Jump to content

Hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
AnomieBOT (talk | contribs)
m Dating maintenance tags: {{Clarify}}
 
(74 intermediate revisions by 32 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Occurrence of hyperinflation in early 20th century Germany}}
{{short description|Occurrence of hyperinflation in early 20th century Germany}}
{{Use dmy dates|date=March 2024}}
<!-- Section on stabilization unclear, particularly with backing of the rentenmark -->
<!-- Section on stabilization unclear, particularly with backing of the rentenmark -->
[[File:Bundesarchiv Bild 183-R1215-506, Berlin, Reichsbank, Geldauflieferungsstelle.jpg|thumb|upright=1.2|Piles of new ''[[Notgeld]]'' [[banknote]]s awaiting distribution at the [[Reichsbank]] during the hyperinflation]]
[[File:Bundesarchiv Bild 183-R1215-506, Berlin, Reichsbank, Geldauflieferungsstelle.jpg|thumb|upright=1.2|Piles of new ''[[Notgeld]]'' [[banknote]]s awaiting distribution at the [[Reichsbank]] during the hyperinflation]]
[[Hyperinflation]] affected the [[Papiermark|German Papiermark]], the currency of the [[Weimar Republic]], between 1921 and 1923, primarily in 1923. It caused considerable internal political instability in the country and led to the [[occupation of the Ruhr]] by France and Belgium after Germany defaulted on its [[World War I reparations|war reparations]].
[[Hyperinflation]] affected the [[Papiermark|German Papiermark]], the currency of the [[Weimar Republic]], between 1921 and 1923, primarily in 1923. The German currency had seen significant inflation during the [[First World War]] due to the way in which the German government funded its war effort through borrowing, with debts of 156 billion marks by 1918. This [[national debt]] was substantially increased by 50 billion marks of reparations payable in cash and in-kind (e.g., with coal and timber) under the May 1921 London Schedule of Payments agreed after the [[Versailles treaty]].

This inflation continued into the post-war period, particularly when in August 1921 the German central bank began buying hard cash with paper currency at any price, which they claimed was to pay reparations in hard cash, though little in the way of cash reparations payments were made until 1924. The currency stabilised in early 1922, but then hyperinflation took off: the exchange value of the mark fell from 320 marks per dollar in mid 1922 to 7,400 marks per US dollar by December 1922. This hyperinflation continued into 1923, and by November 1923, one US dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 marks. Various measures were introduced by German authorities to address this, including a new currency called the ''Rentenmark'', backed by mortgage bonds, later itself replaced by the Reichsmark, and the blocking of the national bank from printing further paper currency.

By 1924 the currency had stabilised and German reparations payments began again under the [[Dawes Plan]]. As the catastrophic fall in the value of the mark had effectively wiped out debts owed, some debts (e.g. mortgages) were revalued so that the lenders could recoup some of their money.

Hyperinflation caused considerable internal political instability in the country. Historians and economists are divided on the causes of this hyperinflation, particularly the extent to which it was caused by reparations payments.


== Background ==
== Background ==
===Inflation during the First World War===
To pay for the large costs of the ongoing [[First World War]], Germany suspended the [[gold standard]] (the convertibility of its currency to gold) when the war broke out in 1914. Unlike [[French Third Republic|France]], which imposed its first [[income tax]] to pay for the war, German Emperor [[Wilhelm II, German Emperor|Wilhelm II]] and the [[Reichstag (German Empire)|Reichstag]] decided unanimously to fund the war entirely by [[Debt|borrowing]].
To pay for the large costs of the [[First World War]], Germany suspended the [[gold standard]] (the convertibility of its currency to gold) when the war broke out in 1914. Unlike [[French Third Republic|France]], which imposed its first [[income tax]] to pay for the war, German Emperor [[Wilhelm II, German Emperor|Wilhelm II]] and the [[Reichstag (German Empire)|Reichstag]] decided unanimously to fund the war entirely by [[Debt|borrowing]].


The government believed that it would be able to pay off the debt by winning the war and imposing war reparations on the defeated Allies. This was to be done by annexing resource-rich industrial territory in the west and east and imposing cash payments to Germany, similar to the [[French indemnity]] that followed German victory over France in 1870.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=103}} Thus, the exchange rate of the mark against the [[US dollar]] steadily devalued from 4.2 to 7.9 marks per dollar between 1914 and 1918, a preliminary warning to the extreme postwar inflation.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Officer |first1=Lawrence |title=Exchange Rates Between the United States Dollar and Forty-one Currencies |url=http://www.measuringworth.com/exchangeglobal/ |website=MeasuringWorth |access-date=2015-01-28}}</ref>
The government believed that it would be able to pay off the debt by winning the war and imposing war reparations on the defeated Allies. This was to be done by annexing resource-rich industrial territory in the west and east and imposing cash payments to Germany, similar to the [[French indemnity]] that followed German victory over France in 1870.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=103}} However, the exchange rate of the mark against the [[US dollar]] steadily devalued from 4.2 to 7.9 marks per dollar between 1914 and 1918, a preliminary warning of the extreme postwar inflation.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Officer |first1=Lawrence |title=Exchange Rates Between the United States Dollar and Forty-one Currencies |url=http://www.measuringworth.com/exchangeglobal/ |website=MeasuringWorth |access-date=2015-01-28}}</ref>


This strategy failed as Germany lost the war, which left the new Weimar Republic saddled with massive war debts that it could not afford: the national debt stood at 156 billion marks in 1918.<ref>T. Balderston, "War finance and inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914–1918", ''Economic History Review'' (1989) 42#3 pp. 222–244</ref> The debt problem was exacerbated by printing money without any economic resources to back it.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=103}} The demand in the [[Treaty of Versailles]] for [[World War I reparations|reparations]] – 132&nbsp;billion [[German gold mark|gold marks]] {{nowrap|({{USD|33 billion}}}}, 1914 exchange rate), later revised under the [[Young Plan]] to 112&nbsp;billion marks ({{USD|26.3 billion}}, 1914 exchange rate) – further accelerated the decline in the value of the mark. By late 1919, 48 paper marks were required to buy a US dollar.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book |title = Banking and Monetary Statistics 1914-1941|last = Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System| year = 1943|location = Washington, DC|pages = 671|url = https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/38}}</ref>
This strategy failed as Germany lost the war, which left the new Weimar Republic saddled with massive war debts that it could not afford: the national debt stood at 156 billion marks in 1918.<ref>T. Balderston, "War finance and inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914–1918", ''Economic History Review'' (1989) 42#3 pp. 222–244</ref> The debt problem was exacerbated by printing money without any economic resources to back it.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=103}}


[[John Maynard Keynes]] characterised the inflationary policies of various wartime governments in his 1919 book ''[[The Economic Consequences of the Peace]]'' as follows:
Afterwards, German currency was relatively stable at about 90 marks per dollar during the first half of 1921.<ref>Laursen and Pedersen, page 134</ref> Because the [[Western Front (World War I)|Western Front]] of the war had been mostly fought in [[France]] and [[Belgium]], Germany came out of the war with most of its industrial infrastructure intact, leaving it in a better position to become the dominant economic force on the European continent<ref name="Marks, page 53">Marks, page 53</ref> after an Allied ultimatum to impose economic sanctions that would force Germany to meet payments.<ref>{{cite book|title=The Weimar Republic|pages=41–42|first=Eberhard|last=Kolb|author-link=Eberhard Kolb|others=Translated by P.S. Falla|year=2012|publisher=[[Routledge]]|edition=2nd|isbn=978-0-415-09077-3|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bvpUwefuUKUC&pg=PT92}}</ref>
{{blockquote|The inflationism of the currency systems of Europe has proceeded to extraordinary lengths. The various belligerent Governments, unable, or too timid or too short-sighted to secure from loans or taxes the resources they required, have printed notes for the balance.}}


