Jump to content

Consumption tax: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Tags: Mobile edit Mobile app edit
Jpn55 (talk | contribs)
m See also: added wikilink
 
(47 intermediate revisions by 38 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Type of tax}}
{{Taxation}}
{{Taxation}}
A '''consumption tax''' is a [[tax]] on spending on goods and services. The [[tax base]] of such a tax is the money spent on [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]]. Consumption taxes are usually indirect, such as a [[sales tax]] or a [[value-added tax]]. However, a consumption tax can also be structured as a form of direct, personal taxation, such as the [[Hall–Rabushka flat tax]].
A '''consumption tax''' is a [[tax]] levied on consumption spending on goods and services. The [[tax base]] of such a tax is the money spent on [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]]. Consumption taxes are usually indirect, such as a [[sales tax]] or a [[value-added tax]]. However, a consumption tax can also be structured as a form of direct, personal taxation, such as the [[Hall–Rabushka flat tax]].


==Types==
==Types==
===Value-added tax===
===Value-added tax===
A value-added tax (VAT) applies to the market value added to a product or material at each stage of its manufacture or distribution. For example, if a retailer buys a shirt for $20 and sells it for $30, this tax would apply to the $10 difference between the two amounts. A simple VAT would be [[proportional tax|proportional]] to consumption but would also be [[regressive tax|regressive]] on income at higher income levels, as consumption falls as a percentage of income. Savings and investment are [[tax-deferred]] until they become consumption. A VAT may exclude certain goods to make it less regressive. It is used in [[European Union]] countries.
A [[value-added tax]] applies to the market value added to a product or material at each stage of its manufacture or distribution. For example, if a retailer buys a shirt for twenty dollars and sells it for thirty dollars, this tax would apply to the ten dollar difference between the two amounts.


A simple value-added tax is [[proportional tax|proportional]] to consumption but is [[regressive tax|regressive]] on income at higher income levels, as consumption tends to fall as a percentage of income as income rises. Savings and investment are [[tax-deferred]] until they become consumption. A value-added tax may exclude certain goods to make it less regressive against income. It is common in [[European Union]] countries.
In [[Goods and Services Tax (Australia)|Australia]], [[Goods and Services Tax (Canada)|Canada]], [[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|New Zealand]] and [[Goods and Services Tax (Singapore)|Singapore]], it is instead called a ''Goods and Services Tax'' (GST). In Canada it is also called [[Harmonized Sales Tax]] (HST) when it is combined with a provincial sales tax.

Value added tax is a consumption based tax and is levied each and every time the value of a good gets increased in the process of manufacturing to the point of sale.

In [[Goods and Services Tax (Australia)|Australia]], [[Goods and Services Tax (Canada)|Canada]], [[India]], [[Goods and Services Tax (New Zealand)|New Zealand]] and [[Goods and Services Tax (Singapore)|Singapore]], it is instead called a "Goods and Services Tax." In Canada, it is also called [[Harmonized Sales Tax]] when it is combined with a provincial sales tax.


===Sales tax===
===Sales tax===
A sales tax typically applies to the sale of goods, sometimes also to the sales of services. The tax is applied at the point of sale. Laws may allow sellers to itemize the tax separately from the price of the goods or services, or they may require it to be included in the price ([[tax-inclusive]]). The tax amount is usually calculated by applying a [[percentage]] rate to the taxable price of a sale. When a tax on goods or services is paid to a governing body directly by a consumer, it is usually called a [[use tax]]. Often laws provide for the [[tax exemption|exemption]] of certain goods or services from sales and use tax.
[[Sales tax]] is a consumption tax applicable to sales of [[goods and services]]. A sales tax typically applies to the sale of goods, and sometimes includes the sales of services. The tax is applied at the point of sale. The tax amount is usually [[Ad valorem tax|''ad valorem'']], that is, it is calculated by applying a percentage rate to the price of a sale. When a tax on goods or services is paid to a governing body directly by a consumer, it is usually called a [[use tax]]. Often, laws provide for the [[Tax exemption|exemption]] of certain goods or services from such taxes.

Laws may allow sellers to itemize the tax separately from the price of the goods or services, or they may require it to be included in the price.


===Excise tax===
===Excise tax===
An [[excise tax]] is a sales tax that applies to a specific class of goods, typically alcohol, gasoline (petrol), or tourism. The tax rate varies according to the type of good and quantity purchased and is typically unaffected by the person who purchases it.
An [[excise tax]] is a sales tax that applies to a specific class of goods, typically [[alcohol tax|alcohol]], tobacco, gasoline (petrol), or tourism. The tax rate varies according to the type of good and quantity purchased and is typically unaffected by the person who purchases it.

[[Sin taxes]], are a type of excise tax imposed on items that are considered harmful to society, in an effort to decrease their consumption by increasing their prices.


===Expenditure tax===
===Expenditure tax===
A direct, personal consumption tax may take the form of an [[expenditure tax]] or an [[income tax]] that deducts savings and [[investment]]s, such as the Hall–Rabushka flat tax.<ref>[http://www.hoover.org/publications/books/3602666.html The Flat Tax] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100523210531/http://www.hoover.org/publications/books/3602666.html |date=2010-05-23 }}, By Robert E. Hall and Alvin Rabushka, Hoover Institution</ref> A direct consumption tax may be called an expenditure tax, a cash-flow tax, or a consumed-income tax and can be [[flat tax|flat]] or [[progressive tax|progressive]]. Expenditure taxes have been briefly implemented in the past in [[India]] and [[Sri Lanka]].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/584578/taxation|title=Taxation|publisher=Encyclopedia Britannica}}</ref>
A direct, personal consumption tax may take the form of an [[expenditure tax]], that is, an [[income tax]] that deducts savings and [[investment]]s, such as the Hall–Rabushka flat tax.<ref>[http://www.hoover.org/publications/books/3602666.html The Flat Tax] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100523210531/http://www.hoover.org/publications/books/3602666.html |date=2010-05-23 }}, By Robert E. Hall and Alvin Rabushka, Hoover Institution</ref> A direct consumption tax may be called an expenditure tax, a cash-flow tax, or a consumed-income tax and can be [[flat tax|flat]] or [[progressive tax|progressive]]. Expenditure taxes were briefly implemented in the past in [[India]] and [[Sri Lanka]].<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.britannica.com/EBchecked/topic/584578/taxation|title=Taxation|publisher=Encyclopedia Britannica}}</ref>


