Jump to content

Associative economics: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
added economic systems sidebar (article is mentioned in/related to series)
 
(45 intermediate revisions by 32 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Economic systems sidebar}}
'''Associative Economics''' is a term used variously by different people around the world. For some of these the work of Austrian [[philosopher]] and social thinker [[Rudolf_Steiner|Rudolf Steiner]]<ref name=WE>Steiner, Rudolf [http://www.economics.goetheanum.org/954.html ''Economics - The World As One Economy''] </ref> is a key reference. Steiner gave a course of lectures in 1922 in which he set out his view that with the advent of [[global economy]], the science of economics would need to take a further step, which included an elaboration of the economic process, a more precise monetary analysis, and a clearer understanding of how, through the division of labour, the associative basis of economic life becomes apparent. ''Associative Economics'' emphasizes the development of conscious coordination of producers, distributors, and consumers. It understands the global economy as a single, closed domain, through which human beings meet one another's needs.
'''Associative economics''' refers to the conscious cooperation of various components of the economy, such as ''labor and management'' or ''consumers, producers, and distributors.'' The purpose of this co-operation would be to set priorities for what items should be produced and in what quantity, and how they should best be distributed. Further questions include the conditions and rights of workers, in particular their ability to be contributing agents to the development of the workplace. The goal of associative economics is to humanize economic relationships.<ref>[https://economics.goetheanum.org/research/associative-economics Asscoiative Economics], Goetheanum</ref>


The idea and term originates in the work of the [[philosopher]] and social thinker [[Rudolf Steiner]].<ref name=WE>Steiner, Rudolf [http://www.economics.goetheanum.org/954.html ''Economics – The World As One Economy'']</ref>
The idea of associative economics is also interpreted by some people with reference to [[community supported agriculture]], [[ethical banking]], [[social finance]], [[Community_land_trust|community land trusts]], and [[local currencies]].<ref>Lamb, Gary. ''Associative Economics: spiritual activity for the common good'' (Ghent, NY: AWSNA. 2010) 20, 145</ref>


==Themes==
===Local and Global===
Some of the themes central to/addressed by associative economics include the following:<ref name=Lamb/>
Associative economics recognizes the central role of the individual entrepreneur and the inherent regulatory effect of face-to-face transactions between producers and consumers. At the same time, it sees that the economic organism has truly become global - has moved beyond national boundaries - and therefore, when it is seen from a national perspective this is only partial and potentially harmful. Within the context of a legislative framework, the economy is best ''managed'' by those who are responsible for activities working in association with one another rather than 'unto themselves'. It has also been described as an "Altruistic Stakeholder-Managed Economy").<ref>Karp, Robert. ''Toward an Associative Economy in the Sustainable Food and Farming Movement'' (New Spirit Ventures. 2007)</ref>
* how the three ways money can move (through gift, loan, or purchase) play roles in the economy;
This picture of an autonomously managed economy belongs to Steiner's overall conception of the threefold nature of social life.
* the factors of production and price formation;
* alternatives to pure market forces for setting prices;
* real and personal credit;
* land rights residing in the commonweal;
* balance of payments,
* banking in an associative economy.


The principles of associative economics have inspired [[community supported agriculture]], [[ethical banking]], [[social finance]], [[community land trust]]s, and [[local currencies]].<ref name=Lamb>Lamb, Gary. ''Associative Economics: spiritual activity for the common good'' (Ghent, NY: AWSNA. 2010) 20, 145</ref>
===The Threefold Nature of Social Life===
Advocates of what is often referred to as the "threefold social organism" or "[[social threefolding]]," promote the autonomy (the separation and conscious interaction) of the three realms of social life: [[economy]], [[rights]], and [[culture]]. They see in the cry of the [[French Revolution]] - "[[Liberté, Égalité, Fraternité]]" - three fundamental ideals of the modern human being that can only find their rightful (and compatible) place in these three spheres.<ref>Steiner, Rudolf. ''Towards Social Renewal'' (Great Barrington: SteinerBooks. 1999)</ref> Freedom and self-determination in the cultural realm - to believe, express, and develop as one sees fit; fraternity (brotherhood/sisterhood) in the economic realm - where, through shared work and division of labor, individuals come together to meet the needs of the whole; and equality in the rights realm - where all citizens can come together to make agreements, decide what is equally right for all.


