Copenhagen Consensus: Difference between revisions
→History: 3 wikilinks |
Reverting edit(s) by 80.71.142.166 (talk) to rev. 1228991652 by Kku: Vandalism (RW 16.1) |
||
(23 intermediate revisions by 17 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{ |
{{Short description|Welfare economics project}} |
||
{{Primary sources|date=January 2021}} |
|||
⚫ | '''Copenhagen Consensus''' is a project that seeks to establish priorities for advancing global welfare using methodologies based on the theory of [[welfare economics]], using cost–benefit analysis. It was conceived |
||
{{Use dmy dates|date=August 2023}} |
|||
{{about|a project by economists|the UN climate change document|Copenhagen Accord|the scientific consensus on climate change|scientific consensus on climate change}} |
|||
⚫ | '''Copenhagen Consensus''' is a project that seeks to establish priorities for advancing global welfare using methodologies based on the theory of [[welfare economics]], using [[cost–benefit analysis]]. It was conceived and organized around 2004 by [[Bjørn Lomborg]],<ref>{{Cite web|title=Our story {{!}} Copenhagen Consensus Center|url=https://www.copenhagenconsensus.com/our-story|access-date=2021-01-02|website=www.copenhagenconsensus.com}}</ref> the author of ''[[The Skeptical Environmentalist]]'' and the then director of the Danish government's [[Environmental Assessment Institute]]. |
||
The project is run by the [[Copenhagen Consensus Center]],<ref>http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com Copenhagen Consensus Center – CCC Home Page</ref> which is directed by Lomborg and was part of the [[Copenhagen Business School]], but it is now an independent [[501(c) organization|501(c)(3) non-profit organisation]] registered in the USA. The project considers possible solutions to a wide range of problems, presented by experts in each field. These are evaluated and ranked by a panel of economists. The emphasis is on rational prioritization by economic analysis. The panel is given an arbitrary budget constraint and instructed to use cost–benefit analysis to focus on a bottom line approach in solving/ranking presented problems. The approach is justified as a corrective to standard practice in [[international development]], where, it is alleged, media attention and the "court of public opinion" results in priorities that are often far from optimal. |
The project is run by the [[Copenhagen Consensus Center]],<ref>http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com Copenhagen Consensus Center – CCC Home Page</ref> which is directed by Lomborg and was part of the [[Copenhagen Business School]], but it is now an independent [[501(c) organization|501(c)(3) non-profit organisation]] registered in the USA. The project considers possible solutions to a wide range of problems, presented by experts in each field. These are evaluated and ranked by a panel of economists. The emphasis is on rational prioritization by economic analysis. The panel is given an arbitrary budget constraint and instructed to use cost–benefit analysis to focus on a bottom line approach in solving/ranking presented problems. The approach is justified as a corrective to standard practice in [[international development]], where, it is alleged, media attention and the "court of public opinion" results in priorities that are often far from optimal. |
||
==History== |
==History== |
||
The project has held conferences in 2004, 2007, 2008, 2009, 2011 and 2012. The 2012 conference ranked bundled [[micronutrient]] interventions the highest priority,<ref name="CC12 Outcome">{{ |
The project has held conferences in 2004, 2007, 2008, 2009, 2011 and 2012. The 2012 conference ranked bundled [[micronutrient]] interventions the highest priority,<ref name="CC12 Outcome">{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/outcome|title=Outcome|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> and the 2008 report identified [[supplementing vitamins]] for undernourished children as the world’s best investment.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-ii|title=Copenhagen Consensus II|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> The 2009 conference, dealing specifically with [[global warming]], proposed research into [[cloud reflectivity modification|marine cloud whitening]] (ships spraying seawater into clouds to make them reflect more sunlight and thereby reduce temperature) as the top climate change priority, though climate change itself is ranked well below other world problems. In 2011 the Copenhagen Consensus Center carried out the Rethink HIV project together with the RUSH Foundation, to find smart solutions to the problem of [[HIV/AIDS]]. In 2007 looked into which projects would contribute most to welfare in Copenhagen Consensus for Latin America in cooperation with the [[Inter-American Development Bank]]. |
||
The initial project was co-sponsored by the Danish government and ''[[The Economist]]''. A book summarizing the Copenhagen Consensus 2004 conclusions, ''[[Global Crises, Global Solutions]]'', edited by Lomborg, was published in October 2004 by [[Cambridge University Press]], followed by the second edition published in 2009 based on the 2008 conclusions |
The initial project was co-sponsored by the Danish government and ''[[The Economist]]''. A book summarizing the Copenhagen Consensus 2004 conclusions, ''[[Global Crises, Global Solutions]]'', edited by Lomborg, was published in October 2004 by [[Cambridge University Press]], followed by the second edition published in 2009 based on the 2008 conclusions. |
||
==Copenhagen Consensus 2012== |
==Copenhagen Consensus 2012== |
||
Line 23: | Line 26: | ||
=== Challenges === |
=== Challenges === |
||
* [[Armed conflict]]<ref>{{ |
* [[Armed conflict]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/armed-conflict-0|title=Armed Conflict|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Biodiversity]]<ref>{{ |
* [[Biodiversity]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/biodiversity-0|title=Biodiversity|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Chronic |
* [[Chronic disease]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/chronic-disease-0|title=Chronic Disease|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Climate Change]]<ref>{{ |
* [[Climate change (general concept)|Climate Change]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/climate-change|title=Climate Change|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Education]]<ref>{{ |
* [[Education]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/education|title=Education|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Hunger]] and [[ |
* [[Hunger]] and [[malnutrition]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/hunger-and-malnutrition-0|title=Hunger and Malnutrition|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Infectious |