This form of tax applies to the difference between an individual's income and increase/decrease savings. Like the other consumption taxes, simple personal consumption taxes are regressive with respect to income. However, because this tax applies on an individual basis, it can be made as progressive as a progressive personal income tax. Just as income tax rates increase with personal income, consumption tax rates increase with personal consumption. Economists from [[Milton Friedman]] to [[Edward Gramlich]] and [[Robert H. Frank]] have supported a progressive consumption tax.<ref name="greenspan">{{
This form of tax applies to the difference between an individual's income and any increase/decrease in savings. Simple personal consumption taxes are regressive with respect to income. However, because this tax applies on an individual basis, it can be made progressive. Just as income tax rates increase with personal income, progressive consumption tax rates increase with personal consumption. Economists from [[Milton Friedman]] to [[Edward Gramlich]] and [[Robert H. Frank]] supported a progressive consumption tax.<ref name="greenspan">{{
cite news | url=https://www.nytimes.com/2005/03/04/politics/04tax.html | title=Fed's Chief Gives Consumption Tax Cautious Backing | last=Andrews | first=Edmund L. | publisher=[[The New York Times]] |date=2005-03-04 | accessdate=2008-02-05}}</ref><ref name="consumptiontax">{{
cite news | url=https://www.nytimes.com/2005/03/04/politics/04tax.html | title=Fed's Chief Gives Consumption Tax Cautious Backing | last=Andrews | first=Edmund L. | work=[[The New York Times]] |date=2005-03-04 | access-date=2008-02-05}}</ref><ref name="consumptiontax">{{
cite news |url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB112492381500022421 | title=A Consumption Tax | publisher=[[The Wall Street Journal]] | last=Auerbach | first=Alan J | date=2005-08-25 | accessdate=2008-02-05}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://democracyjournal.org/magazine/8/progressive-consumption-tax | title=Progressive Consumption Tax | publisher=[[Democracy Journal]] | last=Frank | first=Robert H. | date=2008 | accessdate=2018-12-18}}</ref>
cite news |url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB112492381500022421 | title=A Consumption Tax | newspaper=[[The Wall Street Journal]] | last=Auerbach | first=Alan J | date=2005-08-25 | access-date=2008-02-05}}</ref><ref>{{cite news|url=https://democracyjournal.org/magazine/8/progressive-consumption-tax | title=Progressive Consumption Tax | publisher=[[Democracy Journal]] | last=Frank | first=Robert H. | date=2008 | access-date=2017-12-18}}</ref>


==History==
==History==
Consumption taxes, specifically excise taxes, have featured in several notable historic events. In the U.S., the [[stamp tax]], the [[Boston Tea Party|tax on tea]], and [[Whiskey rebellion|whisky taxes]] produced revolts, the first two against the [[Great Britain|British government]] and the latter against the nascent American Republic. In India, an excise tax on [[History of the British salt tax in India|salt]] led to [[Gandhi]]'s famous [[Salt Satyagraha]], a seminal moment in India's struggle to win independence from the U.K.
Consumption taxes, specifically excise taxes, have featured in several notable historic events. In the United States, the [[stamp tax]], the [[Boston Tea Party|tax on tea]], and [[Whiskey rebellion|whiskey taxes]] produced revolts, the first two against the [[Great Britain|British government]] and the latter against the federal government. In India, an excise tax on [[History of the British salt tax in India|salt]] led to [[Mahatma Gandhi|Mohandas Gandhi]]'s famous [[Salt March]], a major event in the [[Indian independence movement|Indian Independence Movement]].


===United States===
===United States===
In the early U.S., taxes were levied principally on consumption. [[Alexander Hamilton]], one of the two chief authors of the anonymous ''[[The Federalist Papers]]'', favored consumption taxes in part because they are harder to raise to "[[Confiscation|confiscatory]]" levels than incomes taxes.<ref name="Bartlett">{{
In the early United States, taxes were levied principally on consumption. [[Alexander Hamilton]], one of the two chief authors of the anonymous ''[[The Federalist Papers]]'', favored consumption taxes in part because they are harder to raise to [[Confiscation|confiscatory]] levels than income taxes.<ref name="Bartlett">{{
cite web|last=Bartlett |first=Bruce| url=http://www.townhall.com/columnists/BruceBartlett/2002/04/05/the_founders_and_the_consumption_tax | publisher=Townhall.com |title=The Founders and the consumption tax |date=2002-04-05 |accessdate=2007-08-09}}</ref> In ''The Federalist Papers'' ([[Federalist No. 21|No. 21]]), Hamilton wrote:
cite web|last=Bartlett |first=Bruce| url=http://www.townhall.com/columnists/BruceBartlett/2002/04/05/the_founders_and_the_consumption_tax | publisher=Townhall.com |title=The Founders and the consumption tax |date=2002-04-05 |access-date=2007-08-09}}</ref> In ''The Federalist Papers'' ([[Federalist No. 21|No. 21]]), Hamilton wrote:


{{quote|It is a signal advantage of taxes on articles of consumption that they contain in their own nature a security against excess. They prescribe their own limit, which cannot be exceeded without defeating the end proposed—that is, an extension of the revenue. When applied to this object, the saying is as just as it is witty that, "in political arithmetic, two and two do not always make four." If duties are too high, they lessen the consumption; the collection is eluded; and the product to the treasury is not so great as when they are confined within proper and moderate bounds. This forms a complete barrier against any material oppression of the citizens by taxes of this class, and is itself a natural limitation of the power of imposing them.<ref>
{{Blockquote|It is a signal advantage of taxes on articles of consumption that they contain in their own nature a security against excess. They prescribe their own limit, which cannot be exceeded without defeating the end proposed—that is, an extension of the revenue. When applied to this object, the saying is as just as it is witty that, "in political arithmetic, two and two do not always make four." If duties are too high, they lessen the consumption; the collection is eluded; and the product to the treasury is not so great as when they are confined within proper and moderate bounds. This forms a complete barrier against any material oppression of the citizens by taxes of this class, and is itself a natural limitation of the power of imposing them.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.conservativetruth.org/library/fed21.html|title=Federalist Paper - 21|website=www.conservativetruth.org}}</ref>}}
[http://www.conservativetruth.org/library/fed21.html Federalist Paper No. 21]</ref>}}


Although personal and corporate income taxes provide the bulk of revenue to the federal government, consumption taxes continue to be a primary source of income for state and local governments. One of the first detailed proposals of a personal consumption tax was developed in 1974 by William Andrews.<ref>Andrews, William D. "A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax", 87 ''Harv. L. Rev.'' 1113 (1974)</ref>
Although personal and corporate income taxes provide the bulk of revenue to the federal government, consumption taxes continue to be a primary source of income for state and local governments. One of the first detailed proposals of a personal consumption tax was developed in 1974 by William Andrews.<ref>Andrews, William D. "A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax", 87 ''Harv. L. Rev.'' 1113 (1974)</ref>


===Japan===
===Japan===
The [[Liberal Democratic Party (Japan)|Liberal Democratic Party]] government of [[Masayoshi Ōhira]] had attempted to introduce a consumption tax in 1979. Ohira met a lot of opposition within his own party and gave up on his attempt after his party suffered badly in the 1979 election. Ten years later [[Noboru Takeshita]] successfully negotiated with politicians, bureaucrats, business and labor unions to introduce a consumption tax,<ref>The Daily Yomiuri Website [http://www.yomiuri.co.jp/dy/national/T120630003220.htm Reflections on Leadership – 2 / Leaders should build network of contacts, keep enemies close] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> which was introduced at a rate of 3% consumption tax in 1989.
The [[Liberal Democratic Party (Japan)|Liberal Democratic Party]] government of [[Masayoshi Ōhira]] attempted to introduce a consumption tax in 1979. Ohira met opposition within his own party and gave up on his attempt after his party suffered badly in the 1979 election. Ten years later, [[Noboru Takeshita]] successfully negotiated with politicians, bureaucrats, business, and labor unions to introduce a consumption tax,<ref>The Daily Yomiuri Website [http://www.yomiuri.co.jp/dy/national/T120630003220.htm Reflections on Leadership – 2 / Leaders should build network of contacts, keep enemies close] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> which was introduced at a rate of 3% in 1989.


