Jump to content

Monetary base: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
new section on monetary policy
 
(36 intermediate revisions by 29 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|Measure of money supply}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=August 2013}}
{{Expand German|date=January 2024}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=May 2024}}
{{Public finance}}
{{Public finance}}
[[File:Euro monetary base.png|thumb|Euro monetary base]]
[[File:Euro monetary base.png|thumb|Euro monetary base]]


In [[economics]], the '''monetary base''' (also '''base money''', '''money base''', '''high-powered money''', '''reserve money''', '''outside money''', '''central bank money''' or, in the [[United Kingdom|UK]], '''narrow money''') in a country is the total amount of bank notes and coins circulating in the economy. This includes:
In [[economics]], the '''monetary base''' (also '''base money''', '''money base''', '''high-powered money''', '''reserve money''', '''outside money''', '''central bank money''' or, in the [[United Kingdom|UK]], '''narrow money''') in a country is the total amount of money created by the central bank. This includes:


* the total [[currency]] circulating in the public,
* the total [[currency]] circulating in the public,
* plus the currency that is physically held in the [[bank vault|vaults]] of [[commercial bank|commercial banks]],
* plus the currency that is physically held in the [[bank vault|vaults]] of [[commercial bank]]s,
* plus the [[commercial bank|commercial banks']] [[bank reserves|reserves]]<ref>See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulations at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1) and 12 C.F.R. section 204.2.</ref> held in the [[central bank]]<ref>See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulation at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1)(i).</ref> .
* plus the [[commercial bank|commercial banks']] [[bank reserves|reserves]]<ref>See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulations at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1) and 12 C.F.R. section 204.2.</ref> held in the [[central bank]].<ref>See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulation at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1)(i).</ref>


The monetary base should not be confused with the [[money supply]] which consists of the total [[currency]] circulating in the public plus certain types of non-bank deposits with [[commercial bank]]s.
The monetary base should not be confused with the [[money supply]], which consists of the total [[currency]] circulating in the public plus certain types of non-bank deposits with [[commercial bank]]s.


==Management==
==Management==
[[File:Monetary Base United States 1959-01-01 2018-08-01.png|alt=|left|thumb|U.S. Monetary base]]
[[File:US monetary base - Updated.png|alt=|left|thumb|U.S. Monetary base]]
[[File:Money supply Euro.png|thumb|Base money of the Euro zone and money supplies M1, M2 and M3, and euro zone GDP from 1980–2021. Logarithmic scale.]]
[[Open market operation]]s are [[monetary policy]] tools which directly expand or contract the monetary base.
[[Open market operation]]s are [[monetary policy]] tools which directly expand or contract the monetary base.


The monetary base is manipulated during the conduct of monetary policy by a [[finance ministry]] or the central bank. These institutions change the monetary base through open market transactions: the buying and selling of government bonds. For example, if they buy government bonds from commercial banks, they pay for them by adding new amounts to the banks’ reserve deposits at the central bank, the latter being a component of the monetary base.
The monetary base is manipulated during the conduct of monetary policy by a [[finance ministry]] or the central bank. These institutions change the monetary base through open market operations: the buying and selling of government bonds. For example, if they buy government bonds from commercial banks, they pay for them by adding new amounts to the banks’ reserve deposits at the central bank, the latter being a component of the monetary base.


Typically, a central bank can also influence banking activities by manipulating interest rates and setting reserve requirements (how much money banks must keep on hand instead of loaning out to borrowers). Interest rates, especially on [[federal funds]] (ultra-short-term loans between banks), are themselves influenced by open market operations.
Typically, a central bank can also influence banking activities by manipulating interest rates and setting [[reserve requirements]] (how much money banks must keep on hand instead of loaning out to borrowers). Interest rates, especially on [[federal funds]] (ultra-short-term loans between banks), are themselves influenced by open market operations.


The monetary base (MB) has traditionally been considered '''high-powered''' because its increase will typically result in a much larger increase in the supply of [[demand deposit]]s through banks' loan-making; a ratio called the [[money multiplier]].<ref name="Mankiw">{{citation |last=Mankiw |first=N. Gregory |title=Macroeconomics |publisher=Worth |year=2002 |edition=5th |pages=482–489 |chapter=Chapter 18: Money Supply and Money Demand }}</ref>
The monetary base has traditionally been considered '''high-powered''' because its increase will typically result in a much larger increase in the supply of [[demand deposit]]s through banks' loan-making, a ratio called the [[money multiplier]].<ref name="Mankiw">{{citation |last=Mankiw |first=N. Gregory |title=Macroeconomics |publisher=Worth |year=2002 |edition=5th |pages=482–489 |chapter=Chapter 18: Money Supply and Money Demand }}</ref> However, for those that do not agree with the theory of the money multiplier, the monetary base can be thought of as high powered because of the [[fiscal multiplier]] instead.