===Inflation immediately after the First World War===
The first payment was made when it came due in June 1921,<ref>Fergusson, page 38.</ref> and marked the beginning of an increasingly rapid devaluation of the mark, which fell in value to approximately 330 marks per dollar.<ref name=":0" /> The total reparations demanded were 132&nbsp;billion gold marks, but Germany had to pay only 50&nbsp;billion marks at the time, as the reparations were required to be repaid in [[hard currency]], not the rapidly depreciating [[German Papiermark|Papiermark]].<ref name=Marks237>Marks (1978), p. 237</ref>
The value of the German currency continued to fall in the immediate aftermath of the war. By late 1919, the German government had signed the [[Treaty of Versailles]], which included an agreement to pay substantial reparations to the Allied powers both in hard cash and in in-kind shipments of goods such as coal and timber. By then, 48 paper marks were required to buy a US dollar.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book |title = Banking and Monetary Statistics 1914–1941|last = Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System| year = 1943|location = Washington, DC|page = 671|url = https://fraser.stlouisfed.org/title/38}}</ref> In May 1921 the amount to be paid by the Central Powers as a whole was fixed at 132 billion gold marks under the London Schedule of payments which set quarterly deadlines for payments. Of this, 50 billion gold marks was listed in A and B bonds payable under the quarterly deadlines in the schedule; the remaining sum, about 82 billion gold marks, was listed as C bonds that were somewhat hypothetical and not payable under the schedule but instead left to an undefined future date, with the Germans being informed that they realistically would not have to pay them.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|237}}<ref name="Working Papers No. 163/12">{{cite book |last1=Ritschl |first1=Albrecht |title=Reparations, Deficits, and Debt Default: The Great Depression in Germany (Working Papers No. 163/12) |date=June 2012 |publisher=LSE |page=5 |url=https://eprints.lse.ac.uk/44335/1/WP163.pdf |access-date=2 March 2024}}</ref>


The German currency was relatively stable at about 90 marks per dollar during the first half of 1921.<ref>Laursen and Pedersen, p. 134</ref> Because the [[Western Front (World War I)|Western Front]] of the war had been mostly fought in [[France]] and [[Belgium]], Germany came out of the war with most of its industrial infrastructure intact, leaving it in a better place economically than neighbouring France and Belgium.<ref name="Marks, page 53">Marks, The Illusion of Peace, page 53</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=The Weimar Republic|pages=41–42|first=Eberhard|last=Kolb|author-link=Eberhard Kolb|others=Translated by P.S. Falla|year=2012|publisher=[[Routledge]]|edition=2nd|isbn=978-0-415-09077-3|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bvpUwefuUKUC&pg=PT92}}</ref>
From August 1921, the president of the Reichsbank, [[Rudolf Havenstein]] began a strategy of buying foreign currency with marks at any price, without any regard for inflation, and it only increased the speed of the collapse in value of the mark,<ref name="Fergusson p. 40"/> meaning more and more marks were required to buy the foreign currency that was demanded by the Reparations Commission.<ref name="Shapiro, page 187"/>


The first payment of one billion gold marks was made when it came due in June 1921.<ref>Fergusson, p. 38.</ref> At this point, customs posts in the west of Germany were occupied by Allied officials, so that the schedule of payments could be enforced. However, following the first payment the Allied officials were withdrawn from everywhere but [[Düsseldorf]], and whilst some payments in kind continued, only small cash payments were subsequently made for the remainder of 1921–22.<ref name="Marks 1978">{{cite journal |last1=Marks |first1=Sally |title=The Myths of Reparations |journal=Central European History |date=September 1978 |volume=11 |issue=3 |pages=237–239 |doi=10.1017/S0008938900018707 |jstor=4545835 |access-date=22 February 2024 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/4545835}}</ref>{{rp|237}}
In the first half of 1922, the mark stabilized at about 320 marks per dollar.<ref name=":0" /> International reparations conferences were being held. One, in June 1922, was organized by US investment banker [[J. P. Morgan, Jr.]]<ref>Balderston, page 21</ref> The meetings produced no workable solution, and inflation erupted into hyperinflation, the mark falling to 7,400 marks per US dollar by December 1922.<ref name=":0" /> The [[cost-of-living index]] was 41 in June 1922 and 685 in December, a nearly 17-fold increase. By the Autumn of 1922, Havenstein's Reichsbank found itself unable to make reparations payments.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=104}}


From August 1921, the president of the Reichsbank, [[Rudolf Havenstein]], began a strategy of buying foreign currency with marks at any price, without any regard for inflation, and it only increased the speed of the collapse in value of the mark.<ref name="Fergusson p. 40"/> German officials claimed this was in order to make cash payments owed to the Allies using foreign currency. British and French experts stated that this was in an effort to ruin the German currency and, as well as escaping the need for budgetary reform, avoid paying reparations altogether, a claim supported by Reich Chancellery records showing that delaying the currency and budgetary reform that could have addressed hyperinflation was seen as advantageous. Whilst ruinous to the economy and politically destabilising, hyperinflation had advantageous aspects for the German government as, although the war reparations were not listed in paper currency, domestic debts owed from the war were listed, meaning that inflation greatly reduced this debt relative to revenues.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|239}}
The strategy that Havenstein had been using to pay war reparations was the mass printing of bank notes to buy foreign currency, which was then used to pay reparations, but this strategy greatly exacerbated the [[inflation]] of the paper mark.<ref>Fergusson, page 36</ref><ref name="Shapiro, page 187">Shapiro, page 187</ref> Since the mark was, by Autumn of 1922, practically worthless, it was impossible for Havenstein to buy foreign exchange or gold using paper marks. After Germany failed to pay France an installment of reparations on time in late 1922, French and Belgian troops [[Occupation of the Ruhr|occupied the Ruhr valley]], Germany's main industrial region, in January 1923. Reparations were to be paid in goods, such as [[coal]], and the occupation was supposed to ensure reparations payments.


In the first half of 1922, the mark stabilized at about 320 marks per dollar.<ref name=":0" /> International conferences were held. One, in June 1922, was organized by US investment banker [[J. P. Morgan, Jr.]]<ref>Balderston, page 21</ref> The meetings produced no workable solution, and inflation erupted into hyperinflation, the mark falling to 7,400 marks per US dollar by December 1922.<ref name=":0" /> The [[cost-of-living index]] was 41 in June 1922 and 685 in December, a nearly 17-fold increase.{{sfn|Evans|2003|p=104}}
The German government's response was to order a policy of [[passive resistance]] in the Ruhr, with workers being told to do nothing which helped the invaders in any way. While this policy, in practice, amounted to a [[general strike]] to protest the occupation, the striking workers still had to be given financial support. The government paid these workers by printing more and more banknotes, with Germany soon being swamped with paper money, exacerbating the hyperinflation even further.<ref name="johndclare.net">{{Cite web|url=https://www.johndclare.net/Weimar_hyperinflation.htm|title = Hyperinflation}}</ref><ref>''Civilisation in the West, Seventh Edition'', Kishlansky, Geary, and O'Brien, New York, page 807.</ref>

After Germany failed for the thirty-fourth time in thirty-six months to pay an instalment of in-kind reparations of coal, in January 1923 French and Belgian troops [[Occupation of the Ruhr|occupied the Ruhr valley]], Germany's main industrial region. 900 million gold marks of reparations were ultimately secured this way.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|245}}

The German government's response was to order a policy of [[passive resistance]] in the Ruhr, with workers being told to do nothing which helped the French and Belgians in any way. While this policy, in practice, amounted to a [[general strike]] to protest the occupation, the striking workers still had to be given financial support. The government paid these workers by printing more and more banknotes, with Germany soon being swamped with paper money, exacerbating the hyperinflation even further.<ref name="johndclare.net">{{Cite web|url=https://www.johndclare.net/Weimar_hyperinflation.htm|title = Hyperinflation}}</ref><ref>''Civilisation in the West, Seventh Edition'', Kishlansky, Geary, and O'Brien, New York, p. 807.</ref>


==Hyperinflation==
==Hyperinflation==
[[File:Germany Hyperinflation.svg|thumb|Weimar Republic hyperinflation from one to a [[Trillion (short scale)|trillion]] paper marks per gold mark; values on [[logarithmic scale]].]]
[[File:Germany Hyperinflation.svg|thumb|Weimar Republic hyperinflation from one to a [[Trillion (short scale)|trillion]] paper marks per gold mark; values on [[logarithmic scale]].]]