In April 1997<ref>The Daily Yomiuri [http://www.yomiuri.co.jp/adv/wol/dy/opinion/economy_090202.htm Is the “cash payout plan” the most effective solution for stimulating the economy?] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> under the government of [[Ryutaro Hashimoto]]<ref>News Channel Asia [http://www.channelnewsasia.com/stories/economicnews/view/377702/1/.html Aso says raising consumption tax will not aid Japan's economy] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> it was increased to 5%.<ref>Bloomberg website [https://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aCo8OxZWOdGE "Japan’s Kan Tackles Sales Tax ‘Taboo’ That Obama Won’t Touch"] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> The 5% is made up of a 4% national consumption tax and a 1% local consumption tax.<ref>JETRO website [http://www.jetro.go.jp/en/invest/setting_up/laws/section3/page6.html Section 3. Taxes in Japan – 3.6 Overview of consumption tax] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Shortly after the tax was introduced Japan fell into [[Japanese asset price bubble|recession]],<ref>East Asia Forum [http://www.eastasiaforum.org/2012/06/21/japans-aging-population-and-public-deficits/ Japan’s aging population and public deficits] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> which was blamed by some on the consumption tax increase,<ref>MSNBC [http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/47111450/ns/business/t/japan-firms-want-safety-first-nuclear-restarts-poll/#.T_P2645JYpo Japan firms want 'safety first' on nuclear restarts: poll] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> and by others on the [[1997 Asian financial crisis]].
In April 1997,<ref>The Daily Yomiuri [http://www.yomiuri.co.jp/adv/wol/dy/opinion/economy_090202.htm Is the "cash payout plan" the most effective solution for stimulating the economy?] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> under the government of [[Ryutaro Hashimoto]]<ref>News Channel Asia [http://www.channelnewsasia.com/stories/economicnews/view/377702/1/.html Aso says raising consumption tax will not aid Japan's economy] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20081211133547/http://www.channelnewsasia.com/stories/economicnews/view/377702/1/.html |date=2008-12-11 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> the rate increased to 5%.<ref>Bloomberg website [https://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=newsarchive&sid=aCo8OxZWOdGE "Japan’s Kan Tackles Sales Tax ‘Taboo’ That Obama Won’t Touch"] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> The 5% is split between the national and local governments, which receive 4% and 1%, respectively.<ref>JETRO website [http://www.jetro.go.jp/en/invest/setting_up/laws/section3/page6.html Section 3. Taxes in Japan – 3.6 Overview of consumption tax] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171110172541/https://www.jetro.go.jp/en/invest/setting_up/laws/section3/page6.html |date=2017-11-10 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Shortly after the tax was introduced Japan fell into [[Japanese asset price bubble|recession]],<ref>East Asia Forum [http://www.eastasiaforum.org/2012/06/21/japans-aging-population-and-public-deficits/ Japan’s aging population and public deficits] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> which was blamed by some on the consumption tax increase,<ref>MSNBC [http://www.msnbc.msn.com/id/47111450/ns/business/t/japan-firms-want-safety-first-nuclear-restarts-poll/#.T_P2645JYpo Japan firms want 'safety first' on nuclear restarts: poll]{{dead link|date=August 2024|bot=medic}}{{cbignore|bot=medic}} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> and by others on the [[1997 Asian financial crisis]].


Prime Minister [[Junichiro Koizumi]] said he had no intention of raising the tax during his government, but after his massive victory in the 2005 election he lifted a ban on discussing it.<ref>electronic journal of contemporary japanese studies [http://www.japanesestudies.org.uk/ejcjs/vol12/iss1/Kamikubo.html Can the Democratic Party Finally Raise Japan’s Consumption Tax?] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120716200034/http://www.japanesestudies.org.uk/ejcjs/vol12/iss1/Kamikubo.html |date=2012-07-16 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Over the following years a number of [[Liberal Democratic Party (Japan)|LDP]] politicians discussed raising it further, including prime ministers [[Shinzō Abe]],<ref>The Japan Times [http://www.japantimes.co.jp/text/nn20070707a2.html#.T_P69I5JYpo Sales tax hike would need voter OK via Lower House poll] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> [[Yasuo Fukuda]],<ref>The Financial Express [http://www.thefinancialexpress-bd.com/2007/09/22/11930.html Fukuda Vows To Continue Reform In Japan] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> and [[Tarō Asō]].<ref>Reuters [https://www.reuters.com/article/2008/10/01/japan-economy-aso-idUSTKU00304720081001 Japan PM Aso says consumption tax hike unavoidable] Retrieved on July 2012</ref>
Prime Minister [[Junichiro Koizumi]] said he had no intention of raising the tax during his government, but after his massive victory in the 2005 election, he lifted a ban on discussing it.<ref>electronic journal of contemporary japanese studies [http://www.japanesestudies.org.uk/ejcjs/vol12/iss1/Kamikubo.html Can the Democratic Party Finally Raise Japan’s Consumption Tax?] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120716200034/http://www.japanesestudies.org.uk/ejcjs/vol12/iss1/Kamikubo.html |date=2012-07-16 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Over the following years [[Liberal Democratic Party (Japan)|LDP]] politicians discussed raising it further, including prime ministers [[Shinzō Abe]],<ref>The Japan Times [http://www.japantimes.co.jp/text/nn20070707a2.html#.T_P69I5JYpo Sales tax hike would need voter OK via Lower House poll]{{Dead link|date=December 2023 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> [[Yasuo Fukuda]],<ref>The Financial Express [http://www.thefinancialexpress-bd.com/2007/09/22/11930.html Fukuda Vows To Continue Reform In Japan] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> and [[Tarō Asō]].<ref>Reuters [https://www.reuters.com/article/japan-economy-aso-idUSTKU00304720081001 Japan PM Aso says consumption tax hike unavoidable] Retrieved on July 2012</ref>


The [[Democratic Party of Japan]] (now the [[Democratic Party (Japan)|DP]]) came to power in the August 2009 elections with a promise not to raise the consumption tax for four years.<ref>Asashi Shimbun [http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/politics/AJ201204050061 DPJ’S Governing Fiasco: Party never challenged Finance Ministry] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120407185511/http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/politics/AJ201204050061 |date=2012-04-07 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> The first DPJ prime minister, [[Yukio Hatoyama]] was opposed, but [[Naoto Kan]] replaced him and called for the consumption tax to be raised. The following prime minister, [[Yoshihiko Noda]] "staked his political life" on raising the tax.<ref>Forbes magazine [https://www.forbes.com/sites/stephenharner/2012/06/28/for-pm-noda-a-week-of-political-drama-and-the-challenge-ahead/ For PM Noda: A Week of Political Drama and the Challenge Ahead] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Despite an internal battle that saw former DPJ leader and co-founder [[Ichirō Ozawa]] and many other DPJ diet members vote against the bill and then leave the party; on June 26, 2012, the lower house of the Japanese diet passed a bill to double the tax to 10%.<ref>Asahi Shimbun [http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/AJ201206260065 Update: Lower House passes bills to double consumption tax] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130622081457/http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/AJ201206260065 |date=2013-06-22 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref>
The [[Democratic Party (Japan, 1998)|Democratic Party]] came to power in the August 2009 elections with a promise not to raise the consumption tax for four years.<ref>Asashi Shimbun [http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/politics/AJ201204050061 DPJ’S Governing Fiasco: Party never challenged Finance Ministry] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120407185511/http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/politics/AJ201204050061 |date=2012-04-07 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> The first DPJ prime minister, [[Yukio Hatoyama]] was opposed, but [[Naoto Kan]] replaced him and called for the consumption tax to be raised. The following prime minister, [[Yoshihiko Noda]] "staked his political life" on raising the tax.<ref>Forbes magazine [https://www.forbes.com/sites/stephenharner/2012/06/28/for-pm-noda-a-week-of-political-drama-and-the-challenge-ahead/ For PM Noda: A Week of Political Drama and the Challenge Ahead] Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref> Despite an internal battle that saw former DPJ leader and co-founder [[Ichirō Ozawa]] and many other DPJ diet members vote against the bill and then leave the party; on June 26, 2012, the lower house of the Japanese diet passed a bill to double the tax to 10%.<ref>Asahi Shimbun [http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/AJ201206260065 Update: Lower House passes bills to double consumption tax] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130622081457/http://ajw.asahi.com/article/behind_news/AJ201206260065 |date=2013-06-22 }} Retrieved on July 4, 2012</ref>