==Monetary policy==
==Monetary policy==
{{Original research section|date=February 2022}}
[[Monetary policy]] is generally presumed to be the policy preserve of reserve banks, who target an interest rate. If control of the amount of base money in the economy is lost due failure by the reserve bank to meet the reserve requirements of the banking system, banks who are short of reserves will bid up the interest rate. Interest rates are set by the reserve bank to maintain an inflation rate which is considered neither too high or too low. This is usually determined using a Taylor Rule.
The quantity of reserves in the banking system is supported by the open market operations performed by the reserve banks, involving the purchase and sale of various financial instruments, commonly government debt (bonds), usually using "repos". Banks only require enough reserves to facilitate interbank settlement processes.
In some countries, reserve banks now pay interest on reserves. This adds another lever to the interest rate control mechanisms available to the reserve bank.
Following the 2008 financial crisis, quantitative easing raised the amount of reserves in the banking system, as reserve banks purchased bad debt from the banks, paying for it with reserves. This has left the banking system with an oversupply of reserves. This increase in reserves has had no effect on the level of interest rates. Reserves are never lent out by banks.


== Accounting ==
If a country’s [[gross domestic product]] is declining or growing sluggishly, monetary policy can offset this with open market purchases of bonds, which expand the monetary base. This expansion of the base in turn leads to expansion of the [[money supply]] and to downward pressure on interest rates, which makes it less expensive for consumers to buy consumer goods and for companies to purchase new [[physical capital]]; the increase in these types of expenditure gives an upward push to gross domestic product.
Following [[International Financial Reporting Standards|IFRS]] standards, base money is registered as a liability of the central banks' balance sheet,<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Archer|first1=David|last2=Moser-Boehm|first2=Paul|date=2013-04-29|title=Central bank finances|url=https://www.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap71.htm|language=en}}</ref> implying base money is by nature a debt from the central bank. However, given the special nature of central bank money – which cannot be redeemed in anything other than base money – numerous scholars such as [[Michael Kumhof]] have argued it should rather be recorded as a form of equity.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Kumhof|first1=Michael|last2=Allen|first2=Jason G.|last3=Bateman|first3=Will|last4=Lastra|first4=Rosa M.|last5=Gleeson|first5=Simon|last6=Omarova|first6=Saule T.|date=2020-11-14|title=Central Bank Money: Liability, Asset, or Equity of the Nation?|url=https://papers.ssrn.com/abstract=3730608|language=en|location=Rochester, NY|ssrn=3730608 }}</ref>

==United States==
As of August 2018, the monetary base in the United States was USD $3,584,502,000,000, up from 832,999,000,000 in March 2008; this dramatic more-than-three-fold increase was a response to the [[financial crisis of 2007–2008]].<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://fred.stlouisfed.org/series/BOGMBASE|title=Monetary Base; Total|last=|first=|date=|website=Economic Research – Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis|archive-url=|archive-date=|dead-url=|access-date=}}</ref>


==See also==
==See also==
Line 33: Line 39:
*[[Fractional reserve banking]]
*[[Fractional reserve banking]]
*[[Credit theory of money]]
*[[Credit theory of money]]
*[[Broad money]]