=== Land, Labor, and Capital===
==Local and global==
Associative economics recognizes the central role of the individual entrepreneur and the inherent regulatory effect of face-to-face transactions between producers and consumers. At the same time, it sees that the economic organism has become truly global has moved beyond national boundaries so that when the economy is seen from a national perspective this is only partial and potentially harmful. Though within the context of a legislative and regulatory framework, the economy is best conducted not by the State but by those who are responsible for economic activities, potentially everyone working in association with one another rather than unto themselves. It has also been described as an "altruistic stakeholder-managed economy".<ref>Karp, Robert. ''Toward an Associative Economy in the Sustainable Food and Farming Movement'' (New Spirit Ventures. 2007)</ref>
Many things which today are considered commodities within the "free-market" paradigm are differently understood within an associative paradigm for example: [[Land_(economics)|land]], [[Labour_(economics)|labor]], and [[Capital_(economics)|capital]]. These so-called "factors of production" are actually matters of right which simply border the economic realm on all sides. Land is part of the [[commons]]. It is our common heritage, a resource that belongs to all (including future generations) which needs to be stewarded by those most capable to meet current needs (in this, Steiner corroborates many notable thinkers including [[Chief Seattle]]<ref>Chief Seattle [http://www.context.org/ICLIB/IC03/Seattle.htm Letter to President Pierce], 1855</ref> and [[Thomas Jefferson]]).<ref>Jefferson, Thomas [http://www.let.rug.nl/usa/P/tj3/writings/brf/jefl81.htm "The Earth Belongs to the Living"] - a letter to James Madison, Paris, 9/6/1789</ref> Steiner views labor as a form of "wagery," a descendant of serfdom and slavery (where once we sold our whole body, now we sell our time), as well as an economic untruth, an impossibility which we allow to persist:
This picture of an autonomously conducted economy belongs to Steiner's overall conception of the threefold nature of social life.


==The threefold nature of social life==
:''"They actually speak as though a kind of sale and purchase took place between the wage-earner who sells his Labour and the man who buys it from him. But this sale and purchase is fictitious. It does not in reality take place... In reality... it is ''values'' which are exchanged. The worker produces something directly; he delivers a product, and it is this product which the enterpriser [Unternehmer] really buys from him. In actual fact, down to the last farthing, the enterpriser pays for the products which the workers deliver to him. It is time we began to see these things in their right light."''<ref name=WE/>
In the early 20th century, Rudolf Steiner spoke in detail about the threefold nature of social life; not as an invention or theory, but as observable fact (also known as the "threefold social organism" or "[[Social threefolding#Civil society|social threefolding]]"). Central to this perception is the need for autonomy (separate yet conscious interaction) on the part of the three realms of social life: the economy, the rights life (including politics and law), and spiritual-cultural life, meaning the many worldviews that human beings cherish. Though historically premature, they see in the cry of the French Revolution ("Liberté, Égalité, Fraternité") three fundamental ideals of the modern human being, each of which can only find its proper place in one of these three spheres.<ref>Steiner, Rudolf. ''Towards Social Renewal'' (Great Barrington: SteinerBooks. 1999)</ref> Freedom and pluralism in the spiritual-cultural realm, including in education; uncoerced cooperation in the economic realm where through the division of labor individuals come together to meet one another's needs; and democracy and equality in the political rights realm where everyone comes together to sense and make agreements that are right for all.

== Land, labor and capital==
Many things which today are considered commodities within the ‘free-market’ paradigm are differently understood within an associative paradigm. For example: land, labor, and capital. The so-called ‘factors of production’ are seen as 'factors of price formation', essentially matters of right which simply border the economic realm on all sides. However, in the associative paradigm, these 'factors of price formation' do not fall into the hands of the state.

Land is part of the commons. It is our common heritage, a resource that, in a wider sense, belongs to all (including future generations, but, again, ''not'' to the State), and which needs to be entrusted by voluntary groups and individuals to those whom such groups and individuals consider most capable of using it to meet current social needs.
<ref>in this, Steiner corroborates many notable thinkers including [[Chief Seattle]]Chief Seattle [http://www.context.org/ICLIB/IC03/Seattle.htm Letter to President Pierce] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110414051133/http://www.context.org/ICLIB/IC03/Seattle.htm# |date=2011-04-14 }}, 1855 and [[Thomas Jefferson]]). Jefferson, Thomas [http://www.let.rug.nl/usa/P/tj3/writings/brf/jefl81.htm "The Earth Belongs to the Living"] – a letter to James Madison, Paris, 9/6/1789</ref>