Despite considerable opposition and an attempted [[People's Life First#No confidence motion against Yoshihiko Noda|no-confidence motion]] from minor opposition parties the bill was successfully passed through the upper house on August 10, 2012, so the tax was increased to 8% by April 2014 and will be increased to 10% by October 2019 (twice postponed from the original date of October 2015).<ref>Bloomberg website [https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-06-01/abe-postpones-japan-s-sales-tax-hike-until-late-in-2019 Abe Postpones Japan's Sales-Tax Hike Until Late in 2019] Retrieved on March 25, 2017</ref><ref>KPMG research [http://www.kpmg.com/global/en/issuesandinsights/articlespublications/taxnewsflash/pages/2014-2/japan-consumption-tax-rate-increase-to-be-postponed.aspx Japan - Consumption tax rate increase to be postponed] Retrieved on April 23, 2015</ref>
Despite considerable opposition and an attempted [[People's Life First#No confidence motion against Yoshihiko Noda|no-confidence motion]] from minor opposition parties the bill was successfully passed through the upper house on August 10, 2012, with the result that the tax increased to 8% in April 2014 and to 10% in October 2019 (twice postponed from the original date of October 2015).<ref>Bloomberg website [https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2016-06-01/abe-postpones-japan-s-sales-tax-hike-until-late-in-2019 Abe Postpones Japan's Sales-Tax Hike Until Late in 2019] Retrieved on March 25, 2017</ref><ref>KPMG research [http://www.kpmg.com/global/en/issuesandinsights/articlespublications/taxnewsflash/pages/2014-2/japan-consumption-tax-rate-increase-to-be-postponed.aspx Japan - Consumption tax rate increase to be postponed] Retrieved on April 23, 2015</ref>


==Savings effect==
==Savings effect==
Consumption taxes do not tax savings, which allows invested assets to grow more quickly. If, in the absence of taxes, $1 of savings is put aside for retirement at 9% compound interest, savings will grow to $7.86 after 24 years. Alternatively, by assuming a 33% tax rate, the same $1 is reduced to about $0.67 after taxes when earned. The effective interest rate, thereafter, is reduced to 6%, since the rest of the yield is paid in taxes.
Consumption taxes do not tax savings, which allows invested assets to accumulate untaxed. If, in the absence of taxes, one dollar of savings is put aside for retirement at nine percent compound interest, the balance grows to $7.91 after twenty-four years. Alternatively, by assuming a thirty-three percent tax rate, the same dollar is reduced to about sixty-seven cents after taxes when earned. The effective interest rate, thereafter, is reduced to six percent, since the rest of the yield is paid in taxes.


After 24 years, the balance increases only to $2.64. The cumulative taxes in the latter case are $0.96. The missing $4.26 is not lost by the economy in any sense, as the $4.26 is what the government would make in interest, if they invested their tax revenue. If the initial investment amount is not taxed when earned, but the earnings are taxed thereafter, the cumulative taxes paid are about the same, but are spread more evenly across the period and the asset grows to more than $4. These results are primarily sensitive to the rate of return. With a 3% return, most of the tax receipts come from the tax on the initial $1.00.
After twenty-four years, the balance increases only to $2.73. The cumulative taxes in the latter case are $1.02. The other $4.16 is not lost by the economy in any sense, as the $4.16 is what the government would make in interest, if it had invested its tax revenue in the same investment. If the initial invested amount is not taxed when earned, but the earnings are taxed thereafter, the cumulative taxes paid are the same, but are spread more evenly across the period. These results are primarily sensitive to the rate of return; for example, with a three percent return most of the tax receipts come from the tax on the initial dollar.


To the extent that taxing something results in less of it (whether income or consumption), taxing consumption instead of income should encourage both work and capital formation, which will increase economic growth, while discouraging consumption.<ref name="greenspan" /><ref name="consumptiontax" /> Secondly, the tax base will be larger because ''all'' consumption will be taxed.
To the extent that taxing something results in less of it (whether income or consumption), taxing consumption instead of income should encourage both work and capital formation, which increases economic growth, while discouraging consumption.<ref name="greenspan" /><ref name="consumptiontax" /> Secondly, the tax base is larger because all consumption is taxed.


Some critics argue that sales and consumption taxes can shift the tax burden to the less well-off. The ratio of tax obligation shrinks as wealth grows because the wealthy spend proportionally less of their income on consumables.<ref>
Flat consumption taxes are regressive (shift the tax burden to the less well-off). The ratio of tax obligation to income tends to shrink as income increases because high-earners tend to consume proportionally less of their income.<ref>
Gilbert E. Metcalf. "[http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-289.html The National Sales Tax: Who Bears the Burden?]"</ref> An individual unable to save will pay taxes on 100%, but individuals who save or invest a portion of their income will be taxed only on the remaining income.
Gilbert E. Metcalf. "[http://www.cato.org/pubs/pas/pa-289.html The National Sales Tax: Who Bears the Burden?]"</ref> An individual unable to save will pay taxes on all his income, but an individual who saves or invests a portion of his income is taxed only on the remaining income.


==Practical considerations==
==Practical considerations==
Many proposed consumption taxes share some features with the current [[income tax]] systems. Under these proposals, taxpayers would be given exemptions and a standard deduction in order to ensure that the poor do not pay any tax. In a pure consumption tax, other deductions would not be permitted, because all savings would be deductible.<ref name="greenspan"/>
Many proposed consumption taxes share some features with [[income tax]] systems. Under these proposals, taxpayers are typically given exemptions and/or a standard deduction in order to ensure that the poor do not pay any tax. In a flat consumption tax, these other deductions are not permitted.<ref name="greenspan"/>


A withholding system might also be put into place in order to estimate the total tax liability. It would be difficult for many taxpayers to pay no tax all year, only to be faced with a large tax bill at the end of the year.
A withholding system may be put into place in order to approximate the average tax liability, smoothing payments. It is difficult for many taxpayers to pay no tax all year, only to face a large year-end tax bill.


Andrews notes the inherent problem with [[Home|housing]]. Renters necessarily "consume" housing, so they would be taxed on the expenditure of rent. However, homeowners also consume housing in the same way, but as they pay down a mortgage, the payments are classified as savings, not consumption (because equity is being built in an asset).
A consumption tax could also eliminate the concept of basis when computing the value of investments. All income that is put in investments (such as property, stocks, savings accounts) is tax-free. As the asset grows in value, it is not taxed. Only when the proceeds from the asset are spent is any tax imposed. This is in contrast with the current system where if one buys land for $10,000 and sells it for $15,000, one has a taxable gain of $5,000. A consumption tax taxes only consumption, so if one sells an investment to buy another investment, no tax is imposed.


