepper|pepper]] and spices it had a near-[[monopoly]] on, these were high-volume low-profit commodities. The size of the company doubled in this period (making it the largest publicly traded company in the world at the time), but this was "profitless" growth that did not really solve the company's problems.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 673–78</ref>
Finally, a major target for investment was the [[Dutch East India Company]] (VOC). The VOC encountered a rough patch around 1670, after a very profitable period up to that time. The causes were a [[price war]] for market share with the [[Honourable East India Company|English East India Company]] after the [[Third Anglo-Dutch War]], and an [[embargo]] on the export of precious metals (especially silver) by the Japanese [[Shogunate]], which ended the profitable intra-Asiatic trade the company had conducted up to that time (this business of trade within the East-Asian market had financed the spice trade of the company up to that time, and obviated the need to export European silver and gold to pay for Asian commodities it imported in Europe). The VOC now opted for a policy of great expansion of its business, by branching out to Asian bulk products, like textiles, [[coffee]], [[tea]] and [[porcelain]]. Other than the [[Black pepper|pepper]] and spices it had a near-[[monopoly]] on, these were high-volume low-profit commodities. The size of the company doubled in this period (making it the largest publicly traded company in the world at the time), but this was "profitless" growth that did not really solve the company's problems.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 673–78</ref>
Line 161: Line 108:
This lack of profitability characterised all three investment activities just mentioned. {{cquote|In seeking to escape the limited returns offered by the old economic sectors, investors moved out the [[Risk-return spectrum|risk spectrum]]. However, this risk-taking [[entrepreneur]]ialism was not rewarded with the expected higher long-term rate of return, because the expansion of each sector entailed increased exposure to international competitive forces uncompensated by the market power of the entrepot or the sources of the domestic economy.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 678–79.</ref>}}
This lack of profitability characterised all three investment activities just mentioned. {{cquote|In seeking to escape the limited returns offered by the old economic sectors, investors moved out the [[Risk-return spectrum|risk spectrum]]. However, this risk-taking [[entrepreneur]]ialism was not rewarded with the expected higher long-term rate of return, because the expansion of each sector entailed increased exposure to international competitive forces uncompensated by the market power of the entrepot or the sources of the domestic economy.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 678–79.</ref>}}


The final reaction of the Dutch economic elite (which doubled as the political elite in this [[Oligarchy|oligarchical Republic]]) to these economic challenges lay in the political sphere. After the end of the Franco-Dutch War (which, like the previous wars was mostly financed by floating [[Bond (finance)|bonds]], instead of higher taxation) the [[public debt]] had risen to an alarming size. The [[Regenten|Regents]] at first tried to retire a significant part of this debt, and were successful in the years leading up to the Dutch invasion of England, known as the [[Glorious Revolution]] of 1688. Although this episode is usually described as narrowly English, or at most Anglo-Dutch of significance, it was actually part of a strategic defense of the Dutch Republic against the aggressive encroachments of king [[Louis XIV of France]].<ref>Jonathan I, Israel, "The Dutch Role in the Glorious Revolution" in: ''The Anglo-Dutch Moment. Essays on the Glorious Revolution and its world impact'', Cambridge University Press, (1991) pp. 116–20</ref> The ensuing [[Nine Years' War]] and [[War of the Spanish Succession]] had for the Dutch also an economic aspect, as they were trying to revert French protectionist measures, which threatened to close the French and Spanish metropolitan and colonial markets to them (both the [[Treaty of Ryswick]] and the [[Treaty of Utrecht]] contained provisions abrogating the draconian French [[tariff]] list of 1667). The main effect of these wars, however, was that the Dutch public debt increased with{{clarify|by? to?|date=September 2017}} 200 million guilders between 1688 and 1713. In view of the meagre results of the 1713 peace treaty (most advantages of the war that the Republic had helped to win went to Great Britain,<ref>For instance, Britain took over the lucrative [[Asiento]], which the Dutch had held previously.</ref> thanks to the separate peace that country had concluded previously with France) the gamble had not paid off.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 679–80.</ref>
The final reaction of the Dutch economic elite (which doubled as the political elite in this [[Oligarchy|oligarchical Republic]]) to these economic challenges lay in the political sphere. After the end of the Franco-Dutch War (which, like the previous wars was mostly financed by floating [[Bond (finance)|bonds]], instead of higher taxation) the [[public debt]] had risen to an alarming size. The [[Regenten|Regents]] at first tried to retire a significant part of this debt, and were successful in the years leading up to the end of the 1680s. The ensuing [[Nine Years' War]] and [[War of the Spanish Succession]] had for the Dutch also an economic aspect, as they were trying to revert French protectionist measures, which threatened to close the French and Spanish metropolitan and colonial markets to them (both the [[Treaty of Ryswick]] and the [[Treaty of Utrecht]] contained provisions abrogating the draconian French [[tariff]] list of 1667). The main effect of these wars, however, was that the Dutch public debt increased with{{clarify|by? to?|date=September 2017}} 200 million guilders between 1688 and 1713. In view of the meagre results of the 1713 peace treaty (most advantages of the war that the Republic had helped to win went to Great Britain,<ref>For instance, Britain took over the lucrative [[Asiento]], which the Dutch had held previously.</ref> thanks to the separate peace that country had concluded previously with France) the gamble had not paid off.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 679–80.</ref>


===Periwig era: the eighteenth-century economy===
===Periwig era: the eighteenth-century economy===
Although after the Peace of 1713 the Anglo-Dutch alliance of 1689 formally remained in place. With the Republic a guarantor of the Protestant Succession in Great Britain, it was obliged to send troops to England during the [[Jacobite rising of 1715|1715]] and [[Jacobite rising of 1745|1745]] uprisings of the [[Jacobite pretender]]s. Otherwise and in practice, the Republic embarked on a policy of [[Neutral country|neutrality]] during most of the 18th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 975, 985–88</ref> This placed Dutch shipping in an enviable protected position during the many wars of that century, provided the British [[Admiralty court]] was prepared to recognize the Dutch claim of "free ships make free goods"; this enabled the Republic to provide efficient shipping services with its still very large fleet to all European countries. But it eroded the power of the ''stapelmarkt'', as did the emergence of competitors like London and the German North Sea ports [[Bremen]] and [[Hamburg]]. This weakening of the province of Holland as a trade hub in its turn contributed to a disarticulation of the Dutch economic sectors trade, industry, banking and insurance, that had been highly integrated in the Golden Age. Each of those sectors embarked on its own growth path in the 18th-century Dutch economy.
Although after the Peace of 1713 the Anglo-Dutch alliance of 1689 formally remained in place. With the Republic a guarantor of the Protestant succession in Great Britain, it was obliged to send troops to England during the [[Jacobite rising of 1715|1715]] and [[Jacobite rising of 1745|1745]] uprisings of the [[Jacobite pretender]]s). Otherwise and in practice, the Republic embarked on a policy of [[Neutral country|neutrality]] during most of the 18th century.<ref>Israel, ''The Dutch Republic'', pp. 975, 985–88</ref> This placed Dutch shipping in an enviable protected position during the many wars of that century, provided the British [[Admiralty court]] was prepared to recognize the Dutch claim of "free ships make free goods"; this enabled the Republic to provide efficient shipping services with its still very large fleet to all European countries. But it eroded the power of the ''stapelmarkt'', as did the emergence of competitors like London and the German North Sea ports [[Bremen]] and [[Hamburg]]. This weakening of the province of Holland as a trade hub in its turn contributed to a disarticulation of the Dutch economic sectors trade, industry, banking and insurance, that had been highly integrated in the Golden Age. Each of those sectors embarked on its own growth path in the 18th-century Dutch economy.
[[File:Dutch personnel and Japanese women watching an incoming towed Dutch sailing ship at Dejima by Kawahara Keiga.jpg|thumb|Painting by Kawahara Keiga: ''Arrival of a Dutch Ship''. [[Philipp Franz von Siebold]] at [[Dejima]] with his Japanese wife Kusumoto Otaki and their baby-daughter [[Kusumoto Ine]] observing a VOC-ship arriving in the Nagasaki harbour using a [[telescope]].]]
[[File:Dutch personnel and Japanese women watching an incoming towed Dutch sailing ship at Dejima by Kawahara Keiga.jpg|thumb|Painting by Kawahara Keiga: ''Arrival of a Dutch Ship''. [[Philipp Franz von Siebold]] at [[Dejima]] with his Japanese wife Kusumoto Otaki and their baby-daughter [[Kusumoto Ine]] observing a VOC-ship arriving in the Nagasaki harbour using a [[telescope]].]]