A loaf of bread in Berlin that cost around 160 Marks at the end of 1922 cost 200,000,000,000 Marks by late 1923.<ref name="johndclare.net"/>
A loaf of bread in Berlin that cost around 160 marks at the end of 1922 cost 200,000,000,000 or 200 billion (2×10<sup>11</sup>) marks by late 1923.<ref name="johndclare.net"/>


By November 1923, one US dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 German marks.<ref>Coffin; "Western Civilizations"; p. 918</ref>
By November 1923, one US dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 or 4.2 trillion (4.2105×10<sup>12</sup>) German marks.<ref>Coffin; "Western Civilizations"; p. 918</ref>


<gallery>
<gallery>
Line 45: Line 59:
</gallery>
</gallery>


==Stabilization==
==Stabilisation==
The hyperinflation crisis led prominent economists and politicians to seek a means to stabilize German currency. In August 1923, an economist, [[Karl Helfferich]], proposed a plan to issue a new currency, the "Roggenmark" ("rye mark"), to be backed by [[mortgage bond]]s [[indexation|indexed]] to the [[market price]] of rye grain. The plan was rejected because of the greatly fluctuating price of rye in paper marks.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Born |first=Karl Erich |date=1969 |title=Helfferich, Karl |url=https://www.deutsche-biographie.de/pnd118773828.html#ndbcontent |access-date=20 September 2023 |website=Neue Deutsche Biographie 8 [Online-Version] |pages=470–472}}</ref>
German monetary economics was at that time heavily influenced by [[Chartalism]] and the [[German Historical School]], which conditioned the way the hyperinflation was analysed.<ref name = "Laidler Stadler">[https://www.jstor.org/stable/2601130 ''Monetary Explanations of the Weimar Republic's Hyperinflation: Some Neglected Contributions in Contemporary German Literature'', David E. W. Laidler & George W. Stadler, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 30, pp. 816, 818]</ref> The hyperinflation crisis led prominent economists and politicians to seek a means to stabilize German currency. In August 1923, an economist, [[Karl Helfferich]], proposed a plan to issue a new currency, the "Roggenmark" ("rye mark"), to be backed by [[mortgage bond]]s [[indexation|indexed]] to the [[market price]] of rye grain. The plan was rejected because of the greatly fluctuating price of rye in paper marks.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Born |first=Karl Erich |date=1969 |title=Helfferich, Karl |url=https://www.deutsche-biographie.de/pnd118773828.html#ndbcontent |access-date=20 September 2023 |website=Neue Deutsche Biographie 8 [Online-Version] |pages=470–472}}</ref>


Agriculture Minister [[Hans Luther]] proposed a plan that substituted gold for rye and led to the issuance of the [[German Rentenmark|Rentenmark]] ("mortgage mark"), [[Backed currency|backed]] by [[Bond (finance)|bonds]] [[Indexation|indexed]] to the market price of gold.<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.econ.puc-rio.br/pdf/TD159.pdf |title=''The Rentenmark Miracle'', Gustavo H. B. Franco, page 16 |access-date=2010-01-12 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110706161804/http://www.econ.puc-rio.br/pdf/TD159.pdf |archive-date=2011-07-06 |url-status=dead }}</ref> The [[bond (finance)|gold bonds]] were indexed at the rate of 2,790 gold marks per kilogram of gold, the same as the pre-war [[German gold mark|gold marks]]. Rentenmarks were not redeemable in gold but only indexed to the gold bonds. The plan was adopted in [[monetary reform]] decrees on October 13–15, 1923.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Born |first=Karl Erich |date=1987 |title=Luther, Hans |url=https://www.deutsche-biographie.de/pnd118575422.html#ndbcontent |access-date=20 September 2023 |website=Neue Deutsche Biographie 15 [Online-Version] |pages=544–547}}</ref> A new bank, the [[Deutsche Rentenbank|Rentenbank]], was set up by Hans Luther when he became Finance Minister.<ref>{{Cite web |last1=Llewellyn |first1=Jennifer |last2=Thompson |first2=Steve |date=26 September 2019 |title=The hyperinflation of 1923 |url=https://alphahistory.com/weimarrepublic/1923-hyperinflation/ |access-date=23 September 2023 |website=Alpha History}}</ref>
Agriculture Minister [[Hans Luther]] proposed a plan that substituted gold for rye and led to the issuance of the [[German Rentenmark|Rentenmark]] ("mortgage mark"), [[Backed currency|backed]] by [[Bond (finance)|bonds]] [[Indexation|indexed]] to the market price of gold.<ref>{{Cite web |url=http://www.econ.puc-rio.br/pdf/TD159.pdf |title=The Rentenmark Miracle|author= Gustavo H. B. Franco|
page =16 |access-date=2010-01-12 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110706161804/http://www.econ.puc-rio.br/pdf/TD159.pdf |archive-date=2011-07-06 |url-status=dead }}</ref> The [[bond (finance)|gold bonds]] were indexed at the rate of 2,790 gold marks per kilogram of gold, the same as the pre-war [[German gold mark|gold marks]]. Rentenmarks were not redeemable in gold but only indexed to the gold bonds. The plan was adopted in [[monetary reform]] decrees on 13–15 October 1923.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Born |first=Karl Erich |date=1987 |title=Luther, Hans |url=https://www.deutsche-biographie.de/pnd118575422.html#ndbcontent |access-date=20 September 2023 |website=Neue Deutsche Biographie 15 [Online-Version] |pages=544–547}}</ref> A new bank, the [[Deutsche Rentenbank|Rentenbank]], was set up by Hans Luther when he became Finance Minister.<ref>{{Cite web |last1=Llewellyn |first1=Jennifer |last2=Thompson |first2=Steve |date=26 September 2019 |title=The hyperinflation of 1923 |url=https://alphahistory.com/weimarrepublic/1923-hyperinflation/ |access-date=23 September 2023 |website=Alpha History}}</ref>


[[File:Zwei Rentenmark a.jpg|left|thumb|Two Rentenmark note, issued in line with the Decree of 15 October 1923]]
[[File:Zwei Rentenmark a.jpg|left|thumb|Two Rentenmark note, issued in line with the Decree of 15 October 1923]]
After November 12, 1923, when [[Hjalmar Schacht]] became currency commissioner, Germany's central bank (the [[Reichsbank]]) was not allowed to discount any further government [[Treasury bills]], which meant the corresponding issue of paper marks also ceased.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Guttmann |first=William. |title=The Great Inflation |publisher=Saxon House |year=1975 |isbn=978-0347000178 |location=Hants, UK |pages=208–211}}</ref> The discounting of commercial trade bills was allowed and the amount of Rentenmarks expanded, but the issue was strictly controlled to conform to current commercial and government transactions. The Rentenbank refused credit to the government and to speculators who were not able to borrow Rentenmarks, because Rentenmarks were not legal tender.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 13">Fergusson, Chapter 13</ref>
After 12 November 1923, when [[Hjalmar Schacht]] became currency commissioner, Germany's central bank (the [[Reichsbank]]) was not allowed to discount any further government [[Treasury bills]], which meant the corresponding issue of paper marks also ceased.<ref>{{Cite book |last=Guttmann |first=William. |title=The Great Inflation |publisher=Saxon House |year=1975 |isbn=978-0347000178 |location=Hants, UK |pages=208–211}}</ref> The discounting of commercial trade bills was allowed and the amount of Rentenmarks expanded, but the issue was strictly controlled to conform to current commercial and government transactions. The Rentenbank refused credit to the government and to speculators who were not able to borrow Rentenmarks, because Rentenmarks were not legal tender.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 13">Fergusson, Chapter 13</ref>


On November 16, 1923, the new Rentenmark was introduced to replace the worthless paper marks issued by the Reichsbank. Twelve zeros were cut from prices, and the prices quoted in the new currency remained stable. <ref>{{Cite journal |last=Pfleiderer |first=Otto |date=September 1979 |title=Two Types of Inflation, Two Types of Currency Reform: The German Currency Miracles of 1923 and 1948 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/40750148 |journal=Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics |publisher=Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co. |volume=135 |issue=3 |pages=356 |jstor=40750148 |via=JSTOR}}</ref>
On 16 November 1923, the new Rentenmark was introduced to replace the worthless paper marks issued by the Reichsbank. Twelve zeros were cut from prices, and the prices quoted in the new currency remained stable.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Pfleiderer |first=Otto |date=September 1979 |title=Two Types of Inflation, Two Types of Currency Reform: The German Currency Miracles of 1923 and 1948 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/40750148 |journal=Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics |publisher=Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co. |volume=135 |issue=3 |page=356 |jstor=40750148 }}</ref>


When the president of the Reichsbank, Rudolf Havenstein, died on November 20, 1923, Schacht was appointed to replace him. By November 30, 1923, there were 500,000,000 Rentenmarks in circulation, which increased to 1,000,000,000 by January 1, 1924, and to 1,800,000,000 Rentenmarks by July 1924. Meanwhile, the old paper Marks continued in circulation. The total paper marks increased to 1.2 [[sextillion]] (1,200,000,000,000,000,000,000) in July 1924 and continued to fall in value to a third of their conversion value in Rentenmarks.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 13"/>
When the president of the Reichsbank, Rudolf Havenstein, died on 20 November 1923, Schacht was appointed to replace him. By 30 November 1923, there were 500,000,000 Rentenmarks in circulation, which increased to 1,000,000,000 by January 1, 1924, and to 1,800,000,000 Rentenmarks by July 1924. Meanwhile, the old paper Marks continued in circulation. The total paper marks increased to 1.2 [[sextillion]] (1,200,000,000,000,000,000,000) in July 1924 and continued to fall in value to a third of their conversion value in Rentenmarks.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 13"/>


