Jump to content

Saddle point: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Undid revision 1046580034 by TRAME44 (talk) original was correct, proposed replacement was incorrect
Aligning right
 
(17 intermediate revisions by 12 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Critical point on a surface graph which is not a local extremum}}
{{About|the mathematical property|the peninsula in the Antarctic|Saddle Point|the type of landform and general uses of the word Saddle used as a technical term|Saddle (landform)}}
{{About|the mathematical property|the peninsula in the Antarctic|Saddle Point|the type of landform and general uses of the word "saddle" as a technical term|Saddle (landform)}}


[[File:Saddle point.svg|thumb|right|300px|A saddle point (in red) on the graph of z=x<sup>2</sup>−y<sup>2</sup> ([[Paraboloid#Hyperbolic_paraboloid|hyperbolic paraboloid]])]]
[[File:Saddle point.svg|thumb|right|300px|A saddle point (in red) on the graph of {{math|1=''z'' = ''x''{{sup|2}} − ''y''{{sup|2}}}} ([[Paraboloid#Hyperbolic_paraboloid|hyperbolic paraboloid]])]]
[[File:Saddle_Point_between_maxima.svg|thumb|300px|right|Saddle point between two hills (the intersection of the figure-eight <math>z</math>-contour)]]


In [[mathematics]], a '''saddle point''' or '''minimax point'''<ref>Howard Anton, Irl Bivens, Stephen Davis (2002): ''Calculus, Multivariable Version'', p.&nbsp;844.</ref> is a [[Point (geometry)|point]] on the [[surface (mathematics)|surface]] of the [[graph of a function]] where the [[slope]]s (derivatives) in orthogonal directions are all zero (a [[Critical point (mathematics)|critical point]]), but which is not a [[local extremum]] of the function.<ref>{{cite book |last = Chiang |first = Alpha C. |title = Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics |url = https://archive.org/details/fundamentalmetho0000chia_h4v2 |url-access = registration |location=New York |publisher = [[McGraw-Hill]] |edition=3rd |year=1984 |isbn = 0-07-010813-7 |page = [https://archive.org/details/fundamentalmetho0000chia_h4v2/page/312 312] }}</ref> An example of a saddle point is when there is a critical point with a relative [[minimum]] along one axial direction (between peaks) and at a [[maxima and minima|relative maximum]] along the crossing axis. However, a saddle point need not be in this form. For example, the function <math>f(x,y) = x^2 + y^3</math> has a critical point at <math>(0, 0)</math> that is a saddle point since it is neither a relative maximum nor relative minimum, but it does not have a relative maximum or relative minimum in the <math>y</math>-direction.
In [[mathematics]], a '''saddle point''' or '''minimax point'''<ref>Howard Anton, Irl Bivens, Stephen Davis (2002): ''Calculus, Multivariable Version'', p.&nbsp;844.</ref> is a [[Point (geometry)|point]] on the [[surface (mathematics)|surface]] of the [[graph of a function]] where the [[slope]]s (derivatives) in [[orthogonal]] directions are all zero (a [[Critical point (mathematics)|critical point]]), but which is not a [[local extremum]] of the function.<ref>{{cite book |last = Chiang |first = Alpha C. |author-link=Alpha Chiang |title = Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics |url = https://archive.org/details/fundamentalmetho0000chia_h4v2 |url-access = registration |location=New York |publisher = [[McGraw-Hill]] |edition=3rd |year=1984 |isbn = 0-07-010813-7 |page = [https://archive.org/details/fundamentalmetho0000chia_h4v2/page/312 312] }}</ref> An example of a saddle point is when there is a critical point with a relative [[minimum]] along one axial direction (between peaks) and at a [[maxima and minima|relative maximum]] along the crossing axis. However, a saddle point need not be in this form. For example, the function <math>f(x,y) = x^2 + y^3</math> has a critical point at <math>(0, 0)</math> that is a saddle point since it is neither a relative maximum nor relative minimum, but it does not have a relative maximum or relative minimum in the <math>y</math>-direction.
[[File:Gordena Jackson, Saddle, 1935-1942, NGA 26642.jpg|thumb|right|150px|A riding saddle]]
The name derives from the fact that the prototypical example in two dimensions is a [[surface (mathematics)|surface]] that ''curves up'' in one direction, and ''curves down'' in a different direction, resembling a riding [[saddle]] or a [[mountain pass]] between two peaks forming a [[Saddle (landform)|landform saddle]]. In terms of [[contour line]]s, a saddle point in two dimensions gives rise to a contour graph or trace in which the contour corresponding to the saddle point's value appears to intersect itself.
The name derives from the fact that the prototypical example in two dimensions is a [[surface (mathematics)|surface]] that ''curves up'' in one direction, and ''curves down'' in a different direction, resembling a riding [[saddle]]. In terms of [[contour line]]s, a saddle point in two dimensions gives rise to a contour map with a pair of lines intersecting at the point. Such intersections are rare in actual ordnance survey maps, as the height of the saddle point is unlikely to coincide with the integer multiples used in such maps. Instead, the saddle point appears as a blank space in the middle of four sets of contour lines that approach and veer away from it. For a basic saddle point, these sets occur in pairs, with an opposing high pair and an opposing low pair positioned in orthogonal directions. The critical contour lines generally do not have to intersect orthogonally.