Line 175: Line 122:
Meanwhile, this ''rentier''-class remained very frugal and saved most of its income, thereby amassing more capital that needed to be reinvested. As productive investments within the Republic were scarce (as explained above), they rationally looked for investment opportunities abroad. Ironically, such opportunities were often found in Great Britain, both in infrastructure developments, and in the British public debt that seemed as safe as the Dutch one (as these investors were very [[Risk aversion|risk-averse]]). But other foreign governments were also able to tap the Dutch market for savings by floating [[sovereign debt]] bonds with the assistance of Amsterdam [[merchant bank]]s that required hefty fees for their services (as the young American Republic discovered after [[John Adams]] successfully negotiated loans during the [[American Revolutionary War]]).<ref>By 1780 the net value of Dutch foreign government lending probably exceeded 350 million guilders, two-thirds of which in British government loans; De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 144. [[Alexander Hamilton]] consolidated the American federal foreign debt with a Dutch loan of $10 million in 1791; [[Willard Sterne Randall]], ''Alexander Hamilton: A Life'', Harper Collins 2003, {{ISBN|0-06-095466-3}}, pp. 374–75</ref> Amsterdam in this way became the 18th-century hub of [[international finance]], in tandem with London. The Amsterdam and London stock exchanges were closely aligned and quoted each other's stocks and bonds (Britain often used the Dutch financial institutions to pay subsidies to its allies and to settle its exchange bills in the Russian trade).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 139–47</ref>
Meanwhile, this ''rentier''-class remained very frugal and saved most of its income, thereby amassing more capital that needed to be reinvested. As productive investments within the Republic were scarce (as explained above), they rationally looked for investment opportunities abroad. Ironically, such opportunities were often found in Great Britain, both in infrastructure developments, and in the British public debt that seemed as safe as the Dutch one (as these investors were very [[Risk aversion|risk-averse]]). But other foreign governments were also able to tap the Dutch market for savings by floating [[sovereign debt]] bonds with the assistance of Amsterdam [[merchant bank]]s that required hefty fees for their services (as the young American Republic discovered after [[John Adams]] successfully negotiated loans during the [[American Revolutionary War]]).<ref>By 1780 the net value of Dutch foreign government lending probably exceeded 350 million guilders, two-thirds of which in British government loans; De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 144. [[Alexander Hamilton]] consolidated the American federal foreign debt with a Dutch loan of $10 million in 1791; [[Willard Sterne Randall]], ''Alexander Hamilton: A Life'', Harper Collins 2003, {{ISBN|0-06-095466-3}}, pp. 374–75</ref> Amsterdam in this way became the 18th-century hub of [[international finance]], in tandem with London. The Amsterdam and London stock exchanges were closely aligned and quoted each other's stocks and bonds (Britain often used the Dutch financial institutions to pay subsidies to its allies and to settle its exchange bills in the Russian trade).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 139–47</ref>


The Dutch balance of payments was in surplus most of the time, because a small [[Current account (balance of payments)|deficit on trade in goods]] (because the propensity to import was high as a consequence of the skewed income distribution), was more than compensated by a surplus in trade in services (such as shipping), and a surplus on the income account. The revenues from foreign investment amounted to 15 million guilders annually by 1770, and twice that by 1790. The consequence was a preview of the "[[Dutch disease]]" of the 20th century, where a strong guilder (also caused by a structural balance-of-payments surplus) discouraged exports, as it did in the 18th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 681–83</ref>
The Dutch balance of payments was in surplus most of the time, because a small deficit on the [[Current account (balance of payments)|current account]] (because the propensity to import was high as a consequence of the skewed income distribution), was more than compensated by "invisibles", like the income from shipping services, and the revenues from foreign investment. The latter amounted to 15 million guilders annually by 1770, and twice that by 1790. The consequence was a preview of the "[[Dutch disease]]" of the 20th century, where a strong guilder (also caused by a structural balance-of-payments surplus) discouraged exports, as it did in the 18th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 681–83</ref>


Although compared to the boom years of the Golden Age the 18th-century Dutch economy looked less attractive (which earned this epoch the disdainful epithet "[[wig|periwig]] era" in the Dutch [[Orangism (Netherlands)|Orangist]] historiography of the 19th century), it still had its strengths. The "decline" of the economy as a whole was more relative, compared to its competitors, than absolute. The disappearance of whole industries, though regrettable, was no more than a consequence of secular economic trends, like the comparable industrial realignments of the 20th century (incidentally, in both cases the textile industry was involved). One could even say that by the shift from industry to "service" sectors, the structure of the Dutch economy became even more "modern". (Indeed, one may see an analogy with the changes in the mature British economy a century later). However, the degree of foreign direct investment by the Dutch at the end of the 18th century was even greater than that of the British at the beginning of the 20th century: more than twice GNP versus 1.5 times GNP).<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 146</ref>
Although compared to the boom years of the Golden Age the 18th-century Dutch economy looked less attractive (which earned this epoch the disdainful epithet "[[wig|periwig]] era" in the Dutch [[Orangism (Netherlands)|Orangist]] historiography of the 19th century), it still had its strengths. The "decline" of the economy as a whole was more relative, compared to its competitors, than absolute. The disappearance of whole industries, though regrettable, was no more than a consequence of secular [[Economic indicator|economic trend]]s, like the comparable industrial realignments of the 20th century (ironically, in both cases the textile industry was involved). One could even say that by the shift from industry to "service" sectors, the structure of the Dutch economy became even more "modern" (Indeed, one may see an analogy with the changes in the mature British economy a century later). However, the degree of foreign direct investment by the Dutch at the end of the 18th century was even greater than that of the British at the beginning of the 20th century: more than twice GNP versus 1.5 times GNP.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 146</ref>


Another measure of the performance of the Dutch economy during the 18th century is the estimate that De Vries and Van der Woude have made of the [[Gross domestic product|per capita GDP]] of the Dutch economy in 1742 (for which year tax records provide a basis for estimation and extrapolation). They arrive at an estimated GNP of between 265 and 280 million guilders, or 135–142 [[Dutch guilder|guilders]] per capita. This was at the end of a long period of secular decline after the economic zenith of 1650. The next decades saw some economic resurgence. In the decade 1800–1810 (again a period of economic decline) the national income of the (slightly contracted) population can be estimated at 307 million guilders, or 162 guilders per capita. To put all of this in perspective: in 1740 the GNP of Great Britain was about £80 million, or 120 guilders per capita (and therefore about 20 percent lower than the Dutch per capita income). After this the British per capita income started on a rapid increase, due to the Industrial Revolution. It therefore eventually overtook the Dutch per capita income, but probably only around 1800.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 699–710</ref>
Another measure of the performance of the Dutch economy during the 18th century is the estimate that De Vries and Van der Woude have made of the [[Gross domestic product|per capita GDP]] of the Dutch economy in 1742 (for which year tax records provide a basis for estimation and extrapolation). They arrive at an estimated GNP of between 265 and 280 million guilders, or 135–142 [[Dutch guilder|guilders]] per capita. This was at the end of a long period of secular decline after the economic zenith of 1650. The next decades saw some economic resurgence. In the decade 1800–1810 (again a period of economic decline) the national income of the (slightly contracted) population can be estimated at 307 million guilders, or 162 guilders per capita. To put all of this in perspective: in 1740 the GNP of Great Britain was about £80 million, or 120 guilders per capita (and therefore about 20 percent lower than the Dutch per capita income). After this the British per capita income started on a rapid increase, due to the Industrial Revolution. It therefore eventually overtook the Dutch per capita income, but probably only around 1800.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 699–710</ref>
Line 185: Line 132:
===Final crisis===
===Final crisis===