On August 30, 1924, a monetary law permitted the exchange of a 1-trillion paper mark note to a new [[Reichsmark]], worth the same as a Rentenmark.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Southern |first=David B. |date=March 1979 |title=The Revaluation Question in the Weimar Republic |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1878444 |journal=The Journal of Modern History |volume=51 |issue=1 |page=D1031 |doi=10.1086/242035 |jstor=1878444 |s2cid=144523809 |via=JSTOR}}</ref> By 1924 one dollar was equivalent to 4.2 Rentenmark.<ref>{{Cite book |last1=Swastika |first1=Putri |url={{Google books|odFCEAAAQBAJ|page=99|plainurl=yes}} |title=Applying Risk-Sharing Finance for Economic Development. Lessons from Germany |last2=Mirakhor |first2=Abbas |publisher=Springer International |year=2021 |isbn=978-3030826420 |location=Berlin |pages=99, footnote 31}}</ref>
On 30 August 1924, a monetary law permitted the exchange of a 1-trillion paper mark note to a new [[Reichsmark]], worth the same as a Rentenmark.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Southern |first=David B. |date=March 1979 |title=The Revaluation Question in the Weimar Republic |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1878444 |journal=The Journal of Modern History |volume=51 |issue=1 |page=D1031 |doi=10.1086/242035 |jstor=1878444 |s2cid=144523809}}</ref> By 1924 one dollar was equivalent to 4.2 Rentenmark.<ref>{{Cite book |last1=Swastika |first1=Putri |url={{Google books|odFCEAAAQBAJ|page=99|plainurl=yes}} |title=Applying Risk-Sharing Finance for Economic Development. Lessons from Germany |last2=Mirakhor |first2=Abbas |publisher=Springer International |year=2021 |isbn=978-3030826420 |location=Berlin |page=99, footnote 31}}</ref>


==Revaluation==
==Revaluation==
Line 64: Line 79:
Eventually, some debts were reinstated to compensate creditors partially for the catastrophic reduction in the value of debts that had been quoted in paper marks before the hyperinflation. A decree of 1925 reinstated some mortgages at 25% of face value in the new currency, effectively 25,000,000,000 times their value in the old paper marks, if they had been held for at least five years. Similarly, some government bonds were reinstated at 2.5% of face value, to be paid after reparations were paid.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 14">Fergusson, Chapter 14</ref>
Eventually, some debts were reinstated to compensate creditors partially for the catastrophic reduction in the value of debts that had been quoted in paper marks before the hyperinflation. A decree of 1925 reinstated some mortgages at 25% of face value in the new currency, effectively 25,000,000,000 times their value in the old paper marks, if they had been held for at least five years. Similarly, some government bonds were reinstated at 2.5% of face value, to be paid after reparations were paid.<ref name="Fergusson, Chapter 14">Fergusson, Chapter 14</ref>


Mortgage debt was reinstated at much higher rates than government bonds were. The reinstatement of some debts and a resumption of effective taxation in a still-devastated economy triggered a wave of corporate [[bankruptcy|bankruptcies]].{{cn|date=December 2023}}
Mortgage debt was reinstated at much higher rates than government bonds were. The reinstatement of some debts and a resumption of effective taxation in a still-devastated economy triggered a wave of corporate [[bankruptcy|bankruptcies]].{{citation needed|date=December 2023}}


One of the important issues of the stabilization of a hyperinflation is the ''revaluation''. The term normally refers to the raising of the exchange rate of one national currency against other currencies. As well, it can mean ''revalorization'', the restoration of the value of a currency depreciated by inflation. The German government had the choice of a revaluation law to finish the hyperinflation quickly or of allowing sprawling and the political and violent disturbances on the streets. The government argued in detail that the interests of creditors and debtors had to be fair and balanced. Neither the living standard price index nor the share price index was judged as relevant.{{cn|date=December 2023}}
One of the important issues of the stabilization of a hyperinflation is the ''revaluation''. The term normally refers to the raising of the exchange rate of one national currency against other currencies. As well, it can mean ''revalorization'', the restoration of the value of a currency depreciated by inflation. The German government had the choice of a revaluation law to finish the hyperinflation quickly or of allowing sprawling and the political and violent disturbances on the streets. The government argued in detail that the interests of creditors and debtors had to be fair and balanced. Neither the living standard price index nor the share price index was judged as relevant.{{citation needed|date=December 2023}}


The calculation of the conversion relation was considerably judged to the dollar index as well as to the [[wholesale price index]]. In principle, the German government followed the line of market-oriented reasoning that the dollar index and the wholesale price index would roughly indicate the ''true'' price level in general over the period of high inflation and hyperinflation. In addition, the revaluation was bound on the exchange rate mark and United States dollar to obtain the value of the ''Goldmark''.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=83}}
The calculation of the conversion relation{{clarify|date=November 2024}} was considerably judged to the dollar index as well as to the [[wholesale price index]]. In principle, the German government followed the line of market-oriented reasoning that the dollar index and the wholesale price index would roughly indicate the ''true'' price level in general over the period of high inflation and hyperinflation. In addition, the revaluation was bound on the exchange rate mark and United States dollar to obtain the value of the ''Goldmark''.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=83}}


Finally, the Law on the Revaluation of Mortgages and other Claims of 16 July 1925 (''{{lang|de|Gesetz über die Aufwertung von Hypotheken und anderen Ansprüchen}}'' or ''{{lang|de|Aufwertungsgesetze}}'') included only the ratio of the paper mark to the gold mark for the period from January 1, 1918, to November 30, 1923, and the following days.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=84}} The galloping inflation thus caused the end of a principle, "a mark is worth a mark", which had been recognized, the nominal value principle.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=87}}
Finally, the Law on the Revaluation of Mortgages and other Claims of 16 July 1925 (''{{lang|de|Gesetz über die Aufwertung von Hypotheken und anderen Ansprüchen}}'' or ''{{lang|de|Aufwertungsgesetze}}'') included only the ratio of the paper mark to the gold mark for the period from 1 January 1918, to 30 November 1923, and the following days.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=84}} The galloping inflation thus caused the end of a principle, "a mark is worth a mark", which had been recognized, the nominal value principle.{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=87}}


The law was challenged in the Supreme Court of the German Reich (''{{lang|de|[[Reichsgericht]]}}''), but its 5th Senate ruled, on November 4, 1925, that the law was constitutional, even according to the Bill of Rights and Duties of Germans (Articles 109, 134, 152 and 153 of the Constitution).{{sfn|Friedrich|1928|p=197}}<ref>''{{lang|de|RGZ}} III, 325''</ref>{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=89}} The case set a precedent for [[judicial review]] in German jurisprudence.{{sfn|Friedrich|1928|pp=196-197}}
The law was challenged in the Supreme Court of the German Reich (''{{lang|de|[[Reichsgericht]]}}''), but its 5th Senate ruled, on 4 November 1925, that the law was constitutional, even according to the Bill of Rights and Duties of Germans (Articles 109, 134, 152 and 153 of the Constitution).{{sfn|Friedrich|1928|p=197}}<ref>''{{lang|de|RGZ}} III, 325''</ref>{{sfn|Fischer|2010|p=89}} The case set a precedent for [[judicial review]] in German jurisprudence.{{sfn|Friedrich|1928|pp=196–197}}


==Analysis==
==Causes==
Historians and economists differ over the causes of the German hyperinflation, particularly on the subject of whether it was caused by reparations payments.
The hyperinflation episode in the Weimar Republic in the early 1920s was not the first or even the most severe instance of inflation in history. <ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.cato.org/publications/working-paper/world-hyperinflations |title=World Hyperinflations &#124; Steve H. Hanke and Nicholas Krus &#124; Cato Institute: Working Paper |publisher=Cato.org |date=15 August 2012 |access-date=15 October 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121017012645/http://www.cato.org/publications/working-paper/world-hyperinflations |archive-date=17 October 2012 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.karlwhelan.com/IMB/Hyperinflations.pdf|title=World Hyperinflations|publisher=CNBC|date=14 February 2011|access-date=13 July 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130905085358/http://www.karlwhelan.com/IMB/Hyperinflations.pdf|archive-date=5 September 2013|url-status=live}}</ref> However, it has been the subject of the most scholarly [[economic]] analysis and debate. The hyperinflation drew significant interest, as many of the dramatic and unusual economic behaviors now associated with hyperinflation were first documented systematically: [[Exponential growth|exponential]] increases in prices and interest rates, [[redenomination|redenomination of the currency]], consumer flight from cash to hard assets and the rapid expansion of industries that produced those assets.