[[File:Julia set for z^2+0.7i*z.png|thumb|right|300px|Saddle point on the countour plot is the point where level curves cross ]]



[[File:Saddle_Point_between_maxima.svg|thumb|300px|right|Saddle point between two hills (the intersection of the figure-eight {{mvar|z}}-contour)]]
[[File:Julia set for z^2+0.7i*z.png|thumb|right|300px|Saddle point on the contour plot is the point where level curves cross ]]


== Mathematical discussion ==
== Mathematical discussion ==
A simple criterion for checking if a given stationary point of a real-valued function ''F''(''x'',''y'') of two real variables is a saddle point is to compute the function's [[Hessian matrix]] at that point: if the Hessian is [[Positive-definite matrix#Indefinite|indefinite]], then that point is a saddle point. For example, the Hessian matrix of the function <math>z=x^2-y^2</math> at the stationary point <math>(x, y, z)=(0, 0, 0)</math> is the matrix
A simple criterion for checking if a given [[stationary point]] of a real-valued function ''F''(''x'',''y'') of two real variables is a saddle point is to compute the function's [[Hessian matrix]] at that point: if the Hessian is [[Positive-definite matrix#Indefinite|indefinite]], then that point is a saddle point. For example, the Hessian matrix of the function <math>z=x^2-y^2</math> at the stationary point <math>(x, y, z)=(0, 0, 0)</math> is the matrix
: <math>\begin{bmatrix}
: <math>\begin{bmatrix}
2 & 0\\
2 & 0\\
Line 35: Line 35:
Classical examples of two-dimensional saddle surfaces in the [[Euclidean space]] are second order surfaces, the [[hyperbolic paraboloid]] <math>z=x^2-y^2</math> (which is often referred to as "''the'' saddle surface" or "the standard saddle surface") and the [[hyperboloid of one sheet]]. The [[Pringles]] potato chip or crisp is an everyday example of a hyperbolic paraboloid shape.
Classical examples of two-dimensional saddle surfaces in the [[Euclidean space]] are second order surfaces, the [[hyperbolic paraboloid]] <math>z=x^2-y^2</math> (which is often referred to as "''the'' saddle surface" or "the standard saddle surface") and the [[hyperboloid of one sheet]]. The [[Pringles]] potato chip or crisp is an everyday example of a hyperbolic paraboloid shape.


Saddle surfaces have negative [[Gaussian curvature]] which distinguish them from convex/elliptical surfaces which have positive Gaussian curvature. A classical third-order saddle surface is the [[monkey saddle]].<ref>{{cite book |first = R. Creighton |last=Buck |year=2003 |title = Advanced Calculus |location = Long Grove, IL |publisher=[[Waveland Press]] |edition=3rd |isbn = 1-57766-302-0 |page=160 |url = https://books.google.com/books?id=7cYQAAAAQBAJ&pg=PA160 }}</ref>
Saddle surfaces have negative [[Gaussian curvature]] which distinguish them from convex/elliptical surfaces which have positive Gaussian curvature. A classical third-order saddle surface is the [[monkey saddle]].<ref>{{cite book |first = R. Creighton |last=Buck |author-link=Robert Creighton Buck |year=2003 |title = Advanced Calculus |location = Long Grove, IL |publisher=[[Waveland Press]] |edition=3rd |isbn = 1-57766-302-0 |page=160 |url = https://books.google.com/books?id=7cYQAAAAQBAJ&pg=PA160 }}</ref>


==Examples==
==Examples==
In a two-player [[zero-sum (game theory)|zero sum]] game defined on a continuous space, the [[Nash equilibrium|equilibrium]] point is a saddle point.
In a two-player [[zero-sum (game theory)|zero sum]] game defined on a continuous space, the [[Nash equilibrium|equilibrium]] point is a saddle point.