The disparity is explained by what is known as the imputed rental value of a home. A homeowner could choose to rent the home to others in exchange for money, but instead chooses to live in the home. Therefore, the homeowner is also consuming housing by not permitting renters to pay for and occupy the home. The amount of money that the homeowner could receive in rent is the imputed rental value of the home.
Andrews notes the inherent problem with [[Home|housing]]. Renters necessarily "consume" housing, so they will be taxed on the expenditure of rent. However, homeowners also consume housing in the same way, but as they pay down a mortgage, the payments are classified as savings, not consumption (because equity is being built in an asset).


The disparity is explained by what is known as the imputed rental value of a home. A homeowner could choose to rent the home to others in exchange for money but instead chooses to live in the home to the exclusion of all possible renters. Therefore, the homeowner is also consuming housing by not permitting renters to pay for and occupy the home. The amount of money that the homeowner could receive in rent is the imputed rental value of the home.
A true consumption tax would tax the imputed rental value of the home (which could be determined in the same way that valuation occurs for property tax purposes) but not the increase in the asset value (the home). Andrews proposes to ignore this method of taxing imputed rental values because of its complexity. In the [[United States]], home ownership is subsidized by the federal government by permitting limited deductions for mortgage interest expense and capital gains. Therefore, treating renters and homeowners identically under such a consumption tax may not be feasible there.


This issue would not arise under an expenditure tax, since all withdrawals of funds from a pre-tax investment account are treated as taxable consumption, whether these funds are used to pay rent, buy a house, or pay down mortgage principal. A person may buy a house within a pre-tax account, but would not be allowed to live there.
A true consumption tax would tax the imputed rental value of the home (which could be determined in the same way that valuation occurs for property tax purposes) and would not tax the increase in the value of the asset (the home). Andrews proposes to ignore this method of taxing imputed rental values because of its complexity. In the [[United States]], home ownership is subsidized by the federal government by permitting a deduction for mortgage interest expense and exempting a significant increase in value from the capital gains tax. Therefore, treating renters and homeowners identically under a consumption tax may not be feasible there.


Also, a consumption tax could utilize progressive rates in order to maintain "fairness." The more that someone spends on consumption, the more that the person will be taxed. The rate structure could look like the current bracket system, or a new bracket system could be implemented.
Also, a consumption tax could utilize progressive rates in order to maintain "fairness". More consumption means disproportionately more tax liability.


== Economic impact ==
== Economic impact ==
The temporal neutrality of a consumption tax, however, is that consumption itself is taxed, so it is irrelevant what good or service is being consumed in terms of allocation of resources. The only possible effect on neutrality is between consumption and savings. Taxing only consumption should, in theory, cause an increase in savings.<ref name="greenspan"/> William Gale, Co-director of the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, offers a simplified way to understand a consumption tax: Assume that our current tax system remains the same but remove limitations to contributing to and removing funds from a traditional [[Individual Retirement Account]] (IRA).


The temporal neutrality of a consumption tax, however, is that consumption itself is taxed, so it is irrelevant what good or service is being consumed in terms of allocation of resources. The only possible effect on neutrality is between consumption and savings. Taxing only consumption should, in theory, cause an increase in savings.<ref name="greenspan"/>
Thus, a person would essentially have a bank account where they could place tax-free earnings at any time, but unsaved (or consumed) withdrawals would be subject to taxation. Having an unrestricted IRA under the current system would approximate a consumption tax at the federal level.<!-- This is not an accurate statement of Gale's contentions. -->


Many economists and tax experts favor consumption taxes over income taxes for [[economic growth]].<ref name="money">{{cite news| url=http://money.cnn.com/2005/09/06/pf/taxes/consumptiontax_0510/| last=Regnier| first=Pat| title=Just how fair is the FairTax?| work=| publisher=Money Magazine| date=2005-09-07| accessdate=2006-07-20}}</ref><ref name="fox">{{cite news | title=Greenspan: Consumption Tax Could Help Economy | url=http://www.foxnews.com/story/0,2933,149298,00.html | publisher=Fox News | date=2005-03-03 | accessdate=2008-08-09}}</ref><ref name="oecd">{{cite news| title=America the Uncompetitive | url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB121875570585042551 | publisher=Wall Street Journal | date=2008-08-15 | accessdate=2008-09-03}}</ref>
Many economists and tax experts favor consumption taxes over income taxes for [[economic growth]].<ref name="money">{{cite news| url=https://money.cnn.com/2005/09/06/pf/taxes/consumptiontax_0510/| last=Regnier| first=Pat| title=Just how fair is the FairTax?| work=Money Magazine| date=2005-09-07| access-date=2006-07-20}}</ref><ref name="fox">{{cite news | title=Greenspan: Consumption Tax Could Help Economy | url=http://www.foxnews.com/story/0,2933,149298,00.html | publisher=Fox News | date=2005-03-03 | access-date=2008-08-09}}</ref><ref name="oecd">{{cite news| title=America the Uncompetitive | url=https://www.wsj.com/articles/SB121875570585042551 | newspaper=Wall Street Journal | date=2008-08-15 | access-date=2008-09-03}}</ref>


Depending on implementation (such as treatment of depreciation) and circumstances, income taxes either favor or disfavor investment. (On the whole, the US system is thought to disfavor investment.<ref name="greenspan"/>) By not disfavoring investment, a consumption tax ''might'' increase the capital stock, productivity, and therefore increase the size of the economy.<ref name="greenspan"/><ref name="consumptiontax"/> Consumption more closely tracks long-run average income.<ref name="consumptiontax"/> An individual or a family's income often varies dramatically from year to year. The sale of a home, a one-time job bonus, and various other events can lead to temporary high income that will push a low or middle income person into a high tax bracket. On the other hand, a wealthy individual may be temporarily unemployed and will pay no taxes.
Depending on implementation (such as treatment of depreciation) and circumstances, income taxes either favor or disfavor investment. (On the whole, the American system is thought to disfavor investment.<ref name="greenspan"/>) By not disfavoring investment, a consumption tax would increase the capital stock, productivity, and therefore increase the size of the economy.<ref name="greenspan"/><ref name="consumptiontax"/> Consumption also more closely tracks long-run average income.<ref name="consumptiontax"/> The income of an individual or family can often vary dramatically from year to year. The sale of a home, a one-time job bonus, and various other events can lead to temporary high income that will push a lower or middle income person into a higher tax bracket. On the other hand, a wealthier individual may be temporarily unemployed and earn no income.

== Impact on work choices ==
Consumption taxes, like other taxes, alter individual decisions away from optimal choices. An important concern is potential impact on individual work decisions. Two possible impacts are known as income effect (taxes reduce the real value of work) and substitution effect (changes in relative value of work in relation to other activities).