The Treaty of Versailles had imposed an undefined debt on Germany, which the London Schedule of Payments agreed in May 1921 had determined to be essentially 50 billion marks in A and B bonds payable partly in-kind with goods like coal and timber, and partly in gold and hard-cash. From June 1921, when a single payment of 1 billion gold marks was paid (roughly 1.4% of Germany's nominal 1925 GNP){{ref|German nominal GNP in 1925 was approximately 71.1 bn Reichsmarks, see LSE Working Papers No. 163/12, Table 2.1}}, until the agreement of the Dawes plan in late 1924, only relatively small cash payments were made by Germany, though partial in-kind payments continued. For example, of the 300 million gold marks due under a variable annuity in November 1921, only 13 million was paid, and of the roughly 3 billion gold marks total due under payments in 1922, only 435 million were paid in cash.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|238}}
German monetary economics was at that time heavily influenced by [[Chartalism]] and the [[German Historical School]], which conditioned the way the hyperinflation was analyzed.<ref name = "Laidler Stadler">[https://www.jstor.org/stable/2601130 ''Monetary Explanations of the Weimar Republic's Hyperinflation: Some Neglected Contributions in Contemporary German Literature'', David E. W. Laidler & George W. Stadler, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 30, pages 816, 818]</ref>


Germany's leadership claimed that, with its gold depleted, inflation resulted during 1921–23 due to attempts to buy foreign currency with German currency in an effort to make cash payments as reparations. This would be equivalent to selling German currency in exchange for payment in foreign currency, but the resulting increase in the supply of German marks on the market caused the German mark to fall rapidly in value.<ref name="Fergusson p. 40">Fergusson; ''When Money Dies''; p. 40</ref><ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|238}}
[[John Maynard Keynes]] described the situation in ''[[The Economic Consequences of the Peace]]'':
{{blockquote|The inflationism of the currency systems of Europe has proceeded to extraordinary lengths. The various belligerent Governments, unable, or too timid or too short-sighted to secure from loans or taxes the resources they required, have printed notes for the balance.}}


British and French experts claimed that the German leadership were purposefully stoking inflation as a way of avoiding paying reparations, as well as a way of avoiding budgetary reforms – a view later supported by analysis of Reich Chancellery record showing that tax reform and currency stabilisation was delayed in 1922–23 in the hope of reductions in reparations. Particularly, Allied analysis of German statistics showed that printing of paper currency was being used to maintain tax rates much lower than in Allied countries, to fund relatively high levels of state expenditure, and that this effect was being worsened by unrestricted [[capital flight]] from Germany. Reparations payments continued more or less in full from 1924 to 1931 without a return of hyperinflation and, after 1930, Germany protested that reparations payments were [[deflation]]ary.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|239}} Inflation also enabled the German government to pay off its substantial domestic debts, particularly war debts, in devalued marks.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|245}}
It was then that French and British economic experts began to claim that Germany deliberately destroyed its economy to avoid war reparations, but both governments had conflicting views on how to handle the situation. The French declared that Germany should keep paying reparations, but Britain sought to grant a [[moratorium (law)|moratorium]] to allow financial reconstruction.<ref name="Marks, page 53"/>


One point on which historians tend to agree is that the printing of cash by the German government to make payments to striking workers in the Ruhr, who were refusing to make reparations deliveries to the Allies, contributed to hyperinflation.<ref name="Marks 1978" />{{rp|245}}<ref name="Fergusson p. 40" /> The occupation of the Ruhr also caused German output to fall.<ref name="Working Papers No. 163/12" />
Firms responded to the crisis by focusing on those elements of their information systems they identified as essential to continuing operations. In the beginning the focus was on adjusting sales and procurement arrangements, modifications to financial reporting, and the use of more nonmonetary information in internal reporting. With the continuous acceleration of inflation, human resources were redeployed to the most critical corporate functions, in particular those involved in the remuneration of labor. There is evidence that some parts of corporate accounting systems fell into disrepair, but there was also innovation.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Hoffmann|first1=Sebastian|last2=Walker|first2=Stephen P.|date=2020|title=Adapting to Crisis: Accounting Information Systems during the Weimar Hyperinflation|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/business-history-review/article/abs/adapting-to-crisis-accounting-information-systems-during-the-weimar-hyperinflation/9DC8DC9AC8D0A205288CB6DB96A46656|journal=Business History Review|language=en|volume=94|issue=3|pages=593–625|doi=10.1017/S0007680520000550|s2cid=225645243|issn=0007-6805|hdl=20.500.11820/e7755750-6903-4ab9-aab2-da795ed70c25|hdl-access=free}}</ref>

Regardless of the reason for the declining value of the German currency, the decline caused prices of goods to rise rapidly, increasing the cost of operating the German government, which could not be financed by raising taxes because those taxes would be payable in the ever-falling German currency. The resulting deficit was financed by some combination of issuing bonds and simply creating more money: both increasing the supply of German mark-denominated financial assets on the market and so further reducing the currency's price. When the German people realized that their money was rapidly losing value, they tried to spend it quickly. That increased [[monetary velocity]] and caused an ever-faster increase in prices, creating a [[vicious cycle]].<ref>Parsson; ''Dying of Money''; pp. 116{{Ndash}}117</ref>

The government and the banks had two unacceptable alternatives. If they stopped inflation, there would be immediate bankruptcies, unemployment, strikes, hunger, violence, collapse of civil order, insurrection and possibly even revolution.<ref name="Fergusson p. 254">Fergusson; ''When Money Dies''; p. 254</ref> If they continued the inflation, they would default on their foreign debt. However, attempting to avoid both unemployment and insolvency ultimately failed when Germany had both.<ref name="Fergusson p. 254"/>


==Aftermath and legacy==
==Aftermath and legacy==
[[File:Bundesarchiv Bild 102-00104, Inflation, Tapezieren mit Geldscheinen.jpg|right|upright|thumb|Germany, 1923: banknotes had lost so much value that they were used as wallpaper.]]
[[File:Bundesarchiv Bild 102-00104, Inflation, Tapezieren mit Geldscheinen.jpg|right|upright|thumb|Germany, 1923: banknotes had lost so much value that they were used as wallpaper.]]
The hyperinflation episode in the Weimar Republic in the early 1920s was not the first or even the most severe instance of inflation in history.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.cato.org/publications/working-paper/world-hyperinflations |title=World Hyperinflations &#124; Steve H. Hanke and Nicholas Krus &#124; Cato Institute: Working Paper |publisher=Cato.org |date=15 August 2012 |access-date=15 October 2012 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121017012645/http://www.cato.org/publications/working-paper/world-hyperinflations |archive-date=17 October 2012 |url-status=live }}</ref><ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.karlwhelan.com/IMB/Hyperinflations.pdf|title=World Hyperinflations|publisher=CNBC|date=14 February 2011|access-date=13 July 2012|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20130905085358/http://www.karlwhelan.com/IMB/Hyperinflations.pdf|archive-date=5 September 2013|url-status=live}}</ref> However, it has been the subject of the most scholarly [[economic]] analysis and debate. The hyperinflation drew significant interest, as many of the dramatic and unusual economic behaviors now associated with hyperinflation were first documented systematically: [[Exponential growth|exponential]] increases in prices and interest rates, [[redenomination|redenomination of the currency]], consumer flight from cash to hard assets and the rapid expansion of industries that produced those assets.


Since the hyperinflation, German monetary policy has retained a central concern with the maintenance of a sound currency, a concern that had an effect on the [[European sovereign debt crisis]].<ref>[http://www.csmonitor.com/World/Europe/2010/0328/Greece-bailout-What-s-the-future-of-the-euro/(page)/2 ''Greece bailout: What's the future of the euro?'', Ben Quinn, Christian Science Monitor, 28 March 2010]</ref> According to one study, many Germans conflate hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic with the Great Depression, seeing the two separate events as one big economic crisis that encompassed both rapidly rising prices and mass unemployment.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Haffert|first1=Lukas|last2=Redeker|first2=Nils|last3=Rommel|first3=Tobias|title=Misremembering Weimar: Hyperinflation, the Great Depression, and German collective economic memory|journal=Economics & Politics|year=2021|volume=33|issue=3|pages=664–686|language=en|doi=10.1111/ecpo.12182|s2cid=233631576 |issn=1468-0343|doi-access=}}</ref>
Since the hyperinflation, German monetary policy has retained a central concern with the maintenance of a sound currency, a concern that had an effect on the [[European sovereign debt crisis]].<ref>[http://www.csmonitor.com/World/Europe/2010/0328/Greece-bailout-What-s-the-future-of-the-euro/(page)/2 ''Greece bailout: What's the future of the euro?'', Ben Quinn, Christian Science Monitor, 28 March 2010]</ref> According to one study, many Germans conflate hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic with the [[Great Depression]], seeing the two separate events as one big economic crisis that encompassed both rapidly rising prices and mass unemployment.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Haffert|first1=Lukas|last2=Redeker|first2=Nils|last3=Rommel|first3=Tobias|title=Misremembering Weimar: Hyperinflation, the Great Depression, and German collective economic memory|journal=Economics & Politics|year=2021|volume=33|issue=3|pages=664–686|language=en|doi=10.1111/ecpo.12182|s2cid=233631576 |issn=1468-0343|doi-access=}}</ref>