After 1780, a new conjuncture of internal and external conditions conspired to drive the economy and political structure of the Republic to crisis. The [[Fourth Anglo-Dutch War]] ended the cloak of neutrality that had protected Dutch shipping for most of the century, obviating during that period the need for naval protection that was now lacking due to many years of neglect of the navy. Trade came temporarily to a standstill, because the British blockade could not be broken, as exemplified by the Dutch failure in the [[Battle of Dogger Bank (1781)]]. The trade of the VOC was devastated, even apart from the loss of some of its colonies. It experienced a [[liquidity crisis]], which exposed its inherent [[insolvency]]. The company was too important to let it fail (also because of the importance of its outstanding debt in the Dutch financial system), so that it was kept afloat for more than a decade by emergency aid from the [[States of Holland]], before it was finally nationalized in 1796.
After 1780, a new conjuncture of internal and external conditions conspired to drive the economy and political structure of the Republic to crisis. The [[Fourth Anglo-Dutch War]] ended the cloak of neutrality that had protected Dutch shipping for most of the century, obviating during that period the need for naval protection that was now lacking due to many years of neglect of the navy. Trade came temporarily to a standstill, because the British blockade could not be broken, despite the relative success of the Dutch navy in the [[Battle of Dogger Bank (1781)]]. The trade of the VOC was devastated, even apart from the loss of some of its colonies. It experienced a [[liquidity crisis]], which exposed its inherent [[insolvency]]. The company was too important to let it fail (also because of the importance of its outstanding debt in the Dutch financial system), so that it was kept afloat for more than a decade by emergency aid from the [[States of Holland]], before it was finally nationalized in 1796.


[[File:L'arsenal_de_la_VOC.jpg|250px|right|thumb|The Arsenal of the VOC]]
[[File:L'arsenal_de_la_VOC.jpg|250px|right|thumb|The arsenal of the VOC]]


Attempts at political reform (and attendant reform of the derelict system of public finance) by the [[Patriots (Dutch Republic)|Patriots]] were thwarted by the suppression of their revolt by the [[Frederick William II of Prussia|Prussian]] intervention in the quarrel with [[Stadtholder]] [[William V, Prince of Orange|William V]] in 1787. This meant that no further attempts at reform were made until the overthrow of the old Republic and its replacement by the Batavian Republic in 1795.<ref>Schama, pp. 64–138</ref> That [[puppet state]] of the French Republic was unable to get the freedom of movement from its "sister republic", that would have been necessary to bring about effective reforms, even though the Patriots now had the chance to force them through. An enormous new tax burden to finance transfer payments to France (a war indemnity of 100 million guilders and annual maintenance costs of 12 million guilders of an army of occupation), amounting to 230 million guilders total, broke the back of the fiscal system. Eventually, the public debt was forced into [[Default (finance)|default]] (though only when the Netherlands were annexed to [[First French Empire|imperial France]] in 1810).
Attempts at political reform (and attendant reform of the derelict system of public finance) by the [[Patriots (Dutch Republic)|Patriots]] were thwarted by the suppression of their revolt by the [[Frederick William II of Prussia|Prussian]] intervention in the quarrel with [[Stadtholder]] [[William V, Prince of Orange|William V]] in 1787. This meant that no further attempts at reform were made until the overthrow of the old Republic and its replacement by the Batavian Republic in 1795.<ref>Schama, pp. 64–138</ref> That [[puppet state]] of the French Republic was unable to get the freedom of movement from its "sister republic", that would have been necessary to bring about effective reforms, even though the Patriots now had the chance to force them through. An enormous new tax burden to finance transfer payments to France (a war indemnity of 100 million guilders and annual maintenance costs of 12 million guilders of an army of occupation), amounting to 230 million guilders total, broke the back of the fiscal system. Eventually, the public debt was forced into [[Default (finance)|default]] (though only when the Netherlands were annexed to [[First French Empire|imperial France]] in 1810).
Line 197: Line 144:
It is therefore fitting to see the year 1815, in which the [[United Kingdom of the Netherlands]] embodied a newly independent political incorporation of the original Habsburg Netherlands, as the end of an economic era also. The hoped for economic resurgence of the Netherlands (other than that of the Southern Netherlands with which it was now temporarily reunited) would, however, not really take flight before the structural problems of the old economy were finally laid to rest around 1850 with the final liquidation of the public debt of the old Republic. This explains at least partly why the Dutch economy was so tardy in implementing the steam-power based industrial revolution of the 19th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 687</ref>
It is therefore fitting to see the year 1815, in which the [[United Kingdom of the Netherlands]] embodied a newly independent political incorporation of the original Habsburg Netherlands, as the end of an economic era also. The hoped for economic resurgence of the Netherlands (other than that of the Southern Netherlands with which it was now temporarily reunited) would, however, not really take flight before the structural problems of the old economy were finally laid to rest around 1850 with the final liquidation of the public debt of the old Republic. This explains at least partly why the Dutch economy was so tardy in implementing the steam-power based industrial revolution of the 19th century.<ref>De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 687</ref>


==See also==
==References==
* [[Financial history of the Dutch Republic]]


==Notes==
{{notelist}}

==References==
{{reflist|2}}
{{reflist|2}}


==Further reading==
==Further reading==
* de Vries, Johan. "Benelux, 1920–1970", in C. M. Cipolla, ed. ''The Fontana Economic History of Europe: Contemporary Economics Part One'' (1976) pp.&nbsp;1–71
* Dhondt, Jan, and Marinette Bruwier in Carlo Cipolla, ''The Emergence of Industrial Societies-1'' (Fontana, 1970) pp.&nbsp;329–55
* Dhondt, Jan, and Marinette Bruwier in Carlo Cipolla, ''The Emergence of Industrial Societies-1'' (Fontana, 1970) pp.&nbsp;329–55
* Houtte, J. A. Van. "Economic Development of Belgium and the Netherlands from the Beginning of the Modern Era", ''Journal of European Economic History''(1972), 1:100–20
* Houtte, J. A. Van. "Economic Development of Belgium and the Netherlands from the Beginning of the Modern Era", ''Journal of European Economic History''(1972), 1:100–20
Line 215: Line 158:
* [[Simon Schama|Schama, S.]] (1977), ''Patriots and Liberators. Revolution in the Netherlands 1780–1813'', New York, Vintage books, {{ISBN|0-679-72949-6}}
* [[Simon Schama|Schama, S.]] (1977), ''Patriots and Liberators. Revolution in the Netherlands 1780–1813'', New York, Vintage books, {{ISBN|0-679-72949-6}}
* [[Simon Schama|Schama, S.]] ''[[The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in the Golden Age]]'' (1997)
* [[Simon Schama|Schama, S.]] ''[[The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in the Golden Age]]'' (1997)
* de Vries, Johan. "Benelux, 1920–1970", in C. M. Cipolla, ed. ''The Fontana Economic History of Europe: Contemporary Economics Part One'' (1976) pp.&nbsp;1–71
* Vries, J. de, and Woude, A. van der. (1997), ''The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815'', Cambridge University Press, {{ISBN|978-0-521-57825-7}}
* Vries, J. de, and Woude, A. van der. (1997), ''The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815'', Cambridge University Press, {{ISBN|978-0-521-57825-7}}
**Riel, Arthur van. "Review: Rethinking the Economic History of the Dutch Republic: The Rise and Decline of Economic Modernity Before the Advent of Industrialized Growth Nederland 1500–1815..." ''Journal of Economic History'' (1996) 56#1 pp.&nbsp;223–29 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2124027 in JSTOR], review
**Riel, Arthur van. "Review: Rethinking the Economic History of the Dutch Republic: The Rise and Decline of Economic Modernity Before the Advent of Industrialized Growth Nederland 1500–1815..." ''Journal of Economic History'' (1996) 56#1 pp.&nbsp;223–29 [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2124027 in JSTOR], review
* Wilson, C. H. “The Economic Decline of the Netherlands.” ''Economic History Review'' 9#2 (1939), pp.&nbsp;111–127. [https://jstor.org/stable/2590218 online], covers 1600 to 1800/


==External links==
==External links==
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20071213194949/http://www.balticconnections.net/index.cfm?article=Baltic+Sea+Trade Baltic Trade]
* [http://www.balticconnections.net/index.cfm?article=Baltic+Sea+Trade Baltic Trade] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20071213194949/http://www.balticconnections.net/index.cfm?article=Baltic+Sea+Trade |date=2007-12-13 }}
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20160304001808/http://esfdb.websites.bta.com/table.aspx?resourceid=11377 Expenditure of the United Provinces, 1586–1648 ]
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20160304001808/http://esfdb.websites.bta.com/table.aspx?resourceid=11377 Expenditure of the United Provinces, 1586–1648 ]
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20160305105025/http://esfdb.websites.bta.com/table.aspx?resourceid=11585 Customs revenue from the admiralties of Amsterdam and Rotterdam, 1587–1715]
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20160305105025/http://esfdb.websites.bta.com/table.aspx?resourceid=11585 Customs revenue from the admiralties of Amsterdam and Rotterdam, 1587–1715]
Line 227: Line 168:


{{Economic history of the Netherlands}}
{{Economic history of the Netherlands}}
{{Europe topic|Economic history of}}
{{Economic history}}
{{Economic history}}



Latest revision as of 01:40, 20 October 2024

English and Dutch ships taking on stores at port, by Jacob Knyff

The economic history of the Netherlands (1500–1815) covers the Netherlands as the Habsburg Netherlands, through the era of the Dutch Republic, the Batavian Republic and the Kingdom of Holland.