Steiner views labor as a form of "wagery," the remnant of serfdom and slavery (where once we sold our whole body, now we sell our ’labor power’). But it is also an economic untruth, an impossibility which we allow to persist: "[People] actually speak as though a kind of sale and purchase took place between the wage-earner who sells his labour and the man who buys it from him. But this sale and purchase is fictitious. It does not in reality take place... [In reality] it is values which are exchanged. The worker produces something directly; he delivers a product, and it is this product which the enterpriser [Unternehmer] really buys from him. In actual fact, down to the last farthing, the enterpriser pays for the products which the workers deliver to him. It is time we began to see these things in their right light."<ref name=WE/>
Lastly, capital is the added value built up through the application of intelligence to labor. It is the human spirit manifest in the economic process. Often taking the form of money, it further frees and empowers the entrepreneur to apply their intelligence. The artist and "social threefolder" [[Joseph Beuys]] famously stated this truth as "Art=Capital" (Kunst=Kapital), or alternatively, for his art piece in the 'Luna Luna' art fair in 1987, "Money is not CAPITAL at all. CAPACITY is CAPITAL."<ref>Beuys, Joseph. ''What is Money?'' (Forest Row, England; Clearview. 2010) 26</ref> Capital is therefore also a product of our common heritage (this time cultural), and derives especially from our access to education.
Capital creates value by the application of intelligence to labor. It is the human spirit manifest in the economic process. An interesting analysis of this viewpoint is provided by Folkert Wilken in his book ''The Liberation of Capital''.<ref>Wilken, Folkert. ''The Liberation of Capital'' (London, England; George Allen & Unwin. 1982)</ref> Often taking the form of money, it further frees and empowers the entrepreneur to apply their intelligence. The artist [[Joseph Beuys]] famously expressed this as "Art=Capital" (Kunst=Kapital), or alternatively, for his art piece in the 'Luna Luna' art fair in 1987, "Money is not CAPITAL at all. CAPACITY is CAPITAL."<ref>Beuys, Joseph. ''What is Money?'' (Forest Row, England; Clearview. 2010) 26</ref> Capital is therefore intimately linked to the individual, although it also owes much to our common heritage, especially the way we are educated.


In an Associative Economy, therefore, land, labor, and capital would be treated as rights phenomena to be held in [[Trusts|trust]] on behalf of the community and consequently managed by those with both the desire and capacity.
In an associative economy, therefore, land, labor, and capital are understood as rights phenomena. Some interpret this to mean they are held in trust on behalf of the community (but not held by the state) and consequently managed by those with both the desire and capacity, but how precisely this idea is given practical expression is one of the key, and liveliest, areas of research in associative economics.


Land trusts, which remove land from the private market, but also keep it out of the hands of the state, have been developed for the protection of the environment and in order to make home ownership more accessible to low income people.
Overall, there are no examples of large-scale communities or societies which apply all of the above principles; instead we see them taken up piece-meal and in smaller initiatives. One of the most significant, and successful, economic endeavors that one could see as aligned with associative principles is the [[Mondragon Corporation]] in Spain (employing over 85,000 people in over 250 different worker-owned companies which work cooperatively together). Smaller communities inspired by Steiner's economic and social ideas include the [[Camphill|Camphill Villages]] (over 100 on 5 continents) and the [[SEKEM|SEKEM Initiative]] near [[Cairo, Egypt]].

As for labor, many different kinds of efforts have been made to treat laborers not as a mere company expense or a mere factor of production, but as partners and associates in the business. That entails profit sharing, and a number of profound changes in the way workers are involved in companies.

As for capital, the associative idea broadly speaking is that the buildup of capital is a social phenomenon due to many more stakeholders than are acknowledged under traditional capitalism. As a social phenomenon, accumulations of capital by a company should be administered in a way that reflects social consideration among many stakeholders: Not just investors, but workers, the local and to some extent global community and environment, and independent educational institutions, are the sources of profits and profitable ideas and capital, and should have some share in the company and in its profits. An associative company would be set up so that it cannot be sold off by investors, since the company is not merely the creation of investors. But many different arrangements are possible.