The hyperinflated, worthless marks became widely collected abroad. The ''[[Los Angeles Times]]'' estimated in 1924 that more of the decommissioned notes were spread about the US than existed in Germany.<ref name="awmol">''Americans With Marks Out of Luck'', Cable and Associated Press, Los Angeles Times, 15 Nov 1924</ref>
The hyperinflated, worthless marks became widely collected abroad. The ''[[Los Angeles Times]]'' estimated in 1924 that more of the decommissioned notes were spread about the US than existed in Germany.<ref name="awmol">''Americans With Marks Out of Luck'', Cable and Associated Press, Los Angeles Times, 15 Nov 1924</ref>


Firms responded to the crisis by focusing on those elements of their information systems they identified as essential to continuing operations. In the beginning the focus was on adjusting sales and procurement arrangements, modifications to financial reporting, and the use of more nonmonetary information in internal reporting. With the continuous acceleration of inflation, human resources were redeployed to the most critical corporate functions, in particular those involved in the remuneration of labor. There is evidence that some parts of corporate accounting systems fell into disrepair, but there was also innovation.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Hoffmann|first1=Sebastian|last2=Walker|first2=Stephen P.|date=2020|title=Adapting to Crisis: Accounting Information Systems during the Weimar Hyperinflation|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/business-history-review/article/abs/adapting-to-crisis-accounting-information-systems-during-the-weimar-hyperinflation/9DC8DC9AC8D0A205288CB6DB96A46656|journal=Business History Review|language=en|volume=94|issue=3|pages=593–625|doi=10.1017/S0007680520000550|s2cid=225645243|issn=0007-6805|hdl=20.500.11820/e7755750-6903-4ab9-aab2-da795ed70c25|hdl-access=free}}</ref>
==Causes==
The Treaty of Versailles imposed a huge debt on Germany that could be paid only in gold or foreign currency. With its gold depleted, the German government attempted to buy foreign currency with German currency,<ref name="Fergusson p. 40">Fergusson; ''When Money Dies''; p. 40</ref> equivalent to selling German currency in exchange for payment in foreign currency, but the resulting increase in the supply of German marks on the market caused the German mark to fall rapidly in value, which greatly increased the number of marks needed to buy more foreign currency.

That caused German prices of goods to rise rapidly, increasing the cost of operating the German government, which could not be financed by raising taxes because those taxes would be payable in the ever-falling German currency. The resulting deficit was financed by some combination of issuing bonds and simply creating more money, both increasing the supply of German mark-denominated financial assets on the market and so further reducing the currency's price. When the German people realized that their money was rapidly losing value, they tried to spend it quickly. That increased [[monetary velocity]] caused an ever-faster increase in prices, creating a [[vicious cycle]].<ref>Parsson; ''Dying of Money''; pp. 116{{Ndash}}117</ref>

The government and the banks had two unacceptable alternatives. If they stopped inflation, there would be immediate bankruptcies, unemployment, strikes, hunger, violence, collapse of civil order, insurrection and possibly even revolution.<ref name="Fergusson p. 254">Fergusson; ''When Money Dies''; p. 254</ref> If they continued the inflation, they would default on their foreign debt.

However, attempting to avoid both unemployment and insolvency ultimately failed when Germany had both.<ref name="Fergusson p. 254"/>


== See also ==
== See also ==
Line 144: Line 156:
[[Category:1923 in economic history]]
[[Category:1923 in economic history]]
[[Category:1923 in Germany]]
[[Category:1923 in Germany]]
[[Category:Economic history of Germany]]
[[Category:Economy of the Weimar Republic]]
[[Category:Economy of the Weimar Republic]]
[[Category:Inflation in Germany]]
[[Category:Inflation in Germany]]
Line 150: Line 161:
[[Category:1923 disasters in Germany]]
[[Category:1923 disasters in Germany]]
[[Category:1920s disasters in Germany]]
[[Category:1920s disasters in Germany]]
[[Category:Hyperinflation|Weimar]]

Latest revision as of 19:58, 28 November 2024

Piles of new Notgeld banknotes awaiting distribution at the Reichsbank during the hyperinflation

Hyperinflation affected the German Papiermark, the currency of the Weimar Republic, between 1921 and 1923, primarily in 1923. The German currency had seen significant inflation during the First World War due to the way in which the German government funded its war effort through borrowing, with debts of 156 billion marks by 1918. This national debt was substantially increased by 50 billion marks of reparations payable in cash and in-kind (e.g., with coal and timber) under the May 1921 London Schedule of Payments agreed after the Versailles treaty.

This inflation continued into the post-war period, particularly when in August 1921 the German central bank began buying hard cash with paper currency at any price, which they claimed was to pay reparations in hard cash, though little in the way of cash reparations payments were made until 1924. The currency stabilised in early 1922, but then hyperinflation took off: the exchange value of the mark fell from 320 marks per dollar in mid 1922 to 7,400 marks per US dollar by December 1922. This hyperinflation continued into 1923, and by November 1923, one US dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 marks. Various measures were introduced by German authorities to address this, including a new currency called the Rentenmark, backed by mortgage bonds, later itself replaced by the Reichsmark, and the blocking of the national bank from printing further paper currency.

By 1924 the currency had stabilised and German reparations payments began again under the Dawes Plan. As the catastrophic fall in the value of the mark had effectively wiped out debts owed, some debts (e.g. mortgages) were revalued so that the lenders could recoup some of their money.

Hyperinflation caused considerable internal political instability in the country. Historians and economists are divided on the causes of this hyperinflation, particularly the extent to which it was caused by reparations payments.

Background

[edit]

Inflation during the First World War

[edit]

To pay for the large costs of the First World War, Germany suspended the gold standard (the convertibility of its currency to gold) when the war broke out in 1914. Unlike France, which imposed its first income tax to pay for the war, German Emperor Wilhelm II and the Reichstag decided unanimously to fund the war entirely by borrowing.

The government believed that it would be able to pay off the debt by winning the war and imposing war reparations on the defeated Allies. This was to be done by annexing resource-rich industrial territory in the west and east and imposing cash payments to Germany, similar to the French indemnity that followed German victory over France in 1870.[1] However, the exchange rate of the mark against the US dollar steadily devalued from 4.2 to 7.9 marks per dollar between 1914 and 1918, a preliminary warning of the extreme postwar inflation.[2]

This strategy failed as Germany lost the war, which left the new Weimar Republic saddled with massive war debts that it could not afford: the national debt stood at 156 billion marks in 1918.[3] The debt problem was exacerbated by printing money without any economic resources to back it.[1]

John Maynard Keynes characterised the inflationary policies of various wartime governments in his 1919 book The Economic Consequences of the Peace as follows:

The inflationism of the currency systems of Europe has proceeded to extraordinary lengths. The various belligerent Governments, unable, or too timid or too short-sighted to secure from loans or taxes the resources they required, have printed notes for the balance.