After becoming de facto independent from the empire of Philip II of Spain around 1585 the country experienced almost a century of explosive economic growth. The young Republic become the dominant trade power by the mid-17th century, partly due to its shipbuilding. In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totalled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total. Pillars of this position were the dominance of the Amsterdam Entrepôt in European trade, and that of the Dutch East and West India Companies (VOC and WIC) in intercontinental trade. The Dutch society had possibly the highest standard of living in Europe (and probably in the world) by the middle of the 17th century. Affluence facilitated a Golden Age in culture typified by the artist Rembrandt van Rijn (1606–1669).

However, around 1670 a combination of politico-military upheavals (wars with France and England) and adverse economic developments (a break in the upward secular trend of price levels) brought the Dutch economic boom to an abrupt end. This caused a retrenchment of the Dutch economy in the period up to 1713, in which the industrial sector was partly dismantled and growth in trade leveled off. The economy struck out in new directions, including whaling, colonial plantations in Suriname, and new types of trade with Asia. However, these riskier ventures often failed to bring commensurate gains. The VOC embarked on a period of profitless growth. The financial strength proved more durable, enabling the Netherlands to play the role of a major power in the European conflicts around the turn of the 18th century by hiring mercenary armies and subsidizing its allies.

These conflicts put an enormous strain on the resources of the Republic, however, and for that reason the Republic (like its opponent, the France of Louis XIV) was deeply in debt at the end of the War of the Spanish Succession. The regents of the Republic more or less abandoned its Great-Power pretensions after 1713, cutting down on its military preparedness in a vain attempt to pay down this overhang of public debt. That debt brought a significant rentier class into being that helped change the nature of the economy from one invested primarily in trade and industry into one in which a significant financial sector played a dominant role. By the end of the 18th century the Republic was the major market for sovereign debt, and a major source of foreign direct investment.

Wars with Great Britain and France at the end of the 18th century, and attendant political upheavals, caused a financial and economic crisis from which the economy was unable to recover. After the successors of the Republic (the Batavian Republic and the Kingdom of Holland) were forced to engage in policies of economic warfare against the French Empire, which proved disastrous for Dutch trade and industry; most of the gains of the previous two centuries were rapidly lost. The newly independent Kingdom of the Netherlands was faced in 1815 with an economy that was largely deindustrialized and deurbanized, but still saddled with a crippling public debt, which it was forced to repudiate (the first time that the Dutch state defaulted since the dark pre-independence days of the Revolt).

Development

[edit]

The economic history of the Netherlands may be written from different perspectives. The following section approaches it as a developing economy, going through several stages, resembling a life-cycle. A sectoral approach may be found in other articles, such as Maritime history of the Netherlands, Dutch East India Company and Dutch West India Company for trade; the Greenland and Spitsbergen Fishery for whaling; and Financial history of the Dutch Republic for banking and finance, plus sundry articles on the history of industries.

Pre-Revolt economy

[edit]

The territory of the northern maritime provinces that would later constitute the Dutch Republic (previously disparate fiefs of the Holy Roman Empire) were gathered together under the suzerainty of the Duchy of Burgundy in the late 15th century.[1] In the late Middle Ages these territories already formed part of a premodern economic system with its own measure of integration, brought about by intensive trade relations. That economic system formed the matrix in which the later economic development took place. The territory that would become the Southern Netherlands held a central position in this trade network at the time, while the provinces formed a periphery. Flanders and the Duchy of Brabant were further advanced industrially than Holland and Zeeland, and the metropolitan port city of Antwerp held the position of main entrepôt in northwestern Europe, as the hub in a far-flung trade web that spanned the whole known world. The ports in the northern provinces had only a regional importance, though Amsterdam had already built up a preponderant position in the Baltic trade, after making inroads on the monopoly of the Hanseatic League in the late 15th century.[2]

Although the northern provinces had an as yet subordinate position in the aggregate economy of the Habsburg Netherlands, let alone in the entire Habsburg empire, they possessed economic features that set them apart from the rest of Europe, and presented them with opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Unlike other parts of Europe these lands had not been ravaged severely by the plague pandemic of the 14th century, though like elsewhere that catastrophe contributed to scarcity of labor in the 15th century.[3] The region also faced catastrophe of an ecological nature: the low-lying area was yet insufficiently protected against the sea and was repeatedly subjected to major flooding, of which the St. Elizabeth's flood (1421) was only an outstanding example. This resulted in a major permanent loss of arable land.[4] In addition, the land in the maritime provinces consisted mostly of peat bogs, which form poor land for agriculture, and were at the time extensively exploited for the fuel peat. This resulted again in extensive permanent loss of arable land.[5] Because of these losses many people were driven from the land and forced to seek employment in urban centers. This caused a degree of urbanization even larger than that in Flanders, but also a labor supply for non-agricultural purposes that was more elastic than elsewhere in Europe.[6]

Paper maker

Although the immediate result of this elastic supply was downward pressure on wages, it also presented an opportunity for explosive growth when aggregate consumer demand in Europe finally rebounded from the long depression, caused by the population losses of the pandemic. Besides, there were alternative employment opportunities that did not exist elsewhere. Technological developments in fisheries (new methods of cleaning and preserving herring developed in the maritime provinces around this time) caused a major change in the economics of fisheries.[7] Similar developments in shipping technology led to an explosion in seagoing trade. Finally, the development of dikes and drainage techniques (windmills, sluices) laid the base for new forms of agriculture (dairy farming) in the maritime provinces. These developments did not result directly in a major change in the economic structure of the Habsburg Netherlands. However, they provided a springboard for the developments that would follow the political upheaval that would become known as the Dutch Revolt[8] in the second part of the 16th century.[6]

This political development had a number of important economic consequences. First of all, it led to an economic rupture with the Habsburg Empire, seen as a loose economic entity. By the time the Revolt erupted the disadvantages of being part of this empire (heavy taxation to finance the military adventures of the Habsburg rulers) began to outweigh the advantages of belonging to its trade network. One of these advantages had been enjoying the services of the Antwerp entrepôt.[9]

In the economic and technological circumstances of the time such an entrepôt (or to use the Dutch term: stapelmarkt) fulfilled important functions. The word has connotations of a duty-free port, but in an economic sense, a stapelmarkt was a place where commodities were temporarily physically stocked for future reexport. This was viable because of a legal monopoly for stockpiling a single commodity (wool), granted by a political ruler (like the staple ports designated by the kings of England in medieval times), but also more generally because of technical and economic reasons that still give certain advantages to a spoke-hub distribution paradigm. An important ancillary function of such a physical stock of commodities is that it makes it easier for merchants to even out supply fluctuations, and hence to control price gyrations in thin and volatile markets. Finally, where a physical market forms, market information can more easily be gathered. This was actually the most important economic function of a stapelmarkt in the primitive circumstances of the late 16th century.[10]

Antwerp-as-entrepôt was already in decline before the Revolt, and before the Fall of Antwerp that sealed its fate as a major commercial center. But its demise started a scramble of other ports that wanted to take over its essential economic function, and Amsterdam (and to a lesser extent other major Dutch ports like Rotterdam and Enkhuizen) succeeded in doing so, though it was not a foregone conclusion that this prize would not go to London, Bremen or Hamburg. However, the political circumstances of the Revolt probably helped the displaced Calvinist merchants of Antwerp settle near their northern coreligionists, and bring their money with them. More important, however, must have been the advantages of Amsterdam, which already gave it a strong position in the Baltic trades: elastic supplies of shipping and labor, low transaction costs, and efficient markets.[11]