One example is the [[Mondragon Corporation]] (started by Catholic priest José Mª Arizmendiarrieta, who was not associated with Rudolf Steiner, but whose economic views overlapped in important ways with Steiner's economic views). By the end of 2011, the Mondragon Corporation<ref>{{cite web |title=Yes, there is an alternative to capitalism: Mondragon shows the way {{!}} Richard Wolff |date=2012-06-24 |website=[[The Guardian]] |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230604091152/https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2012/jun/24/alternative-capitalism-mondragon |archive-date=2023-06-04 |url-status=live |url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2012/jun/24/alternative-capitalism-mondragon}}</ref> employed 83,869 people working in 256 companies<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.openideo.com/open/connected/inspiration/learning-from-of-mondragon-corporation-redesigning-work-and-living/ |title=OpenIDEO - How might we inspire and enable communities to take more initiative in making their local environments better? - Inspiration - Learning from of Mondragón Corporation - Redesigning Work and Living |access-date=2013-02-04 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130220235024/http://www.openideo.com/open/connected/inspiration/learning-from-of-mondragon-corporation-redesigning-work-and-living |archive-date=2013-02-20 |url-status=dead }}</ref> in four areas of activity: finance, industry, retail and knowledge.

In an associative enterprise, distant investors, if allowed to invest at all, might not be given any voting rights, or the ability to take control of the company and sell it unilaterally without regard to other stakeholders. An emphasis might be placed on getting investment capital from a company's workers, who could be asked to invest part of their earnings or profits in a company investment fund to help expand the company and develop new offshoots. When a worker leaves the company, he withdraws his invested capital, plus its earnings and interest, and some sort of pension given enough years of service. The company is set up so that no one can amass company shares, and thus the company itself cannot be sold and remains a resource for the community, which after all has been a part of the company's success. The company, while for-profit, might be held in trust by a non-profit board, which ensures the company remains as a resource for the community. The broad guiding lines of associative economic enterprise are that economic life should not be owned or managed by the state (which however of course legislates and makes sure that laws and regulations are followed by companies, including basic rights for workers), nor should economic life be owned or managed merely by those who have lots of capital to invest; ownership should be spread among all the stakeholders, with an emphasis on those who work in a company, the local community, and independent schools. Management of the company should be determined not by the state, but by talent, know-how, and success: i.e., whoever can manage the company profitably and for the benefit of all stakeholders, might be selected in various ways by various stakeholders, depending on circumstances.


==Notes==
==Notes==
Line 32: Line 56:
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/Lectures/WorldEcon/WldEco_index.html Rudolf Steiner, ''World Economy'']
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/Lectures/WorldEcon/WldEco_index.html Rudolf Steiner, ''World Economy'']
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/GA/GA0023/English/SCR2001/GA023_index.html Rudolf Steiner, ''Towards Social Renewal'']
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/GA/GA0023/English/SCR2001/GA023_index.html Rudolf Steiner, ''Towards Social Renewal'']
* [http://cfae.biz/catalog/product_info.php?cPath=1&products_id=62&osCsid=1b15d047ecf30ee145b2ad8c64fb6ebd Rudolf Steiner and Christopher Houghton Budd, ''Rudolf Steiner: Economist'']
* [https://www.cfae.biz/publications/international-shop/detail/?tx_ttnews%5Btt_news%5D=14&cHash=dcb35e43ea5785efaa02ac7c16b19a5f, "Rudolf Steiner, Economist / Rudolf Steiner and Christopher Houghton Budd"]{{dead link|date=October 2016 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}
* [https://www.cfae.biz/publications/international-shop/detail/?tx_ttnews%5Btt_news%5D=8&cHash=79deaf3fcad8ae5d7f9bf8d914cecb57, "A Human Response to Globalisation / Marc Desaules"]{{dead link|date=October 2016 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}
* [http://cfae.biz/catalog/product_info.php?cPath=1&products_id=62&osCsid=1b15d047ecf30ee145b2ad8c64fb6ebd Mark Desaules, ''A Human Response to Globalization'']
* [https://www.cfae.biz/publications/international-shop/detail/?tx_ttnews%5Btt_news%5D=15&cHash=de6fbaf3e74ba2a64fed8d44cd576f20, "The Metamorphosis of Capitalism / Christopher Houghton Budd"]{{dead link|date=October 2016 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}
* [http://cfae.biz/catalog/product_info.php?cPath=1&products_id=40&osCsid=c4316969001070ec5386a54e2af7847b Christoper Houghton Budd, ''The Metamorphosis of Capitalism'']
* [http://www.clairviewbooks.com/pages/viewbook.php?isbn_in=9781905570256 Joseph Beuys, ''What is Money?'']
* [http://www.clairviewbooks.com/pages/viewbook.php?isbn_in=9781905570256 Joseph Beuys, ''What is Money?'']
* [http://www.awsna.org/catalog/product_info.php?products_id=609&osCsid=ls5f9d8i6sh1c6s6btehc3m985 Gary Lamb, ''Associative Economics: Spiritul Activity for the Common Good'']
* [http://www.awsna.org/catalog/product_info.php?products_id=609&osCsid=ls5f9d8i6sh1c6s6btehc3m985 Gary Lamb, ''Associative Economics: Spiritual Activity for the Common Good'']
* [http://www.steinerbooks.org/detail.html?id=9780880106344 John Bloom, ''The Genius of Money'']
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20110310130039/http://www.steinerbooks.org/detail.html?id=9780880106344 John Bloom, ''The Genius of Money'']
* Richard Masters, ''Rudolf Steiner and Social Reform: Threefolding and Other Proposals''