Inflation immediately after the First World War

[edit]

The value of the German currency continued to fall in the immediate aftermath of the war. By late 1919, the German government had signed the Treaty of Versailles, which included an agreement to pay substantial reparations to the Allied powers both in hard cash and in in-kind shipments of goods such as coal and timber. By then, 48 paper marks were required to buy a US dollar.[4] In May 1921 the amount to be paid by the Central Powers as a whole was fixed at 132 billion gold marks under the London Schedule of payments which set quarterly deadlines for payments. Of this, 50 billion gold marks was listed in A and B bonds payable under the quarterly deadlines in the schedule; the remaining sum, about 82 billion gold marks, was listed as C bonds that were somewhat hypothetical and not payable under the schedule but instead left to an undefined future date, with the Germans being informed that they realistically would not have to pay them.[5]: 237 [6]

The German currency was relatively stable at about 90 marks per dollar during the first half of 1921.[7] Because the Western Front of the war had been mostly fought in France and Belgium, Germany came out of the war with most of its industrial infrastructure intact, leaving it in a better place economically than neighbouring France and Belgium.[8][9]

The first payment of one billion gold marks was made when it came due in June 1921.[10] At this point, customs posts in the west of Germany were occupied by Allied officials, so that the schedule of payments could be enforced. However, following the first payment the Allied officials were withdrawn from everywhere but Düsseldorf, and whilst some payments in kind continued, only small cash payments were subsequently made for the remainder of 1921–22.[5]: 237 

From August 1921, the president of the Reichsbank, Rudolf Havenstein, began a strategy of buying foreign currency with marks at any price, without any regard for inflation, and it only increased the speed of the collapse in value of the mark.[11] German officials claimed this was in order to make cash payments owed to the Allies using foreign currency. British and French experts stated that this was in an effort to ruin the German currency and, as well as escaping the need for budgetary reform, avoid paying reparations altogether, a claim supported by Reich Chancellery records showing that delaying the currency and budgetary reform that could have addressed hyperinflation was seen as advantageous. Whilst ruinous to the economy and politically destabilising, hyperinflation had advantageous aspects for the German government as, although the war reparations were not listed in paper currency, domestic debts owed from the war were listed, meaning that inflation greatly reduced this debt relative to revenues.[5]: 239 

In the first half of 1922, the mark stabilized at about 320 marks per dollar.[4] International conferences were held. One, in June 1922, was organized by US investment banker J. P. Morgan, Jr.[12] The meetings produced no workable solution, and inflation erupted into hyperinflation, the mark falling to 7,400 marks per US dollar by December 1922.[4] The cost-of-living index was 41 in June 1922 and 685 in December, a nearly 17-fold increase.[13]

After Germany failed for the thirty-fourth time in thirty-six months to pay an instalment of in-kind reparations of coal, in January 1923 French and Belgian troops occupied the Ruhr valley, Germany's main industrial region. 900 million gold marks of reparations were ultimately secured this way.[5]: 245 

The German government's response was to order a policy of passive resistance in the Ruhr, with workers being told to do nothing which helped the French and Belgians in any way. While this policy, in practice, amounted to a general strike to protest the occupation, the striking workers still had to be given financial support. The government paid these workers by printing more and more banknotes, with Germany soon being swamped with paper money, exacerbating the hyperinflation even further.[14][15]

Hyperinflation

[edit]
Weimar Republic hyperinflation from one to a trillion paper marks per gold mark; values on logarithmic scale.

A loaf of bread in Berlin that cost around 160 marks at the end of 1922 cost 200,000,000,000 or 200 billion (2×1011) marks by late 1923.[14]

By November 1923, one US dollar was worth 4,210,500,000,000 or 4.2 trillion (4.2105×1012) German marks.[16]

Stabilisation

[edit]

German monetary economics was at that time heavily influenced by Chartalism and the German Historical School, which conditioned the way the hyperinflation was analysed.[17] The hyperinflation crisis led prominent economists and politicians to seek a means to stabilize German currency. In August 1923, an economist, Karl Helfferich, proposed a plan to issue a new currency, the "Roggenmark" ("rye mark"), to be backed by mortgage bonds indexed to the market price of rye grain. The plan was rejected because of the greatly fluctuating price of rye in paper marks.[18]

Agriculture Minister Hans Luther proposed a plan that substituted gold for rye and led to the issuance of the Rentenmark ("mortgage mark"), backed by bonds indexed to the market price of gold.[19] The gold bonds were indexed at the rate of 2,790 gold marks per kilogram of gold, the same as the pre-war gold marks. Rentenmarks were not redeemable in gold but only indexed to the gold bonds. The plan was adopted in monetary reform decrees on 13–15 October 1923.[20] A new bank, the Rentenbank, was set up by Hans Luther when he became Finance Minister.[21]

Two Rentenmark note, issued in line with the Decree of 15 October 1923

After 12 November 1923, when Hjalmar Schacht became currency commissioner, Germany's central bank (the Reichsbank) was not allowed to discount any further government Treasury bills, which meant the corresponding issue of paper marks also ceased.[22] The discounting of commercial trade bills was allowed and the amount of Rentenmarks expanded, but the issue was strictly controlled to conform to current commercial and government transactions. The Rentenbank refused credit to the government and to speculators who were not able to borrow Rentenmarks, because Rentenmarks were not legal tender.[23]

On 16 November 1923, the new Rentenmark was introduced to replace the worthless paper marks issued by the Reichsbank. Twelve zeros were cut from prices, and the prices quoted in the new currency remained stable.[24]

When the president of the Reichsbank, Rudolf Havenstein, died on 20 November 1923, Schacht was appointed to replace him. By 30 November 1923, there were 500,000,000 Rentenmarks in circulation, which increased to 1,000,000,000 by January 1, 1924, and to 1,800,000,000 Rentenmarks by July 1924. Meanwhile, the old paper Marks continued in circulation. The total paper marks increased to 1.2 sextillion (1,200,000,000,000,000,000,000) in July 1924 and continued to fall in value to a third of their conversion value in Rentenmarks.[23]

On 30 August 1924, a monetary law permitted the exchange of a 1-trillion paper mark note to a new Reichsmark, worth the same as a Rentenmark.[25] By 1924 one dollar was equivalent to 4.2 Rentenmark.[26]

Revaluation

[edit]
Conversion table

Eventually, some debts were reinstated to compensate creditors partially for the catastrophic reduction in the value of debts that had been quoted in paper marks before the hyperinflation. A decree of 1925 reinstated some mortgages at 25% of face value in the new currency, effectively 25,000,000,000 times their value in the old paper marks, if they had been held for at least five years. Similarly, some government bonds were reinstated at 2.5% of face value, to be paid after reparations were paid.[27]

Mortgage debt was reinstated at much higher rates than government bonds were. The reinstatement of some debts and a resumption of effective taxation in a still-devastated economy triggered a wave of corporate bankruptcies.[citation needed]

One of the important issues of the stabilization of a hyperinflation is the revaluation. The term normally refers to the raising of the exchange rate of one national currency against other currencies. As well, it can mean revalorization, the restoration of the value of a currency depreciated by inflation. The German government had the choice of a revaluation law to finish the hyperinflation quickly or of allowing sprawling and the political and violent disturbances on the streets. The government argued in detail that the interests of creditors and debtors had to be fair and balanced. Neither the living standard price index nor the share price index was judged as relevant.[citation needed]

The calculation of the conversion relation[clarification needed] was considerably judged to the dollar index as well as to the wholesale price index. In principle, the German government followed the line of market-oriented reasoning that the dollar index and the wholesale price index would roughly indicate the true price level in general over the period of high inflation and hyperinflation. In addition, the revaluation was bound on the exchange rate mark and United States dollar to obtain the value of the Goldmark.[28]

Finally, the Law on the Revaluation of Mortgages and other Claims of 16 July 1925 (Gesetz über die Aufwertung von Hypotheken und anderen Ansprüchen or Aufwertungsgesetze) included only the ratio of the paper mark to the gold mark for the period from 1 January 1918, to 30 November 1923, and the following days.[29] The galloping inflation thus caused the end of a principle, "a mark is worth a mark", which had been recognized, the nominal value principle.[30]

The law was challenged in the Supreme Court of the German Reich (Reichsgericht), but its 5th Senate ruled, on 4 November 1925, that the law was constitutional, even according to the Bill of Rights and Duties of Germans (Articles 109, 134, 152 and 153 of the Constitution).[31][32][33] The case set a precedent for judicial review in German jurisprudence.[34]

Causes

[edit]

Historians and economists differ over the causes of the German hyperinflation, particularly on the subject of whether it was caused by reparations payments.