The Golden Age

[edit]
Dutch East Indiamen by Hendrick Cornelisz Vroom

These developments set the stage for the era of explosive economic growth that is roughly coterminous with the period of social and cultural bloom that has been called the Dutch Golden Age, and formed the material basis for that cultural era. During the numerous years of Dutch economic growth the average GDP per capita increased by 0.18 percent per annum; at about 1810 the growth rate was about 1 percent annually.[12] Amsterdam became the hub of world trade,[13] the center into which staples such as rye and luxuries flowed for sorting, processing, and distribution, and then were reexported around Europe and the world.[14]

In 1670, the Dutch merchant marine totalled 568,000 tons of shipping—about half the European total.[15]

First stage: 1585–1622

[edit]

A determining trait of the 1585 through 1622 period was the rapid accumulation of trade capital. The seed money for this expansion was brought in by displaced Antwerp merchants and by other European merchants (for instance the New Christians who were displaced from the Iberian lands by religious persecution) that were quickly attracted by the new opportunities in Amsterdam. These merchants often invested in high-risk ventures like pioneering expeditions to the East Indies to engage in the spice trade. These ventures were soon consolidated in the Dutch East India Company (VOC). There were similar ventures in different fields, however, like the trade in Russia and the Levant. The profits of these ventures were ploughed back into financing new trade, which led to an exponential growth thereof.

Merchant capitalism

[edit]

Dutch "merchant capitalism" was based on trading, shipping and finance rather than manufacturing or agriculture and marked the transition of the Dutch economy to a new stage. The accumulation of capital in the enormous amounts generated in this period caused demand for productive investment opportunities beside the immediate reinvestment in the own business. It also necessitated innovative institutional arrangements to bring demand and supply of investment funds together. From this period date the Amsterdam Stock Exchange and the Amsterdamsche Wisselbank. There were also innovations in marine insurance and legal structuring of firms like the joint stock company. These innovations helped manage risk. For example, ships were financed by shares, with each of 16 merchants, say, holding a 1/16 share. This minimized risk and maximized opportunity for windfall gains.[16]

Staple market

[edit]

Even more important in this respect was the staple market (stapelmarkt) itself that helped to manage the risk of price fluctuations. Related instruments were the provision of trade credit to suppliers in order to secure favored access to raw materials (Dutch merchants routinely bought up grain harvests in the Baltic area and grape harvests in France, important in the wine trade, before they were harvested) and the financing of commodity trade with bills of exchange, which helped bind customers to the merchant.

The system was not just geared to reexport of commodities, but it also serviced a large domestic market, either as a final consumer, or as an intermediate user of raw materials and intermediate products for processing to finished products. The Republic was small, to be sure, but its urban population around 1650 was larger than that of the British Isles and Scandinavia combined. It was also larger than that of all German lands (admittedly devastated by the Thirty Years' War at the time).[17] This closeness to a sizable domestic market helped the Amsterdam market perform its price-stabilizing function.

Technological innovations

[edit]

The explosive growth in capital accumulation directly led to an equally explosive growth in investment in fixed capital for industries related to trade. Technological innovations like the wind-driven sawmill (invented by Cornelis Corneliszoon), which significantly increased productivity in ship building, offered opportunities for profitable investment, as did the textile industries (mechanized fulling, new draperies) and other industries that made use of mechanization on the basis of wind power. This mechanization was based on yet another invention of Corneliszoon, for which he received a patent in 1597: a type of crankshaft that converted the continuous rotational movement of the wind (windmill) or river (water wheel) into a reciprocating one.

Shipbuilding
[edit]
Dutch fluyt, 1677

The Dutch built the largest merchant fleet in the world. In the North Sea and Baltic there was little risk of piracy and trips shuttled between markets. In dangerous zones (where the risk of piracy or shipwreck was high) they traveled in convoys with a light guard.

A major technological advance was the design of the Dutch merchant ship known as the fluyt. Unlike rivals, it was not built for possible conversion in wartime to a warship, so it was cheaper to build and carried twice the cargo, and could be handled by a smaller crew. Construction by specialized shipyards using new tools made it half the cost of rival ships. The factors combined to sharply lower the cost of transportation for Dutch merchants, giving them a major competitive advantage.[18]

The ship building district of Zaan, near Amsterdam, had around 900 windmills at the end of the 17th century. Other industries that saw significant growth were papermaking, sugar refining, printing, the linen industry (with spin-offs in vegetable oils, like flax and rape oil), and industries that used the cheap peat fuel, like brewing and ceramics (brickworks, pottery and clay-pipe making).

Textiles

[edit]

The explosive growth of the textiles industries in several specialized Dutch cities, like Enschede (woollen cloth), Haarlem (linen), and Amsterdam (silk) was mainly caused by the influx of skilled workers and capital from the Southern Netherlands in the final decades of the 16th century, when Calvinist entrepreneurs and workers were forced to leave the Spanish-dominated areas. It was therefore not due to a specific technological development, but more to the fact that a whole industry migrated, lock, stock, and barrel, to the Northern Netherlands, thus reinvigorating the northern textile industry, that had been moribund before the Revolt.[19]

Labor force

[edit]

This rapid industrialization may be indirectly illustrated by the rapid growth of the nonagricultural labor force and the increase in real wages during the same time (which usually would have a negative correlation, instead of a positive one). In the half-century between 1570 and 1620 this labor supply increased 3 percent per annum, a truly phenomenal growth. Despite this, nominal wages were repeatedly increased, outstripping price increases. In consequence, real wages for unskilled laborers were 62 percent higher in 1615–1619 than in 1575–1579.[20]

Fisheries

[edit]

Another important growth sector were the fisheries, especially the herring fishery (also known as the "Great Fishery"), already important in pre-Revolt days, because of the Flemish invention of gibbing, which made better preservation possible, experienced a tremendous growth due to the development of a specialized ship type, the Herring Buss by the late 16th century. This was a veritable "factory ship" that enabled Dutch herring fishermen to follow the herring to the shoals of the Dogger Bank and other places far from the Dutch shores, and stay away for months at a time. Actually, linked to the fishery itself was an important onshore processing industry that prepared the salted herring for export across Europe. It also attracted its own supporting industries, like salt refining and the salt trade; fishing net manufacture; and specialized shipbuilding. The fisheries were not particularly profitable in themselves (they were already a mature industry by 1600), but organizational innovations (vertical integration of production, processing, and trade) enabled an efficient business model, in which the traders used the revenues of fishing to buy up grain in Baltic ports during the winter months (when otherwise the fishing boats would have been idle), which they transported to Western Europe when the ice floes thawed in Spring. The revenues of this incidental trade were invested in unrefined salt or new boats. The industry was also supported by the Dutch government by market regulation (under the tutelage of an industry body, the Commissioners of the Great Fishery), and naval protection of the fishing fleet against privateers and the Royal Navy (because the English looked askance at Dutch fishing in waters they claimed). The combination of these factors secured a de facto monopoly for Dutch soused herring in the two centuries between 1500 and 1700.[21]

Art and tulips

[edit]
A tulip, known as "the Viceroy", displayed in a 1637 Dutch catalog. Its bulb cost between 3,000 and 4,200 guilders (florins) depending on size. A skilled craftsman at the time earned about 300 guilders a year.

During this period the flourishing of Dutch painters became emblematic of the Golden Age in Dutch culture. At the time, this was just an industry like many others, with offshoots like chemical pigment making.[22] Its rise illustrates the general boom conditions in the country, like the horticultural developments that laid the basis for the sophisticated tulip farming sector (which had its own speculative bubble, known as the tulip mania). By 1636, the tulip bulb became the fourth leading export product of the Netherlands – after gin, herring and cheese. The price of tulips skyrocketed because of speculation in tulip futures among people who never saw the bulbs. Many men made and lost fortunes overnight, to the consternation of Calvinists who abhorred this artificial frenzy that denied the virtues of moderation, discretion and genuine work.[23]

Wars with Spain and England

[edit]

The phenomenal growth in trade slowed somewhat in the years after the recommencement of the Eighty Years' War with Spain in 1621 (the end of the Twelve Years' Truce). That recommencement offered the possibility of extending trade to the Western Hemisphere (indeed, the Dutch West India Company was founded in 1621), but elsewhere the Dutch were increasingly pushing up against European rivals in a struggle for market share. The competitive advantages of the more efficient Dutch shippers invited protectionist countermeasures, like the English Navigation Acts in the mid-17th century, the French tariff system, instituted under Jean-Baptiste Colbert, and similar protectionist measures instituted by Sweden at the same time. These protectionist measures caused a number of trade wars and military conflicts, like the Anglo-Dutch Wars of the 17th century, the Dutch-Swedish War, and the Franco-Dutch War (though the latter had a more general politico-military character, like the later conflicts between the Republic and France; these wars had an important economic component too, though).