===Journals and Articles===
===Journals and articles===
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/Books/GA024/English/AP1985/GA024_a02.html Rudolf Steiner, "The International Economy and the Threefold Social Order" from the newspaper ''The Social Future'']
* [http://wn.rsarchive.org/Books/GA024/English/AP1985/GA024_a02.html Rudolf Steiner, "The International Economy and the Threefold Social Order" from the newspaper ''The Social Future'']
* [http://www.rsarchive.org/RelAuthors/BarfieldOwen/barfield_economics.php Owen Barfield, "The Relation Between the Economics of C. H. Douglas and Those of Rudolf Steiner"]
* [http://www.rsarchive.org/RelAuthors/BarfieldOwen/barfield_economics.php Owen Barfield, "The Relation Between the Economics of C. H. Douglas and Those of Rudolf Steiner"]
* [http://www.thinkoutword.org/Robert%20Karp%20Essay.pdf Robert Karp, "Toward an Associative Economy in the Sustainable Food and Farming Movement"]
* [http://www.thinkoutword.org/Robert%20Karp%20Essay.pdf Robert Karp, "Toward an Associative Economy in the Sustainable Food and Farming Movement"]
* [http://www.thinkoutword.org/pdfs/Money_Article.pdf Sarah Hearn, "Money: Reclaiming the Power to Create"]
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20110728104517/http://www.thinkoutword.org/pdfs/Money_Article.pdf Sarah Hearn, "Money: Reclaiming the Power to Create"]
* [http://socialrenewal.com/pdfs/lamb%20fall%2008%20pdf.pdf Gary Lamb, "The Transformation of the Competitive Market and Capitalism: A Necessity of the Twenty-First Century"]
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20110716101454/http://socialrenewal.com/pdfs/lamb%20fall%2008%20pdf.pdf Gary Lamb, "The Transformation of the Competitive Market and Capitalism: A Necessity of the Twenty-First Century"]
* [http://altramoneta.noblogs.org/gallery/570/GGPreparata_Perishable_Money_in_a_Threefold_Commonwealth.pdf Guido Giacomo Preparata, "Perishable Money in a Threefold Commenwealth: Rudolf Steiner and the Social Economics of an Anarchist Utopia." ''Review of Radical Economics'' 38/4 (Fall 2006)]
* [http://altramoneta.noblogs.org/gallery/570/GGPreparata_Perishable_Money_in_a_Threefold_Commonwealth.pdf Guido Giacomo Preparata, "Perishable Money in a Threefold Commonwealth: Rudolf Steiner and the Social Economics of an Anarchist Utopia." ''Review of Radical Economics'' 38/4 (Fall 2006)]
* [http://www.cfae.biz/associate/ ''Associate!'' a monthly digest by the Centre for Associative Economics]
* [http://www.cfae.biz/associate/ ''Associate!'' a monthly digest by the Centre for Associative Economics]



{{Anthroposophy series}}
{{Anthroposophy series}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Associative Economics}}
[[Category:Anthroposophy]]
[[Category:Anthroposophy]]
[[Category:Rudolf Steiner]]
[[Category:Rudolf Steiner]]
[[Category:Economics]]
[[Category:Schools of economic thought]]