The Treaty of Versailles had imposed an undefined debt on Germany, which the London Schedule of Payments agreed in May 1921 had determined to be essentially 50 billion marks in A and B bonds payable partly in-kind with goods like coal and timber, and partly in gold and hard-cash. From June 1921, when a single payment of 1 billion gold marks was paid (roughly 1.4% of Germany's nominal 1925 GNP)[1], until the agreement of the Dawes plan in late 1924, only relatively small cash payments were made by Germany, though partial in-kind payments continued. For example, of the 300 million gold marks due under a variable annuity in November 1921, only 13 million was paid, and of the roughly 3 billion gold marks total due under payments in 1922, only 435 million were paid in cash.[5]: 238 

Germany's leadership claimed that, with its gold depleted, inflation resulted during 1921–23 due to attempts to buy foreign currency with German currency in an effort to make cash payments as reparations. This would be equivalent to selling German currency in exchange for payment in foreign currency, but the resulting increase in the supply of German marks on the market caused the German mark to fall rapidly in value.[11][5]: 238 

British and French experts claimed that the German leadership were purposefully stoking inflation as a way of avoiding paying reparations, as well as a way of avoiding budgetary reforms – a view later supported by analysis of Reich Chancellery record showing that tax reform and currency stabilisation was delayed in 1922–23 in the hope of reductions in reparations. Particularly, Allied analysis of German statistics showed that printing of paper currency was being used to maintain tax rates much lower than in Allied countries, to fund relatively high levels of state expenditure, and that this effect was being worsened by unrestricted capital flight from Germany. Reparations payments continued more or less in full from 1924 to 1931 without a return of hyperinflation and, after 1930, Germany protested that reparations payments were deflationary.[5]: 239  Inflation also enabled the German government to pay off its substantial domestic debts, particularly war debts, in devalued marks.[5]: 245 

One point on which historians tend to agree is that the printing of cash by the German government to make payments to striking workers in the Ruhr, who were refusing to make reparations deliveries to the Allies, contributed to hyperinflation.[5]: 245 [11] The occupation of the Ruhr also caused German output to fall.[6]

Regardless of the reason for the declining value of the German currency, the decline caused prices of goods to rise rapidly, increasing the cost of operating the German government, which could not be financed by raising taxes because those taxes would be payable in the ever-falling German currency. The resulting deficit was financed by some combination of issuing bonds and simply creating more money: both increasing the supply of German mark-denominated financial assets on the market and so further reducing the currency's price. When the German people realized that their money was rapidly losing value, they tried to spend it quickly. That increased monetary velocity and caused an ever-faster increase in prices, creating a vicious cycle.[35]

The government and the banks had two unacceptable alternatives. If they stopped inflation, there would be immediate bankruptcies, unemployment, strikes, hunger, violence, collapse of civil order, insurrection and possibly even revolution.[36] If they continued the inflation, they would default on their foreign debt. However, attempting to avoid both unemployment and insolvency ultimately failed when Germany had both.[36]

Aftermath and legacy

[edit]
Germany, 1923: banknotes had lost so much value that they were used as wallpaper.

The hyperinflation episode in the Weimar Republic in the early 1920s was not the first or even the most severe instance of inflation in history.[37][38] However, it has been the subject of the most scholarly economic analysis and debate. The hyperinflation drew significant interest, as many of the dramatic and unusual economic behaviors now associated with hyperinflation were first documented systematically: exponential increases in prices and interest rates, redenomination of the currency, consumer flight from cash to hard assets and the rapid expansion of industries that produced those assets.

Since the hyperinflation, German monetary policy has retained a central concern with the maintenance of a sound currency, a concern that had an effect on the European sovereign debt crisis.[39] According to one study, many Germans conflate hyperinflation in the Weimar Republic with the Great Depression, seeing the two separate events as one big economic crisis that encompassed both rapidly rising prices and mass unemployment.[40]

The hyperinflated, worthless marks became widely collected abroad. The Los Angeles Times estimated in 1924 that more of the decommissioned notes were spread about the US than existed in Germany.[41]

Firms responded to the crisis by focusing on those elements of their information systems they identified as essential to continuing operations. In the beginning the focus was on adjusting sales and procurement arrangements, modifications to financial reporting, and the use of more nonmonetary information in internal reporting. With the continuous acceleration of inflation, human resources were redeployed to the most critical corporate functions, in particular those involved in the remuneration of labor. There is evidence that some parts of corporate accounting systems fell into disrepair, but there was also innovation.[42]

See also

[edit]

Citations

[edit]
  1. ^ a b Evans 2003, p. 103.
  2. ^ Officer, Lawrence. "Exchange Rates Between the United States Dollar and Forty-one Currencies". MeasuringWorth. Retrieved 28 January 2015.
  3. ^ T. Balderston, "War finance and inflation in Britain and Germany, 1914–1918", Economic History Review (1989) 42#3 pp. 222–244
  4. ^ a b c Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (1943). Banking and Monetary Statistics 1914–1941. Washington, DC. p. 671.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  5. ^ a b c d e f g h i Marks, Sally (September 1978). "The Myths of Reparations". Central European History. 11 (3): 237–239. doi:10.1017/S0008938900018707. JSTOR 4545835. Retrieved 22 February 2024.
  6. ^ a b Ritschl, Albrecht (June 2012). Reparations, Deficits, and Debt Default: The Great Depression in Germany (Working Papers No. 163/12) (PDF). LSE. p. 5. Retrieved 2 March 2024.
  7. ^ Laursen and Pedersen, p. 134
  8. ^ Marks, The Illusion of Peace, page 53
  9. ^ Kolb, Eberhard (2012). The Weimar Republic. Translated by P.S. Falla (2nd ed.). Routledge. pp. 41–42. ISBN 978-0-415-09077-3.
  10. ^ Fergusson, p. 38.
  11. ^ a b c Fergusson; When Money Dies; p. 40
  12. ^ Balderston, page 21
  13. ^ Evans 2003, p. 104.
  14. ^ a b "Hyperinflation".
  15. ^ Civilisation in the West, Seventh Edition, Kishlansky, Geary, and O'Brien, New York, p. 807.
  16. ^ Coffin; "Western Civilizations"; p. 918
  17. ^ Monetary Explanations of the Weimar Republic's Hyperinflation: Some Neglected Contributions in Contemporary German Literature, David E. W. Laidler & George W. Stadler, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 30, pp. 816, 818
  18. ^ Born, Karl Erich (1969). "Helfferich, Karl". Neue Deutsche Biographie 8 [Online-Version]. pp. 470–472. Retrieved 20 September 2023.
  19. ^ Gustavo H. B. Franco. "The Rentenmark Miracle" (PDF). p. 16. Archived from the original (PDF) on 6 July 2011. Retrieved 12 January 2010.
  20. ^ Born, Karl Erich (1987). "Luther, Hans". Neue Deutsche Biographie 15 [Online-Version]. pp. 544–547. Retrieved 20 September 2023.
  21. ^ Llewellyn, Jennifer; Thompson, Steve (26 September 2019). "The hyperinflation of 1923". Alpha History. Retrieved 23 September 2023.
  22. ^ Guttmann, William. (1975). The Great Inflation. Hants, UK: Saxon House. pp. 208–211. ISBN 978-0347000178.
  23. ^ a b Fergusson, Chapter 13
  24. ^ Pfleiderer, Otto (September 1979). "Two Types of Inflation, Two Types of Currency Reform: The German Currency Miracles of 1923 and 1948". Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft / Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics. 135 (3). Mohr Siebeck GmbH & Co.: 356. JSTOR 40750148.
  25. ^ Southern, David B. (March 1979). "The Revaluation Question in the Weimar Republic". The Journal of Modern History. 51 (1): D1031. doi:10.1086/242035. JSTOR 1878444. S2CID 144523809.
  26. ^ Swastika, Putri; Mirakhor, Abbas (2021). Applying Risk-Sharing Finance for Economic Development. Lessons from Germany. Berlin: Springer International. p. 99, footnote 31. ISBN 978-3030826420.
  27. ^ Fergusson, Chapter 14
  28. ^ Fischer 2010, p. 83.
  29. ^ Fischer 2010, p. 84.
  30. ^ Fischer 2010, p. 87.
  31. ^ Friedrich 1928, p. 197.
  32. ^ RGZ III, 325
  33. ^ Fischer 2010, p. 89.
  34. ^ Friedrich 1928, pp. 196–197.
  35. ^ Parsson; Dying of Money; pp. 116–117
  36. ^ a b Fergusson; When Money Dies; p. 254
  37. ^ "World Hyperinflations | Steve H. Hanke and Nicholas Krus | Cato Institute: Working Paper". Cato.org. 15 August 2012. Archived from the original on 17 October 2012. Retrieved 15 October 2012.
  38. ^ "World Hyperinflations" (PDF). CNBC. 14 February 2011. Archived (PDF) from the original on 5 September 2013. Retrieved 13 July 2012.
  39. ^ Greece bailout: What's the future of the euro?, Ben Quinn, Christian Science Monitor, 28 March 2010
  40. ^ Haffert, Lukas; Redeker, Nils; Rommel, Tobias (2021). "Misremembering Weimar: Hyperinflation, the Great Depression, and German collective economic memory". Economics & Politics. 33 (3): 664–686. doi:10.1111/ecpo.12182. ISSN 1468-0343. S2CID 233631576.
  41. ^ Americans With Marks Out of Luck, Cable and Associated Press, Los Angeles Times, 15 Nov 1924
  42. ^ Hoffmann, Sebastian; Walker, Stephen P. (2020). "Adapting to Crisis: Accounting Information Systems during the Weimar Hyperinflation". Business History Review. 94 (3): 593–625. doi:10.1017/S0007680520000550. hdl:20.500.11820/e7755750-6903-4ab9-aab2-da795ed70c25. ISSN 0007-6805. S2CID 225645243.

General and cited sources

[edit]
[edit]