=== Income effect ===
Under a consumption tax, an individual's purchasing power decreases, either through increased prices (producers pass the tax along to the consumer) or through decreased wages (taxing authorities directly tax the consumer based on a measurement of their consumption). Assuming the former case, of increased prices, if an individual had monthly expenses of $1,000 and an hourly wage of $10 per hour, they would have to work 100 hours a month to cover the expenditures. However, under a 10% consumption tax and assuming the tax is passed completely on to consumers, the monthly expenditures would be $1,100 meaning the individual would have to work 110 hours to cover them. It is expected that individuals increase their amount of work to compensate for the loss of consumption power as a response to increased taxation.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book |last=Stupak |first=Jeffrey M. |url=https://sgp.fas.org/crs/misc/R44342.pdf |title=Consumption Taxes: An Overview |last2=Marples |first2=Donald J. |year=2016 |pages=1–14}}</ref>

=== Substitution effect ===
Along with decrease in purchasing power, taxes also decrease the relative value of work in relation to leisure time. If a tax is implemented on consumption, the value of spending an hour at work decreases in relation to different activities because the tax decreases the actual amount of goods and services an individual can purchase for a given level of work. This subsequently increases the relative value of leisure time and decreases amount of working time, effectively working opposite to the income effect.

If the consumption tax is to be revenue neutral, the tax rate is likely to be higher in comparison with an income tax, because of the smaller tax base. While the tax base for income tax includes all of personal income, the tax base for consumption tax include only income less savings, thus being necessarily smaller. The higher tax rate might then result in an increased substitution effect. However, the consumption tax is levied also on past savings consumed later in individual's life, e.g. during retirement. The tax on this capital is not expected to distort one's behavior, because there is no legal way to avoid this tax burden. The consumption tax on past savings is thus an example of a lump-sum tax. As a consequence, the consumption tax rate does not have to be that much higher than income tax rate in order to preserve revenue neutrality. One possible disadvantage is a higher burden among elderly, consuming primarily their past savings.<ref name=":0" />

=== Empirical evidence ===
According to theory, taxes have two opposing effects on individual's work decisions, the net impact might thus be unclear. Empirical evidence shows that increased taxes cause a decrease in work effort, meaning the substitution effect is larger than the income effect. A study shows that a consumption tax is likely to decrease work effort more than an income tax, although the difference is expected to be minor.<ref name=":0" />

== Tax burden of consumption tax ==

=== Tax burden across income classes ===
Consumption taxes are often criticised to be regressive, meaning the average tax rate decreases with increasing income. However, it depends on income measurement. If income is measured annually or monthly, consumption taxes are truly regressive, as higher-income individuals can afford to save more, thus reducing the tax base for consumption tax more significantly than lower-income individuals. But if lifetime income is used to measure the ability to pay, the burden tends to be more equitable as over a lifetime, lifetime consumption is a good approximation of lifetime income.<ref name=":0" />

=== Tax burden across age groups ===
Because the tax base of consumption tax depends mostly on the ability to save money, it can be expected that middle-aged individuals will have the smallest tax burden as a percentage of their annual income. Elderly people and young adults will on the other hand face higher tax burden as a portion of their income, having more difficulties to save larger amounts of income.<ref name=":0" />


==See also==
==See also==
* [[Alcohol tax]]
* [[Excise|Excise tax]]
* [[Excise|Excise tax]]
* [[FairTax]]
* [[FairTax]]
Line 88: Line 118:
* [[Turnover tax]]
* [[Turnover tax]]
* [[Value-added tax]]
* [[Value-added tax]]
*[[X tax]]
* [[William Petty]], early [[classical economics|classical economist]] who proposed a consumption tax
* [[William Petty]], early [[Classical economics|classical economist]] who proposed a consumption tax
* ''[[The Philosophy of Poverty]]'', by [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualist]] theorist [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]]
* ''[[The Philosophy of Poverty]]'', by [[Mutualism (economic theory)|mutualist]] theorist [[Pierre-Joseph Proudhon]]

==Further reading==

* Ganderson, Joseph; Limberg, Julian (2022), "[https://oxford.universitypressscholarship.com/view/10.1093/oso/9780192897572.001.0001/oso-9780192897572-chapter-9 The Rise of General Consumption Taxes]" in ''Global Taxation.'' Oxford University Press.


==Notes==
==Notes==
Line 98: Line 133:
* [http://www.usapr.org/Papers_Source/1.pdf The Consumption Tax: Macroeconomic Effects]{{dead link|date=August 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} – Edward Cremata
* [http://www.usapr.org/Papers_Source/1.pdf The Consumption Tax: Macroeconomic Effects]{{dead link|date=August 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }} – Edward Cremata
* [http://econblog.aplia.com/2007/10/should-government-tax-consumption-or.html?showComments=false Why do consumption taxes encourage saving?]
* [http://econblog.aplia.com/2007/10/should-government-tax-consumption-or.html?showComments=false Why do consumption taxes encourage saving?]
* [https://www.income-tax.co.uk/ UK Income Tax Calculator]
* [https://www.income-tax.co.uk/ Salary After Tax Estimator]
* [https://incomeaftertax.com Income Tax Calculator]
* [https://asktaxman.co.uk UK Income Tax Calculator]
* [https://personalfinancetools.co.uk/Salary-Calculator/ UK Income Tax Calculator]

{{Population}}
{{Authority control}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Consumption Tax}}
[[Category:Personal taxes]]
[[Category:Personal taxes]]

Latest revision as of 15:36, 25 October 2024

A consumption tax is a tax levied on consumption spending on goods and services. The tax base of such a tax is the money spent on consumption. Consumption taxes are usually indirect, such as a sales tax or a value-added tax. However, a consumption tax can also be structured as a form of direct, personal taxation, such as the Hall–Rabushka flat tax.

Types

[edit]

Value-added tax

[edit]

A value-added tax applies to the market value added to a product or material at each stage of its manufacture or distribution. For example, if a retailer buys a shirt for twenty dollars and sells it for thirty dollars, this tax would apply to the ten dollar difference between the two amounts.

A simple value-added tax is proportional to consumption but is regressive on income at higher income levels, as consumption tends to fall as a percentage of income as income rises. Savings and investment are tax-deferred until they become consumption. A value-added tax may exclude certain goods to make it less regressive against income. It is common in European Union countries.

Value added tax is a consumption based tax and is levied each and every time the value of a good gets increased in the process of manufacturing to the point of sale.

In Australia, Canada, India, New Zealand and Singapore, it is instead called a "Goods and Services Tax." In Canada, it is also called Harmonized Sales Tax when it is combined with a provincial sales tax.

Sales tax

[edit]

Sales tax is a consumption tax applicable to sales of goods and services. A sales tax typically applies to the sale of goods, and sometimes includes the sales of services. The tax is applied at the point of sale. The tax amount is usually ad valorem, that is, it is calculated by applying a percentage rate to the price of a sale. When a tax on goods or services is paid to a governing body directly by a consumer, it is usually called a use tax. Often, laws provide for the exemption of certain goods or services from such taxes.

Laws may allow sellers to itemize the tax separately from the price of the goods or services, or they may require it to be included in the price.

Excise tax

[edit]

An excise tax is a sales tax that applies to a specific class of goods, typically alcohol, tobacco, gasoline (petrol), or tourism. The tax rate varies according to the type of good and quantity purchased and is typically unaffected by the person who purchases it.

Sin taxes, are a type of excise tax imposed on items that are considered harmful to society, in an effort to decrease their consumption by increasing their prices.