Latest revision as of 11:56, 26 November 2024

Associative economics refers to the conscious cooperation of various components of the economy, such as labor and management or consumers, producers, and distributors. The purpose of this co-operation would be to set priorities for what items should be produced and in what quantity, and how they should best be distributed. Further questions include the conditions and rights of workers, in particular their ability to be contributing agents to the development of the workplace. The goal of associative economics is to humanize economic relationships.[1]

The idea and term originates in the work of the philosopher and social thinker Rudolf Steiner.[2]

Themes

[edit]

Some of the themes central to/addressed by associative economics include the following:[3]

  • how the three ways money can move (through gift, loan, or purchase) play roles in the economy;
  • the factors of production and price formation;
  • alternatives to pure market forces for setting prices;
  • real and personal credit;
  • land rights residing in the commonweal;
  • balance of payments,
  • banking in an associative economy.

The principles of associative economics have inspired community supported agriculture, ethical banking, social finance, community land trusts, and local currencies.[3]

Local and global

[edit]

Associative economics recognizes the central role of the individual entrepreneur and the inherent regulatory effect of face-to-face transactions between producers and consumers. At the same time, it sees that the economic organism has become truly global – has moved beyond national boundaries – so that when the economy is seen from a national perspective this is only partial and potentially harmful. Though within the context of a legislative and regulatory framework, the economy is best conducted not by the State but by those who are responsible for economic activities, potentially everyone working in association with one another rather than unto themselves. It has also been described as an "altruistic stakeholder-managed economy".[4] This picture of an autonomously conducted economy belongs to Steiner's overall conception of the threefold nature of social life.

The threefold nature of social life

[edit]

In the early 20th century, Rudolf Steiner spoke in detail about the threefold nature of social life; not as an invention or theory, but as observable fact (also known as the "threefold social organism" or "social threefolding"). Central to this perception is the need for autonomy (separate yet conscious interaction) on the part of the three realms of social life: the economy, the rights life (including politics and law), and spiritual-cultural life, meaning the many worldviews that human beings cherish. Though historically premature, they see in the cry of the French Revolution ("Liberté, Égalité, Fraternité") three fundamental ideals of the modern human being, each of which can only find its proper place in one of these three spheres.[5] Freedom and pluralism in the spiritual-cultural realm, including in education; uncoerced cooperation in the economic realm – where through the division of labor individuals come together to meet one another's needs; and democracy and equality in the political rights realm – where everyone comes together to sense and make agreements that are right for all.

Land, labor and capital

[edit]

Many things which today are considered commodities within the ‘free-market’ paradigm are differently understood within an associative paradigm. For example: land, labor, and capital. The so-called ‘factors of production’ are seen as 'factors of price formation', essentially matters of right which simply border the economic realm on all sides. However, in the associative paradigm, these 'factors of price formation' do not fall into the hands of the state.

Land is part of the commons. It is our common heritage, a resource that, in a wider sense, belongs to all (including future generations, but, again, not to the State), and which needs to be entrusted by voluntary groups and individuals to those whom such groups and individuals consider most capable of using it to meet current social needs. [6]

Steiner views labor as a form of "wagery," the remnant of serfdom and slavery (where once we sold our whole body, now we sell our ’labor power’). But it is also an economic untruth, an impossibility which we allow to persist: "[People] actually speak as though a kind of sale and purchase took place between the wage-earner who sells his labour and the man who buys it from him. But this sale and purchase is fictitious. It does not in reality take place... [In reality] it is values which are exchanged. The worker produces something directly; he delivers a product, and it is this product which the enterpriser [Unternehmer] really buys from him. In actual fact, down to the last farthing, the enterpriser pays for the products which the workers deliver to him. It is time we began to see these things in their right light."[2]

Capital creates value by the application of intelligence to labor. It is the human spirit manifest in the economic process. An interesting analysis of this viewpoint is provided by Folkert Wilken in his book The Liberation of Capital.[7] Often taking the form of money, it further frees and empowers the entrepreneur to apply their intelligence. The artist Joseph Beuys famously expressed this as "Art=Capital" (Kunst=Kapital), or alternatively, for his art piece in the 'Luna Luna' art fair in 1987, "Money is not CAPITAL at all. CAPACITY is CAPITAL."[8] Capital is therefore intimately linked to the individual, although it also owes much to our common heritage, especially the way we are educated.