==References==
==References==
Line 41: Line 48:
| last = Brunner
| last = Brunner
| first = Karl
| first = Karl
| authorlink = Karl Brunner (economist)
| author-link = Karl Brunner (economist)
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
Line 49: Line 56:
| url = http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde1987_X001039
| url = http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde1987_X001039
| chapter = High-powered money and the monetary base
| chapter = High-powered money and the monetary base
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| page = 1
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.2726
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.2726
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* {{Cite book
* {{Cite book
| last = Goodhart
| last = Goodhart
| first = Charles
| first = Charles
| authorlink = Charles Goodhart
| author-link = Charles Goodhart
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
Line 64: Line 72:
| url = http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde1987_X001483
| url = http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde1987_X001483
| chapter = Monetary base
| chapter = Monetary base
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| page = 1
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.3102
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.3102
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* {{Cite book
* {{Cite book
| last = Cagan
| last = Cagan
| first = Phillip
| first = Phillip
| authorlink = Phillip Cagan
| author-link = Phillip Cagan
| title = Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960
| title = Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960
| publisher = National Bureau of Economic Research
| publisher = National Bureau of Economic Research
Line 80: Line 89:
| pages = 45–117
| pages = 45–117
| isbn = 0-87014-097-3
| isbn = 0-87014-097-3
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* [http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current/h3.htm Aggregate Reserves Of Depository Institutions And The Monetary Base (H.3)]
* [http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current/h3.htm Aggregate Reserves Of Depository Institutions And The Monetary Base (H.3)]

{{Authority control}}


[[Category:Monetary economics]]
[[Category:Monetary economics]]

Latest revision as of 00:29, 13 November 2024

Euro monetary base

In economics, the monetary base (also base money, money base, high-powered money, reserve money, outside money, central bank money or, in the UK, narrow money) in a country is the total amount of money created by the central bank. This includes:

The monetary base should not be confused with the money supply, which consists of the total currency circulating in the public plus certain types of non-bank deposits with commercial banks.

Management

[edit]
U.S. Monetary base
Base money of the Euro zone and money supplies M1, M2 and M3, and euro zone GDP from 1980–2021. Logarithmic scale.

Open market operations are monetary policy tools which directly expand or contract the monetary base.

The monetary base is manipulated during the conduct of monetary policy by a finance ministry or the central bank. These institutions change the monetary base through open market operations: the buying and selling of government bonds. For example, if they buy government bonds from commercial banks, they pay for them by adding new amounts to the banks’ reserve deposits at the central bank, the latter being a component of the monetary base.

Typically, a central bank can also influence banking activities by manipulating interest rates and setting reserve requirements (how much money banks must keep on hand instead of loaning out to borrowers). Interest rates, especially on federal funds (ultra-short-term loans between banks), are themselves influenced by open market operations.

The monetary base has traditionally been considered high-powered because its increase will typically result in a much larger increase in the supply of demand deposits through banks' loan-making, a ratio called the money multiplier.[3] However, for those that do not agree with the theory of the money multiplier, the monetary base can be thought of as high powered because of the fiscal multiplier instead.

Monetary policy

[edit]

Monetary policy is generally presumed to be the policy preserve of reserve banks, who target an interest rate. If control of the amount of base money in the economy is lost due failure by the reserve bank to meet the reserve requirements of the banking system, banks who are short of reserves will bid up the interest rate. Interest rates are set by the reserve bank to maintain an inflation rate which is considered neither too high or too low. This is usually determined using a Taylor Rule. The quantity of reserves in the banking system is supported by the open market operations performed by the reserve banks, involving the purchase and sale of various financial instruments, commonly government debt (bonds), usually using "repos". Banks only require enough reserves to facilitate interbank settlement processes. In some countries, reserve banks now pay interest on reserves. This adds another lever to the interest rate control mechanisms available to the reserve bank. Following the 2008 financial crisis, quantitative easing raised the amount of reserves in the banking system, as reserve banks purchased bad debt from the banks, paying for it with reserves. This has left the banking system with an oversupply of reserves. This increase in reserves has had no effect on the level of interest rates. Reserves are never lent out by banks.

Accounting

[edit]

Following IFRS standards, base money is registered as a liability of the central banks' balance sheet,[4] implying base money is by nature a debt from the central bank. However, given the special nature of central bank money – which cannot be redeemed in anything other than base money – numerous scholars such as Michael Kumhof have argued it should rather be recorded as a form of equity.[5]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulations at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1) and 12 C.F.R. section 204.2.
  2. ^ See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulation at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1)(i).
  3. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002), "Chapter 18: Money Supply and Money Demand", Macroeconomics (5th ed.), Worth, pp. 482–489
  4. ^ Archer, David; Moser-Boehm, Paul (29 April 2013). "Central bank finances". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  5. ^ Kumhof, Michael; Allen, Jason G.; Bateman, Will; Lastra, Rosa M.; Gleeson, Simon; Omarova, Saule T. (14 November 2020). "Central Bank Money: Liability, Asset, or Equity of the Nation?". Rochester, NY. SSRN 3730608. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
[edit]