For a second-order linear autonomous system, a [[critical point (mathematics)|critical point]] is a saddle point if the [[Characteristic equation (calculus)|characteristic equation]] has one positive and one negative real eigenvalue.<ref>{{harvnb|von Petersdorff|2006}}</ref>
For a second-order linear autonomous system, a [[critical point (mathematics)|critical point]] is a saddle point if the [[Characteristic equation (calculus)|characteristic equation]] has one positive and one negative real [[Eigenvalues and eigenvectors|eigenvalue]].<ref>{{harvnb|von Petersdorff|2006}}</ref>


In optimization subject to equality constraints, the first-order conditions describe a saddle point of the [[Lagrange multiplier|Lagrangian]].
In optimization subject to equality constraints, the first-order conditions describe a saddle point of the [[Lagrange multiplier|Lagrangian]].
Line 52: Line 52:
== See also ==
== See also ==
* [[Saddle-point method]] is an extension of [[Laplace's method]] for approximating integrals
* [[Saddle-point method]] is an extension of [[Laplace's method]] for approximating integrals
* [[Extremum]]
* [[Maximum and minimum]]
* [[Derivative test]]
* [[Derivative test]]
* [[Hyperbolic equilibrium point]]
* [[Hyperbolic equilibrium point]]
* [[Hyperbolic geometry]]
* [[Minimax theorem]]
* [[Minimax theorem]]
* [[Max–min inequality]]
* [[Max–min inequality]]
* [[Monkey saddle]]
* [[Mountain pass theorem]]
* [[Mountain pass theorem]]


Line 69: Line 69:
* {{citation |last1=Hilbert |first1=David |author1-link = David Hilbert |last2=Cohn-Vossen |first2=Stephan |author2-link = Stephan Cohn-Vossen |title = Geometry and the Imagination |publisher=[[Chelsea Publishing|Chelsea]] |location = New York, NY |edition=2nd |isbn = 978-0-8284-1087-8 |year=1952 }}
* {{citation |last1=Hilbert |first1=David |author1-link = David Hilbert |last2=Cohn-Vossen |first2=Stephan |author2-link = Stephan Cohn-Vossen |title = Geometry and the Imagination |publisher=[[Chelsea Publishing|Chelsea]] |location = New York, NY |edition=2nd |isbn = 978-0-8284-1087-8 |year=1952 }}
* {{citation |first=Tobias |last = von Petersdorff |chapter-url = https://www.math.umd.edu/~petersd/246/stab.html |chapter=Critical Points of Autonomous Systems |year=2006 |title = Differential Equations for Scientists and Engineers (Math 246 lecture notes) }}
* {{citation |first=Tobias |last = von Petersdorff |chapter-url = https://www.math.umd.edu/~petersd/246/stab.html |chapter=Critical Points of Autonomous Systems |year=2006 |title = Differential Equations for Scientists and Engineers (Math 246 lecture notes) }}
* {{citation |last = Widder |first = D. V. |title = Advanced calculus |publisher=Dover Publications |location = New York, NY |year=1989 |page=128 |isbn = 0-486-66103-2 }}
* {{citation |last = Widder |first = D. V. |author-link=David Widder |title = Advanced calculus |publisher=Dover Publications |location = New York, NY |year=1989 |page=128 |isbn = 0-486-66103-2 }}
* {{citation |last = Agarwal |first = A. |title = Study on the Nash Equilibrium (Lecture Notes) |url = http://www.cse.iitd.ernet.in/~rahul/cs905/lecture3/nash1.html#SECTION00041000000000000000 }}
* {{citation |last = Agarwal |first = A. |title = Study on the Nash Equilibrium (Lecture Notes) |url = http://www.cse.iitd.ernet.in/~rahul/cs905/lecture3/nash1.html#SECTION00041000000000000000 }}
{{refend}}
{{refend}}

Latest revision as of 18:22, 9 November 2024

A saddle point (in red) on the graph of z = x2y2 (hyperbolic paraboloid)

In mathematics, a saddle point or minimax point[1] is a point on the surface of the graph of a function where the slopes (derivatives) in orthogonal directions are all zero (a critical point), but which is not a local extremum of the function.[2] An example of a saddle point is when there is a critical point with a relative minimum along one axial direction (between peaks) and at a relative maximum along the crossing axis. However, a saddle point need not be in this form. For example, the function has a critical point at that is a saddle point since it is neither a relative maximum nor relative minimum, but it does not have a relative maximum or relative minimum in the -direction.