In an associative economy, therefore, land, labor, and capital are understood as rights phenomena. Some interpret this to mean they are held in trust on behalf of the community (but not held by the state) and consequently managed by those with both the desire and capacity, but how precisely this idea is given practical expression is one of the key, and liveliest, areas of research in associative economics.

Land trusts, which remove land from the private market, but also keep it out of the hands of the state, have been developed for the protection of the environment and in order to make home ownership more accessible to low income people.

As for labor, many different kinds of efforts have been made to treat laborers not as a mere company expense or a mere factor of production, but as partners and associates in the business. That entails profit sharing, and a number of profound changes in the way workers are involved in companies.

As for capital, the associative idea broadly speaking is that the buildup of capital is a social phenomenon due to many more stakeholders than are acknowledged under traditional capitalism. As a social phenomenon, accumulations of capital by a company should be administered in a way that reflects social consideration among many stakeholders: Not just investors, but workers, the local and to some extent global community and environment, and independent educational institutions, are the sources of profits and profitable ideas and capital, and should have some share in the company and in its profits. An associative company would be set up so that it cannot be sold off by investors, since the company is not merely the creation of investors. But many different arrangements are possible.

One example is the Mondragon Corporation (started by Catholic priest José Mª Arizmendiarrieta, who was not associated with Rudolf Steiner, but whose economic views overlapped in important ways with Steiner's economic views). By the end of 2011, the Mondragon Corporation[9] employed 83,869 people working in 256 companies[10] in four areas of activity: finance, industry, retail and knowledge.

In an associative enterprise, distant investors, if allowed to invest at all, might not be given any voting rights, or the ability to take control of the company and sell it unilaterally without regard to other stakeholders. An emphasis might be placed on getting investment capital from a company's workers, who could be asked to invest part of their earnings or profits in a company investment fund to help expand the company and develop new offshoots. When a worker leaves the company, he withdraws his invested capital, plus its earnings and interest, and some sort of pension given enough years of service. The company is set up so that no one can amass company shares, and thus the company itself cannot be sold and remains a resource for the community, which after all has been a part of the company's success. The company, while for-profit, might be held in trust by a non-profit board, which ensures the company remains as a resource for the community. The broad guiding lines of associative economic enterprise are that economic life should not be owned or managed by the state (which however of course legislates and makes sure that laws and regulations are followed by companies, including basic rights for workers), nor should economic life be owned or managed merely by those who have lots of capital to invest; ownership should be spread among all the stakeholders, with an emphasis on those who work in a company, the local community, and independent schools. Management of the company should be determined not by the state, but by talent, know-how, and success: i.e., whoever can manage the company profitably and for the benefit of all stakeholders, might be selected in various ways by various stakeholders, depending on circumstances.

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ Asscoiative Economics, Goetheanum
  2. ^ a b Steiner, Rudolf Economics – The World As One Economy
  3. ^ a b Lamb, Gary. Associative Economics: spiritual activity for the common good (Ghent, NY: AWSNA. 2010) 20, 145
  4. ^ Karp, Robert. Toward an Associative Economy in the Sustainable Food and Farming Movement (New Spirit Ventures. 2007)
  5. ^ Steiner, Rudolf. Towards Social Renewal (Great Barrington: SteinerBooks. 1999)
  6. ^ in this, Steiner corroborates many notable thinkers including Chief SeattleChief Seattle Letter to President Pierce Archived 2011-04-14 at the Wayback Machine, 1855 and Thomas Jefferson). Jefferson, Thomas "The Earth Belongs to the Living" – a letter to James Madison, Paris, 9/6/1789
  7. ^ Wilken, Folkert. The Liberation of Capital (London, England; George Allen & Unwin. 1982)
  8. ^ Beuys, Joseph. What is Money? (Forest Row, England; Clearview. 2010) 26
  9. ^ "Yes, there is an alternative to capitalism: Mondragon shows the way | Richard Wolff". The Guardian. 2012-06-24. Archived from the original on 2023-06-04.
  10. ^ "OpenIDEO - How might we inspire and enable communities to take more initiative in making their local environments better? - Inspiration - Learning from of Mondragón Corporation - Redesigning Work and Living". Archived from the original on 2013-02-20. Retrieved 2013-02-04.
[edit]

Organizations

[edit]

Books

[edit]

Journals and articles

[edit]