Horse-drawn barge

The result of worsening trade prospects between 1621 and 1663 was declining profitability, leading to reorientation of investment flows during this period. There was now much more investment in infrastructure, like the trekvaarten, an extensive system of canals that formed the basis of a public transportation system, based on trekschuiten or horse-drawn boats. This was also a period of major land reclamation projects, the droogmakerijen of inland lakes like Beemster and Schermer that were drained by windmills and converted to polders. In this way appreciable areas of fertile arable land were gained, reversing the trend of the 15th and 16th centuries. Finally, there was a tremendous boom in real estate investment, ranging from the extensions of cities like Amsterdam (where the famous canal belts were built) to harbor improvements and fortifications. The total urban population was nearly doubled in the century after 1580, necessitating a commensurate boom in urban construction, which by 1640 assumed the proportions of a speculative "bubble".[24]

During the Thirty Years' War the Republic also played the role of the world's "arsenal." It had an extensive arms trade, using both the products of a sophisticated domestic arms industry (gun assembly and gun foundries), and foreign industries (the iron guns produced in the Wealden iron industry were extensively traded by the Dutch in the 1620s).[25] This trade also occasioned an episode in the industrial development of early-modern Sweden, where arms merchants like Louis de Geer and the Trip brothers invested in iron mines and iron works, an early example of foreign direct investment.[26]

Zenith in 1650s

[edit]

By the 1650s, when this boom period reached its zenith, the economy of the Republic achieved a classic harmony between its trading, industrial, agricultural, and fishing sectors, their interrelations cemented by productivity-enhancing investments. The gains in output had increased tremendously over the course of a century: the carrying capacity of the ocean-going fleet had increased by 1 percent annually; agricultural output per laborer had increased by 80 percent since 1500 (thanks to the pursuit of comparative advantage via agricultural specialization). The overall productivity of labor was reflected in the wage level, which was the highest in Europe at the time.[27]

Although it is difficult to quantify concepts such as Gross domestic product and per-capita GDP in an age when reliable economic statistics were not gathered, De Vries and Van der Woude have nevertheless ventured to make a number of informed estimates, justified in their view, by the "modern" character of the Dutch economy in this period. They arrive at a size of the economy around 1660 that was approximately 45 percent of that of Britain (with two-and-a-half times the Dutch population).[28] This works out at a per capita income that is 30 to 40 percent higher than that of Great Britain (admittedly still a premodern economy at the time).[29]

Retrenchment

[edit]

This favorable economic constellation came to a rather abrupt end around 1670 as a consequence of two mutually reinforcing economic trends. The first was the rather abrupt closure of major European markets, especially France, for political reasons, as indicated in the previous section. This put an end to the heretofore secular increase in trade volumes for the Dutch economy. The effect of this stall probably would not have been as serious, but at approximately the same time the secular trend of the price level had reversed from inflation to deflation. The whole of the 16th century, and the first half of the 17th century, had seen a rising price level. This now suddenly came to an end, to be replaced by deflationary tendencies that would last into the 1740s. Because of the tendency of nominal wages to be sticky downward, the already high level of real wages in the maritime provinces continued to rise, even though the business cycle went downward. This of course reinforced the trade depression in the short run, but in the longer run it caused a structural realignment of the Dutch economy.

The reaction of Dutch industry and agriculture was a defensive realignment in three directions. First, there was a shift in the product mix to higher value products (for instance more luxury textile products, livestock fattening instead of dairy farming). This was of necessity a self-limiting solution, as it made exporting even more difficult, so this response led to a further contraction of the sectors in question. The second response was investment in labor-saving means of production. However, this required a level of technological innovation that apparently was no longer attainable. (In this respect it is remarkable that the number of patents granted in the Netherlands was remarkably lower in this period than in the first half of the 17th century.)[30] Besides, this type of reorientation in investment was undercut by a third response: outsourcing of industrial production to areas with a lower wage level, like the Generality Lands, which solved the high-wage problem in a different way, but also contributed to deindustrialization in the maritime provinces.

The consequences of foreign protectionism were not all negative, however. Protectionist retaliation on the part of the Dutch government made all kinds of import-substitution industrialization possible, in for instance the production of sail cloth and the paper industry.

The main defensive response of the Dutch economy was in capital investment. The enormous capital stock amassed during the Golden Age was redirected away from investment in commerce, agricultural land (where rents went down appreciably in a short period of time), and real estate (house rents also sharply declined), and instead in the direction of other, rather high-risk investments. One of these was the whaling industry in which the Noordsche Compagnie had held a Dutch monopoly in the first half of the century. After its charter expired other companies entered this market, leading to an expansion of the Dutch whaling fleet from about 75 ships to 200 ships after 1660. The results were disappointing, however, due to overfishing, a high price elasticity of demand due to substitutability of vegetable oils for whale oil, and the competition of foreign whalers.

Triangular trade between Western Europe, Africa and Americas

Another important venue for investment after 1674 (when the second West India Company was launched, after the bankruptcy of its predecessor) was the triangular slave trade and sugar trade, based on the plantations in recently acquired Suriname and Demerara (exchanged for New Amsterdam at the Treaty of Breda (1667)). This also gave a new impulse to the sugar refineries, which had been in a slump in 1680. This was one of the few boom sectors of the economy in this era: the slave population in Surinam quadrupled between 1682 and 1713, and the volume of sugar shipments rose from 3 to 15 million pounds per annum. This was in a period when the Dutch planters, unlike their English and French competitors, did not receive mercantilist protection.

Finally, a major target for investment was the Dutch East India Company (VOC). The VOC encountered a rough patch around 1670, after a very profitable period up to that time. The causes were a price war for market share with the English East India Company after the Third Anglo-Dutch War, and an embargo on the export of precious metals (especially silver) by the Japanese Shogunate, which ended the profitable intra-Asiatic trade the company had conducted up to that time (this business of trade within the East-Asian market had financed the spice trade of the company up to that time, and obviated the need to export European silver and gold to pay for Asian commodities it imported in Europe). The VOC now opted for a policy of great expansion of its business, by branching out to Asian bulk products, like textiles, coffee, tea and porcelain. Other than the pepper and spices it had a near-monopoly on, these were high-volume low-profit commodities. The size of the company doubled in this period (making it the largest publicly traded company in the world at the time), but this was "profitless" growth that did not really solve the company's problems.[31]

This lack of profitability characterised all three investment activities just mentioned.

In seeking to escape the limited returns offered by the old economic sectors, investors moved out the risk spectrum. However, this risk-taking entrepreneurialism was not rewarded with the expected higher long-term rate of return, because the expansion of each sector entailed increased exposure to international competitive forces uncompensated by the market power of the entrepot or the sources of the domestic economy.[32]

The final reaction of the Dutch economic elite (which doubled as the political elite in this oligarchical Republic) to these economic challenges lay in the political sphere. After the end of the Franco-Dutch War (which, like the previous wars was mostly financed by floating bonds, instead of higher taxation) the public debt had risen to an alarming size. The Regents at first tried to retire a significant part of this debt, and were successful in the years leading up to the end of the 1680s. The ensuing Nine Years' War and War of the Spanish Succession had for the Dutch also an economic aspect, as they were trying to revert French protectionist measures, which threatened to close the French and Spanish metropolitan and colonial markets to them (both the Treaty of Ryswick and the Treaty of Utrecht contained provisions abrogating the draconian French tariff list of 1667). The main effect of these wars, however, was that the Dutch public debt increased with[clarification needed] 200 million guilders between 1688 and 1713. In view of the meagre results of the 1713 peace treaty (most advantages of the war that the Republic had helped to win went to Great Britain,[33] thanks to the separate peace that country had concluded previously with France) the gamble had not paid off.[34]

Periwig era: the eighteenth-century economy

[edit]

Although after the Peace of 1713 the Anglo-Dutch alliance of 1689 formally remained in place. With the Republic a guarantor of the Protestant succession in Great Britain, it was obliged to send troops to England during the 1715 and 1745 uprisings of the Jacobite pretenders). Otherwise and in practice, the Republic embarked on a policy of neutrality during most of the 18th century.[35] This placed Dutch shipping in an enviable protected position during the many wars of that century, provided the British Admiralty court was prepared to recognize the Dutch claim of "free ships make free goods"; this enabled the Republic to provide efficient shipping services with its still very large fleet to all European countries. But it eroded the power of the stapelmarkt, as did the emergence of competitors like London and the German North Sea ports Bremen and Hamburg. This weakening of the province of Holland as a trade hub in its turn contributed to a disarticulation of the Dutch economic sectors trade, industry, banking and insurance, that had been highly integrated in the Golden Age. Each of those sectors embarked on its own growth path in the 18th-century Dutch economy.