A riding saddle

The name derives from the fact that the prototypical example in two dimensions is a surface that curves up in one direction, and curves down in a different direction, resembling a riding saddle. In terms of contour lines, a saddle point in two dimensions gives rise to a contour map with a pair of lines intersecting at the point. Such intersections are rare in actual ordnance survey maps, as the height of the saddle point is unlikely to coincide with the integer multiples used in such maps. Instead, the saddle point appears as a blank space in the middle of four sets of contour lines that approach and veer away from it. For a basic saddle point, these sets occur in pairs, with an opposing high pair and an opposing low pair positioned in orthogonal directions. The critical contour lines generally do not have to intersect orthogonally.

Saddle point between two hills (the intersection of the figure-eight z-contour)
Saddle point on the contour plot is the point where level curves cross

Mathematical discussion

[edit]

A simple criterion for checking if a given stationary point of a real-valued function F(x,y) of two real variables is a saddle point is to compute the function's Hessian matrix at that point: if the Hessian is indefinite, then that point is a saddle point. For example, the Hessian matrix of the function at the stationary point is the matrix

which is indefinite. Therefore, this point is a saddle point. This criterion gives only a sufficient condition. For example, the point is a saddle point for the function but the Hessian matrix of this function at the origin is the null matrix, which is not indefinite.

In the most general terms, a saddle point for a smooth function (whose graph is a curve, surface or hypersurface) is a stationary point such that the curve/surface/etc. in the neighborhood of that point is not entirely on any side of the tangent space at that point.

The plot of y = x3 with a saddle point at 0

In a domain of one dimension, a saddle point is a point which is both a stationary point and a point of inflection. Since it is a point of inflection, it is not a local extremum.

Saddle surface

[edit]
Hyperbolic paraboloid
A model of an elliptic hyperboloid of one sheet
A monkey saddle

A saddle surface is a smooth surface containing one or more saddle points.

Classical examples of two-dimensional saddle surfaces in the Euclidean space are second order surfaces, the hyperbolic paraboloid (which is often referred to as "the saddle surface" or "the standard saddle surface") and the hyperboloid of one sheet. The Pringles potato chip or crisp is an everyday example of a hyperbolic paraboloid shape.

Saddle surfaces have negative Gaussian curvature which distinguish them from convex/elliptical surfaces which have positive Gaussian curvature. A classical third-order saddle surface is the monkey saddle.[3]

Examples

[edit]

In a two-player zero sum game defined on a continuous space, the equilibrium point is a saddle point.

For a second-order linear autonomous system, a critical point is a saddle point if the characteristic equation has one positive and one negative real eigenvalue.[4]

In optimization subject to equality constraints, the first-order conditions describe a saddle point of the Lagrangian.

Other uses

[edit]

In dynamical systems, if the dynamic is given by a differentiable map f then a point is hyperbolic if and only if the differential of ƒ n (where n is the period of the point) has no eigenvalue on the (complex) unit circle when computed at the point. Then a saddle point is a hyperbolic periodic point whose stable and unstable manifolds have a dimension that is not zero.

A saddle point of a matrix is an element which is both the largest element in its column and the smallest element in its row.

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]

Citations

[edit]
  1. ^ Howard Anton, Irl Bivens, Stephen Davis (2002): Calculus, Multivariable Version, p. 844.
  2. ^ Chiang, Alpha C. (1984). Fundamental Methods of Mathematical Economics (3rd ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. p. 312. ISBN 0-07-010813-7.
  3. ^ Buck, R. Creighton (2003). Advanced Calculus (3rd ed.). Long Grove, IL: Waveland Press. p. 160. ISBN 1-57766-302-0.
  4. ^ von Petersdorff 2006

Sources

[edit]

Further reading

[edit]
[edit]