Expenditure tax

[edit]

A direct, personal consumption tax may take the form of an expenditure tax, that is, an income tax that deducts savings and investments, such as the Hall–Rabushka flat tax.[1] A direct consumption tax may be called an expenditure tax, a cash-flow tax, or a consumed-income tax and can be flat or progressive. Expenditure taxes were briefly implemented in the past in India and Sri Lanka.[2]

This form of tax applies to the difference between an individual's income and any increase/decrease in savings. Simple personal consumption taxes are regressive with respect to income. However, because this tax applies on an individual basis, it can be made progressive. Just as income tax rates increase with personal income, progressive consumption tax rates increase with personal consumption. Economists from Milton Friedman to Edward Gramlich and Robert H. Frank supported a progressive consumption tax.[3][4][5]

History

[edit]

Consumption taxes, specifically excise taxes, have featured in several notable historic events. In the United States, the stamp tax, the tax on tea, and whiskey taxes produced revolts, the first two against the British government and the latter against the federal government. In India, an excise tax on salt led to Mohandas Gandhi's famous Salt March, a major event in the Indian Independence Movement.

United States

[edit]

In the early United States, taxes were levied principally on consumption. Alexander Hamilton, one of the two chief authors of the anonymous The Federalist Papers, favored consumption taxes in part because they are harder to raise to confiscatory levels than income taxes.[6] In The Federalist Papers (No. 21), Hamilton wrote:

It is a signal advantage of taxes on articles of consumption that they contain in their own nature a security against excess. They prescribe their own limit, which cannot be exceeded without defeating the end proposed—that is, an extension of the revenue. When applied to this object, the saying is as just as it is witty that, "in political arithmetic, two and two do not always make four." If duties are too high, they lessen the consumption; the collection is eluded; and the product to the treasury is not so great as when they are confined within proper and moderate bounds. This forms a complete barrier against any material oppression of the citizens by taxes of this class, and is itself a natural limitation of the power of imposing them.[7]

Although personal and corporate income taxes provide the bulk of revenue to the federal government, consumption taxes continue to be a primary source of income for state and local governments. One of the first detailed proposals of a personal consumption tax was developed in 1974 by William Andrews.[8]

Japan

[edit]

The Liberal Democratic Party government of Masayoshi Ōhira attempted to introduce a consumption tax in 1979. Ohira met opposition within his own party and gave up on his attempt after his party suffered badly in the 1979 election. Ten years later, Noboru Takeshita successfully negotiated with politicians, bureaucrats, business, and labor unions to introduce a consumption tax,[9] which was introduced at a rate of 3% in 1989.

In April 1997,[10] under the government of Ryutaro Hashimoto[11] the rate increased to 5%.[12] The 5% is split between the national and local governments, which receive 4% and 1%, respectively.[13] Shortly after the tax was introduced Japan fell into recession,[14] which was blamed by some on the consumption tax increase,[15] and by others on the 1997 Asian financial crisis.

Prime Minister Junichiro Koizumi said he had no intention of raising the tax during his government, but after his massive victory in the 2005 election, he lifted a ban on discussing it.[16] Over the following years LDP politicians discussed raising it further, including prime ministers Shinzō Abe,[17] Yasuo Fukuda,[18] and Tarō Asō.[19]

The Democratic Party came to power in the August 2009 elections with a promise not to raise the consumption tax for four years.[20] The first DPJ prime minister, Yukio Hatoyama was opposed, but Naoto Kan replaced him and called for the consumption tax to be raised. The following prime minister, Yoshihiko Noda "staked his political life" on raising the tax.[21] Despite an internal battle that saw former DPJ leader and co-founder Ichirō Ozawa and many other DPJ diet members vote against the bill and then leave the party; on June 26, 2012, the lower house of the Japanese diet passed a bill to double the tax to 10%.[22]

Despite considerable opposition and an attempted no-confidence motion from minor opposition parties the bill was successfully passed through the upper house on August 10, 2012, with the result that the tax increased to 8% in April 2014 and to 10% in October 2019 (twice postponed from the original date of October 2015).[23][24]

Savings effect

[edit]

Consumption taxes do not tax savings, which allows invested assets to accumulate untaxed. If, in the absence of taxes, one dollar of savings is put aside for retirement at nine percent compound interest, the balance grows to $7.91 after twenty-four years. Alternatively, by assuming a thirty-three percent tax rate, the same dollar is reduced to about sixty-seven cents after taxes when earned. The effective interest rate, thereafter, is reduced to six percent, since the rest of the yield is paid in taxes.

After twenty-four years, the balance increases only to $2.73. The cumulative taxes in the latter case are $1.02. The other $4.16 is not lost by the economy in any sense, as the $4.16 is what the government would make in interest, if it had invested its tax revenue in the same investment. If the initial invested amount is not taxed when earned, but the earnings are taxed thereafter, the cumulative taxes paid are the same, but are spread more evenly across the period. These results are primarily sensitive to the rate of return; for example, with a three percent return most of the tax receipts come from the tax on the initial dollar.

To the extent that taxing something results in less of it (whether income or consumption), taxing consumption instead of income should encourage both work and capital formation, which increases economic growth, while discouraging consumption.[3][4] Secondly, the tax base is larger because all consumption is taxed.

Flat consumption taxes are regressive (shift the tax burden to the less well-off). The ratio of tax obligation to income tends to shrink as income increases because high-earners tend to consume proportionally less of their income.[25] An individual unable to save will pay taxes on all his income, but an individual who saves or invests a portion of his income is taxed only on the remaining income.

Practical considerations

[edit]

Many proposed consumption taxes share some features with income tax systems. Under these proposals, taxpayers are typically given exemptions and/or a standard deduction in order to ensure that the poor do not pay any tax. In a flat consumption tax, these other deductions are not permitted.[3]

A withholding system may be put into place in order to approximate the average tax liability, smoothing payments. It is difficult for many taxpayers to pay no tax all year, only to face a large year-end tax bill.

Andrews notes the inherent problem with housing. Renters necessarily "consume" housing, so they would be taxed on the expenditure of rent. However, homeowners also consume housing in the same way, but as they pay down a mortgage, the payments are classified as savings, not consumption (because equity is being built in an asset).

The disparity is explained by what is known as the imputed rental value of a home. A homeowner could choose to rent the home to others in exchange for money, but instead chooses to live in the home. Therefore, the homeowner is also consuming housing by not permitting renters to pay for and occupy the home. The amount of money that the homeowner could receive in rent is the imputed rental value of the home.

A true consumption tax would tax the imputed rental value of the home (which could be determined in the same way that valuation occurs for property tax purposes) but not the increase in the asset value (the home). Andrews proposes to ignore this method of taxing imputed rental values because of its complexity. In the United States, home ownership is subsidized by the federal government by permitting limited deductions for mortgage interest expense and capital gains. Therefore, treating renters and homeowners identically under such a consumption tax may not be feasible there.

This issue would not arise under an expenditure tax, since all withdrawals of funds from a pre-tax investment account are treated as taxable consumption, whether these funds are used to pay rent, buy a house, or pay down mortgage principal. A person may buy a house within a pre-tax account, but would not be allowed to live there.

Also, a consumption tax could utilize progressive rates in order to maintain "fairness". More consumption means disproportionately more tax liability.