Painting by Kawahara Keiga: Arrival of a Dutch Ship. Philipp Franz von Siebold at Dejima with his Japanese wife Kusumoto Otaki and their baby-daughter Kusumoto Ine observing a VOC-ship arriving in the Nagasaki harbour using a telescope.

As far as industry and agriculture were concerned, the trends that were set in motion in the transitional period after 1670 continued unabated. The Dutch economy remained a high-real-wage and high-tax economy, which discouraged investment in labor-intensive pursuits. This caused a decline of labor-intensive industries, like the textile industry, and of capital-goods industries like shipbuilding (both suffering from a lack of innovation also, which made it even more difficult to conquer foreign markets). That decline was only partially compensated by the growth of industries requiring proximity to ports, or large inputs of skilled labor (which was still in abundant supply) and fixed capital. The agricultural sector, faced with the same pressures, specialized in two directions: less labor-intensive livestock raising on the one hand, and very labor-intensive industrial crop production on the other. Trade shifted from the intra-European "mother trade" serving the Baltic and the Mediterranean to intercontinental trade (colonial wares) and distribution to the German hinterland (which was now a rising market again, after finally recovering from the ravages of the Thirty Years' War). Trade changed in other respects also: shipping became more of a service industry, offering shipping services to merchants of other countries. Trade-related financial services shifted from direct financing to acceptance credit.[36]

The herring fisheries were severely damaged by French privateers during the War of the Spanish Succession. This caused a collapse of the industry in the first decade of the 18th century, from which the industry did not recover. The size of the Enkhuizen fleet halved compared to the previous century. A second sharp contraction of the herring fleet occurred in the years 1756–61. This was due to an equally sharp reduction in revenue in these years. Meanwhile, foreign competitors profited from easier access to the fishing grounds (Scandinavians), lower wages (Scots), or protection (English). They also were not bound to the Dutch regulations that aimed to guarantee the quality of the Dutch product. This challenge induced the industry to go "up market" by improving quality further, thus being able to charge premium prices.[37]

A distinctive trait of the Dutch economy emerging in the 18th century was the fiscal-financial complex. The historically large public debt, resulting from the Republic's participation in the European wars around the turn of the 18th century, was held by a small percentage of the Dutch population (there was hardly any external debt). This implied that the Dutch fiscal system now became yoked to the service of this debt in a way that served the interests of this small rentier class. No less than 70 percent of the annual revenue of the province of Holland (the main debtor) had to be dedicated to debt service. These revenues consisted mainly of regressive indirect taxes with the perverse effect that income was transferred from the poorer classes to the richer to the amount of 14 million guilders a year (approximately 7 percent of the Gross National Product at the time).[38] This debt burden rested preponderantly on the tax payers from Holland, as the finances of the provinces were separated in the confederal system of the Republic, and this unequal debt burden militated against other provinces agreeing to fiscal reform. Fiscal reform was also opposed by the rentiers that had a vested interest in retaining their interest income, but not in paying (direct) income taxes to pay for the debt service.

Meanwhile, this rentier-class remained very frugal and saved most of its income, thereby amassing more capital that needed to be reinvested. As productive investments within the Republic were scarce (as explained above), they rationally looked for investment opportunities abroad. Ironically, such opportunities were often found in Great Britain, both in infrastructure developments, and in the British public debt that seemed as safe as the Dutch one (as these investors were very risk-averse). But other foreign governments were also able to tap the Dutch market for savings by floating sovereign debt bonds with the assistance of Amsterdam merchant banks that required hefty fees for their services (as the young American Republic discovered after John Adams successfully negotiated loans during the American Revolutionary War).[39] Amsterdam in this way became the 18th-century hub of international finance, in tandem with London. The Amsterdam and London stock exchanges were closely aligned and quoted each other's stocks and bonds (Britain often used the Dutch financial institutions to pay subsidies to its allies and to settle its exchange bills in the Russian trade).[40]

The Dutch balance of payments was in surplus most of the time, because a small deficit on the current account (because the propensity to import was high as a consequence of the skewed income distribution), was more than compensated by "invisibles", like the income from shipping services, and the revenues from foreign investment. The latter amounted to 15 million guilders annually by 1770, and twice that by 1790. The consequence was a preview of the "Dutch disease" of the 20th century, where a strong guilder (also caused by a structural balance-of-payments surplus) discouraged exports, as it did in the 18th century.[41]

Although compared to the boom years of the Golden Age the 18th-century Dutch economy looked less attractive (which earned this epoch the disdainful epithet "periwig era" in the Dutch Orangist historiography of the 19th century), it still had its strengths. The "decline" of the economy as a whole was more relative, compared to its competitors, than absolute. The disappearance of whole industries, though regrettable, was no more than a consequence of secular economic trends, like the comparable industrial realignments of the 20th century (ironically, in both cases the textile industry was involved). One could even say that by the shift from industry to "service" sectors, the structure of the Dutch economy became even more "modern" (Indeed, one may see an analogy with the changes in the mature British economy a century later). However, the degree of foreign direct investment by the Dutch at the end of the 18th century was even greater than that of the British at the beginning of the 20th century: more than twice GNP versus 1.5 times GNP.[42]

Another measure of the performance of the Dutch economy during the 18th century is the estimate that De Vries and Van der Woude have made of the per capita GDP of the Dutch economy in 1742 (for which year tax records provide a basis for estimation and extrapolation). They arrive at an estimated GNP of between 265 and 280 million guilders, or 135–142 guilders per capita. This was at the end of a long period of secular decline after the economic zenith of 1650. The next decades saw some economic resurgence. In the decade 1800–1810 (again a period of economic decline) the national income of the (slightly contracted) population can be estimated at 307 million guilders, or 162 guilders per capita. To put all of this in perspective: in 1740 the GNP of Great Britain was about £80 million, or 120 guilders per capita (and therefore about 20 percent lower than the Dutch per capita income). After this the British per capita income started on a rapid increase, due to the Industrial Revolution. It therefore eventually overtook the Dutch per capita income, but probably only around 1800.[43]

One could even say that in the years before 1780 the prospects of the economy were improving: because of the economic growth in the German hinterland there were possibilities of growth in distributional trade in colonial commodities, and industrial products (Dutch or other European). Such possibilities were indeed realized in the 20th century, when the Netherlands again became a major distributional hub. The agricultural sector still enjoyed high productivity, whereas the nearby British markets for dairy products and produce offered opportunities for increased exports (which were indeed soon realized). Only, the high-cost structure of the labor market, high taxes, structural overvaluation of the guilder, all militated against most forms of industrial production, let alone export industries. Without the necessary reforms to remedy these problems the Netherlands were unlikely to participate in the industrial renaissance that Great Britain, and later other neighboring countries, started to experience in the latter part of the 18th century.[44]

Final crisis

[edit]

After 1780, a new conjuncture of internal and external conditions conspired to drive the economy and political structure of the Republic to crisis. The Fourth Anglo-Dutch War ended the cloak of neutrality that had protected Dutch shipping for most of the century, obviating during that period the need for naval protection that was now lacking due to many years of neglect of the navy. Trade came temporarily to a standstill, because the British blockade could not be broken, despite the relative success of the Dutch navy in the Battle of Dogger Bank (1781). The trade of the VOC was devastated, even apart from the loss of some of its colonies. It experienced a liquidity crisis, which exposed its inherent insolvency. The company was too important to let it fail (also because of the importance of its outstanding debt in the Dutch financial system), so that it was kept afloat for more than a decade by emergency aid from the States of Holland, before it was finally nationalized in 1796.

The arsenal of the VOC

Attempts at political reform (and attendant reform of the derelict system of public finance) by the Patriots were thwarted by the suppression of their revolt by the Prussian intervention in the quarrel with Stadtholder William V in 1787. This meant that no further attempts at reform were made until the overthrow of the old Republic and its replacement by the Batavian Republic in 1795.[45] That puppet state of the French Republic was unable to get the freedom of movement from its "sister republic", that would have been necessary to bring about effective reforms, even though the Patriots now had the chance to force them through. An enormous new tax burden to finance transfer payments to France (a war indemnity of 100 million guilders and annual maintenance costs of 12 million guilders of an army of occupation), amounting to 230 million guilders total, broke the back of the fiscal system. Eventually, the public debt was forced into default (though only when the Netherlands were annexed to imperial France in 1810).

More importantly, the Dutch trading system was remorselessly ground away between a British blockade and the French enforced boycott of British goods in the Continental System. This was not compensated by adequate access to the French market, because even when the Netherlands were incorporated in the French empire the old protectionist barriers remained in place. For a while, the Dutch were therefore unable to trade legally anywhere (which left smuggling as the only alternative).[46] In the period of the annexation, 1810–1813, the ports were bereft of shipping and the remnants of industry collapsed.

These external factors were reinforced by internal ones. The necessary reforms of the Dutch system of public finance (as embodied in the Tax Reform Plan of Isaac Jan Alexander Gogel)[47] were blocked for a long time by federalist opposition, and only enacted in the final year of the Republic, just before its transformation to the Kingdom of Holland in 1806. By then it was too little too late.

In the long period of crisis, disinvestments from the commercial and industrial sectors (in the face of unprofitability, high risks, taxation, and forced lending) and the destruction of asset value through foreign and domestic default undermined the remaining international stature of the commercial and financial sectors. Domestically, the disruption of institutions and the irregular access to markets plunged the once-protected sectors of employment ... into a crisis that tore at the venerable structure of the labor market and overwhelmed the Republic's charitable system. This crisis hit hardest in the cities of Holland and Zeeland, which lost 10 percent of their population between 1795 and 1815 ...Deurbanization, re-agriculturalization, and pauperization dominated the final days of this economy.[48]

It is therefore fitting to see the year 1815, in which the United Kingdom of the Netherlands embodied a newly independent political incorporation of the original Habsburg Netherlands, as the end of an economic era also. The hoped for economic resurgence of the Netherlands (other than that of the Southern Netherlands with which it was now temporarily reunited) would, however, not really take flight before the structural problems of the old economy were finally laid to rest around 1850 with the final liquidation of the public debt of the old Republic. This explains at least partly why the Dutch economy was so tardy in implementing the steam-power based industrial revolution of the 19th century.[49]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Israel, The Dutch Republic, pp. 29–35
  2. ^ Israel, The Dutch Republic, pp. 9–21
  3. ^ Israel, The Dutch Republic, p. 14
  4. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 27
  5. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 37–38
  6. ^ a b De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 666
  7. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 243–44, 666
  8. ^ Israel, The Dutch Republic, pp. 169–241
  9. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 667
  10. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 670, 690–92
  11. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 668
  12. ^ Baten, Jörg (2016). A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. p. 15. ISBN 9781107507180.
  13. ^ Charles R. Boxer, The Dutch Seaborne Empire 1600–1800 (1965)
  14. ^ Joost Jonker (1996). Merchants, bankers, middlemen: the Amsterdam money market during the first half of the 19th century. NEHA. p. 32. ISBN 9789057420016. Archived from the original on 2016-07-23. Retrieved 2016-10-14.
  15. ^ Tim William Blanning (2007). The Pursuit of Glory: Europe, 1648–1815. Penguin. p. 96. ISBN 9780670063208. Archived from the original on 2016-05-27. Retrieved 2016-10-14.
  16. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 690–93.
  17. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 671
  18. ^ Jan de Vries (1976). The Economy of Europe in an Age of Crisis, 1600–1750. Cambridge University Press. pp. 117–18. Archived from the original on 2017-04-01. Retrieved 2016-10-14.
  19. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 279–95
  20. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 668–72
  21. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 243–48
  22. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 342–43
  23. ^ Simon Schama, The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in the Golden Age (1997) pp 350–66 esp p. 362
  24. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 672
  25. ^ Cf.Puype, J. P., Hoeven, M. van der (ed.) (1996), The Arsenal of the World. The Dutch Arms Trade in the 17th Century Amsterdam, Batavian Lion International, ISBN 90-6707-413-6
  26. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 141, 378–79
  27. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 672–73
  28. ^ The preponderance of the Dutch population lived in two provinces, Holland and Zeeland. This area experienced a population explosion between 1500 and 1650, with a growth from 350,000 to 1,000,000 inhabitants. Thereafter the growth leveled off, so that the population of the whole country remained at the 2 million level throughout the 18th century; De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 51–52
  29. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 710
  30. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 345–48
  31. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 673–78
  32. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 678–79.
  33. ^ For instance, Britain took over the lucrative Asiento, which the Dutch had held previously.
  34. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 679–80.
  35. ^ Israel, The Dutch Republic, pp. 975, 985–88
  36. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 154–56
  37. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 249–54
  38. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 681–82
  39. ^ By 1780 the net value of Dutch foreign government lending probably exceeded 350 million guilders, two-thirds of which in British government loans; De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 144. Alexander Hamilton consolidated the American federal foreign debt with a Dutch loan of $10 million in 1791; Willard Sterne Randall, Alexander Hamilton: A Life, Harper Collins 2003, ISBN 0-06-095466-3, pp. 374–75
  40. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 139–47
  41. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 681–83
  42. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 146
  43. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 699–710
  44. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, pp. 683–85
  45. ^ Schama, pp. 64–138
  46. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 685
  47. ^ Schama, pp. 494–524
  48. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 686
  49. ^ De Vries and Van der Woude, p. 687

Further reading

[edit]
  • de Vries, Johan. "Benelux, 1920–1970", in C. M. Cipolla, ed. The Fontana Economic History of Europe: Contemporary Economics Part One (1976) pp. 1–71
  • Dhondt, Jan, and Marinette Bruwier in Carlo Cipolla, The Emergence of Industrial Societies-1 (Fontana, 1970) pp. 329–55
  • Houtte, J. A. Van. "Economic Development of Belgium and the Netherlands from the Beginning of the Modern Era", Journal of European Economic History(1972), 1:100–20
  • Israel, Jonathan I. (1995), The Dutch Republic: Its Rise, Greatness and Fall, 1477–1806, Oxford University Press, ISBN 0-19-873072-1 hardback, ISBN 0-19-820734-4 paperback; online edition
  • Mokyr, Joel. "The Industrial Revolution in the Low Countries in the First Half of the Nineteenth Century: A Comparative Case Study", Journal of Economic History (1974) 34#2 pp. 365–99 in JSTOR
  • Mokyr, J. Industrialization in the Low Countries, 1795–1850 (New Haven, 1976).
  • Parthesius, Robert. (2010) Dutch Ships in Tropical Waters: The Development of the Dutch East India Company (VOC) Shipping Network in Asia, 1595–1660 (Amsterdam University Press, 2010). 217 pp.
  • Schama, S. (1977), Patriots and Liberators. Revolution in the Netherlands 1780–1813, New York, Vintage books, ISBN 0-679-72949-6
  • Schama, S. The Embarrassment of Riches: An Interpretation of Dutch Culture in the Golden Age (1997)
  • Vries, J. de, and Woude, A. van der. (1997), The First Modern Economy. Success, Failure, and Perseverance of the Dutch Economy, 1500–1815, Cambridge University Press, ISBN 978-0-521-57825-7
    • Riel, Arthur van. "Review: Rethinking the Economic History of the Dutch Republic: The Rise and Decline of Economic Modernity Before the Advent of Industrialized Growth Nederland 1500–1815..." Journal of Economic History (1996) 56#1 pp. 223–29 in JSTOR, review
[edit]