Economic impact

[edit]

The temporal neutrality of a consumption tax, however, is that consumption itself is taxed, so it is irrelevant what good or service is being consumed in terms of allocation of resources. The only possible effect on neutrality is between consumption and savings. Taxing only consumption should, in theory, cause an increase in savings.[3]

Many economists and tax experts favor consumption taxes over income taxes for economic growth.[26][27][28]

Depending on implementation (such as treatment of depreciation) and circumstances, income taxes either favor or disfavor investment. (On the whole, the American system is thought to disfavor investment.[3]) By not disfavoring investment, a consumption tax would increase the capital stock, productivity, and therefore increase the size of the economy.[3][4] Consumption also more closely tracks long-run average income.[4] The income of an individual or family can often vary dramatically from year to year. The sale of a home, a one-time job bonus, and various other events can lead to temporary high income that will push a lower or middle income person into a higher tax bracket. On the other hand, a wealthier individual may be temporarily unemployed and earn no income.

Impact on work choices

[edit]

Consumption taxes, like other taxes, alter individual decisions away from optimal choices. An important concern is potential impact on individual work decisions. Two possible impacts are known as income effect (taxes reduce the real value of work) and substitution effect (changes in relative value of work in relation to other activities).

Income effect

[edit]

Under a consumption tax, an individual's purchasing power decreases, either through increased prices (producers pass the tax along to the consumer) or through decreased wages (taxing authorities directly tax the consumer based on a measurement of their consumption). Assuming the former case, of increased prices, if an individual had monthly expenses of $1,000 and an hourly wage of $10 per hour, they would have to work 100 hours a month to cover the expenditures. However, under a 10% consumption tax and assuming the tax is passed completely on to consumers, the monthly expenditures would be $1,100 meaning the individual would have to work 110 hours to cover them. It is expected that individuals increase their amount of work to compensate for the loss of consumption power as a response to increased taxation.[29]

Substitution effect

[edit]

Along with decrease in purchasing power, taxes also decrease the relative value of work in relation to leisure time. If a tax is implemented on consumption, the value of spending an hour at work decreases in relation to different activities because the tax decreases the actual amount of goods and services an individual can purchase for a given level of work. This subsequently increases the relative value of leisure time and decreases amount of working time, effectively working opposite to the income effect.

If the consumption tax is to be revenue neutral, the tax rate is likely to be higher in comparison with an income tax, because of the smaller tax base. While the tax base for income tax includes all of personal income, the tax base for consumption tax include only income less savings, thus being necessarily smaller. The higher tax rate might then result in an increased substitution effect. However, the consumption tax is levied also on past savings consumed later in individual's life, e.g. during retirement. The tax on this capital is not expected to distort one's behavior, because there is no legal way to avoid this tax burden. The consumption tax on past savings is thus an example of a lump-sum tax. As a consequence, the consumption tax rate does not have to be that much higher than income tax rate in order to preserve revenue neutrality. One possible disadvantage is a higher burden among elderly, consuming primarily their past savings.[29]

Empirical evidence

[edit]

According to theory, taxes have two opposing effects on individual's work decisions, the net impact might thus be unclear. Empirical evidence shows that increased taxes cause a decrease in work effort, meaning the substitution effect is larger than the income effect. A study shows that a consumption tax is likely to decrease work effort more than an income tax, although the difference is expected to be minor.[29]

Tax burden of consumption tax

[edit]

Tax burden across income classes

[edit]

Consumption taxes are often criticised to be regressive, meaning the average tax rate decreases with increasing income. However, it depends on income measurement. If income is measured annually or monthly, consumption taxes are truly regressive, as higher-income individuals can afford to save more, thus reducing the tax base for consumption tax more significantly than lower-income individuals. But if lifetime income is used to measure the ability to pay, the burden tends to be more equitable as over a lifetime, lifetime consumption is a good approximation of lifetime income.[29]

Tax burden across age groups

[edit]

Because the tax base of consumption tax depends mostly on the ability to save money, it can be expected that middle-aged individuals will have the smallest tax burden as a percentage of their annual income. Elderly people and young adults will on the other hand face higher tax burden as a portion of their income, having more difficulties to save larger amounts of income.[29]

See also

[edit]

Further reading

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ The Flat Tax Archived 2010-05-23 at the Wayback Machine, By Robert E. Hall and Alvin Rabushka, Hoover Institution
  2. ^ "Taxation". Encyclopedia Britannica.
  3. ^ a b c d e f Andrews, Edmund L. (2005-03-04). "Fed's Chief Gives Consumption Tax Cautious Backing". The New York Times. Retrieved 2008-02-05.
  4. ^ a b c d Auerbach, Alan J (2005-08-25). "A Consumption Tax". The Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 2008-02-05.
  5. ^ Frank, Robert H. (2008). "Progressive Consumption Tax". Democracy Journal. Retrieved 2017-12-18.
  6. ^ Bartlett, Bruce (2002-04-05). "The Founders and the consumption tax". Townhall.com. Retrieved 2007-08-09.
  7. ^ "Federalist Paper - 21". www.conservativetruth.org.
  8. ^ Andrews, William D. "A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax", 87 Harv. L. Rev. 1113 (1974)
  9. ^ The Daily Yomiuri Website Reflections on Leadership – 2 / Leaders should build network of contacts, keep enemies close Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  10. ^ The Daily Yomiuri Is the "cash payout plan" the most effective solution for stimulating the economy? Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  11. ^ News Channel Asia Aso says raising consumption tax will not aid Japan's economy Archived 2008-12-11 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  12. ^ Bloomberg website "Japan’s Kan Tackles Sales Tax ‘Taboo’ That Obama Won’t Touch" Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  13. ^ JETRO website Section 3. Taxes in Japan – 3.6 Overview of consumption tax Archived 2017-11-10 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  14. ^ East Asia Forum Japan’s aging population and public deficits Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  15. ^ MSNBC Japan firms want 'safety first' on nuclear restarts: poll[dead link] Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  16. ^ electronic journal of contemporary japanese studies Can the Democratic Party Finally Raise Japan’s Consumption Tax? Archived 2012-07-16 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  17. ^ The Japan Times Sales tax hike would need voter OK via Lower House poll[permanent dead link] Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  18. ^ The Financial Express Fukuda Vows To Continue Reform In Japan Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  19. ^ Reuters Japan PM Aso says consumption tax hike unavoidable Retrieved on July 2012
  20. ^ Asashi Shimbun DPJ’S Governing Fiasco: Party never challenged Finance Ministry Archived 2012-04-07 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  21. ^ Forbes magazine For PM Noda: A Week of Political Drama and the Challenge Ahead Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  22. ^ Asahi Shimbun Update: Lower House passes bills to double consumption tax Archived 2013-06-22 at the Wayback Machine Retrieved on July 4, 2012
  23. ^ Bloomberg website Abe Postpones Japan's Sales-Tax Hike Until Late in 2019 Retrieved on March 25, 2017
  24. ^ KPMG research Japan - Consumption tax rate increase to be postponed Retrieved on April 23, 2015
  25. ^ Gilbert E. Metcalf. "The National Sales Tax: Who Bears the Burden?"
  26. ^ Regnier, Pat (2005-09-07). "Just how fair is the FairTax?". Money Magazine. Retrieved 2006-07-20.
  27. ^ "Greenspan: Consumption Tax Could Help Economy". Fox News. 2005-03-03. Retrieved 2008-08-09.
  28. ^ "America the Uncompetitive". Wall Street Journal. 2008-08-15. Retrieved 2008-09-03.
  29. ^ a b c d e Stupak, Jeffrey M.; Marples, Donald J. (2016). Consumption Taxes: An Overview (PDF). pp. 1–14.
[edit]