* [[Infectious disease]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/infectious-disease-0|title=Infectious Disease|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Natural |
* [[Natural disasters]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/natural-disasters-0|title=Natural Disasters|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Population |
* [[Population growth]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/population-growth-0|title=Population Growth|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
* [[Water]] and [[ |
* [[Water]] and [[sanitation]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/water-and-sanitation-0|title=Water and Sanitation|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
In addition, the Center commissioned research on [[Corruption]]<ref>{{ |
In addition, the Center commissioned research on [[Corruption]]<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/corruption-0|title=Corruption|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> and [[trade barrier]]s,<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-iii/trade-barriers-0|title=Trade Barriers|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> but the Expert Panel did not rank these for Copenhagen Consensus 2012, because the solutions to these challenges are political rather than investment-related. |
||
=== Outcome === |
=== Outcome === |
||
Line 39: | Line 42: | ||
# Bundled [[micronutrient]] interventions to fight hunger and improve education |
# Bundled [[micronutrient]] interventions to fight hunger and improve education |
||
# Expanding the |
# Expanding the subsidy for [[malaria]] combination treatment |
||
# Expanded |
# Expanded childhood immunization coverage |
||
# [[Deworming]] of |
# [[Deworming]] of schoolchildren, to improve educational and health outcomes |
||
# Expanding [[ |
# Expanding [[tuberculosis]] treatment |
||
# R&D to Increase |
# R&D to Increase yield enhancements, to decrease hunger, fight [[biodiversity]] destruction, and lessen the effects of [[climate change]] |
||
# Investing in |
# Investing in effective early warning systems to protect populations against natural disaster |
||
# Strengthening |
# Strengthening surgical capacity |
||
# [[Hepatitis B]] |
# [[Hepatitis B]] immunization |
||
# Using |
# Using low‐Cost drugs in the case of acute [[Myocardial infarction|heart attacks]] in poorer nations (these are already available in developed countries) |
||
# Salt |
# Salt reduction campaign to reduce chronic disease |
||
# [[Climate engineering| |
# [[Climate engineering|Geo‐engineering]] R&D into the feasibility of solar radiation management |
||
# [[Conditional |
# [[Conditional cash transfer]] for school attendance |
||
# Accelerated [[HIV]] |
# Accelerated [[HIV]] vaccine R&D |
||
# Extended |
# Extended field trial of information campaigns on the benefits from schooling |
||
# [[Borehole]] and |
# [[Borehole]] and public hand pump intervention |
||
=== Slate ranking === |
=== Slate ranking === |
||
During the days of the Copenhagen Consensus 2012 conference, a series of articles was published in [[Slate (magazine)|Slate]] Magazine<ref>{{ |
During the days of the Copenhagen Consensus 2012 conference, a series of articles was published in [[Slate (magazine)|Slate]] Magazine<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.slate.com/articles/technology/copenhagen_consensus_2012.html|title=Copenhagen Consensus 2012|website=Slate Magazine|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> each about a challenge that was discussed, and Slate readers could make their own ranking, voting for the solutions which they thought were best. Slate readers' ranking corresponded with that of the Expert Panel on many points, including the desirability of bundled micronutrient intervention; however, the most striking difference was in connection with the problem of [[Human overpopulation|overpopulation]]. [[Family planning]] ranked highest on the Slate priority list, whereas it didn't feature in the top 16 of the Expert Panel's prioritisation.<ref>{{cite journal|title=Slate priority list|journal=Slate|date=14 May 2012|url=http://www.slate.com/articles/technology/copenhagen_consensus_2012/2012/05/nobel_laureates_decide_that_better_nutrition_is_the_best_way_to_help_the_poor_.html|last1=Lomborg|first1=Bjørn}}</ref> |
||
== Copenhagen Consensus 2008 == |
== Copenhagen Consensus 2008 == |
||
Line 72: | Line 75: | ||
===Results=== |
===Results=== |
||
In the Copenhagen Consensus 2008, the solutions for global problems have been ranked in the following order:<ref> |
In the Copenhagen Consensus 2008, the solutions for global problems have been ranked in the following order:<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-ii/outcomes|title=Outcomes|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
# [[Micronutrient]] supplements for children (vitamin A and zinc) |
# [[Micronutrient]] supplements for children (vitamin A and zinc) |
||
Line 107: | Line 110: | ||
Unlike the 2004 results, these were not grouped into qualitative bands such as Good, Poor, etc. |
Unlike the 2004 results, these were not grouped into qualitative bands such as Good, Poor, etc. |
||
[[Gary Yohe]], one of the authors of the global warming paper, subsequently accused Lomborg of "deliberate distortion of our conclusions",<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2008/aug/22/climatechange.carbonemissions | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=Climate change is real, compelling and urgent | first=Gary | last=Yohe | date=2008-08-22 | accessdate=2010-04-30}}</ref> adding that "as one of the authors of the Copenhagen Consensus Project's principal climate paper, I can say with certainty that Lomborg is misrepresenting our findings thanks to a highly selective memory". Kåre Fog further pointed out that the future benefits of emissions reduction were [[Discounted Cash Flow|discounted]] at a higher rate than for any of the other 27 proposals,<ref>http://www.lomborg-errors.dk/CopCons2008.htm</ref> stating "so there is an obvious reason why the climate issue always is ranked last" in Lomborg's environmental studies. |
[[Gary Yohe]], one of the authors of the global warming paper, subsequently accused Lomborg of "deliberate distortion of our conclusions",<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2008/aug/22/climatechange.carbonemissions | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=Climate change is real, compelling and urgent | first=Gary | last=Yohe | date=2008-08-22 | accessdate=2010-04-30}}</ref> adding that "as one of the authors of the Copenhagen Consensus Project's principal climate paper, I can say with certainty that Lomborg is misrepresenting our findings thanks to a highly selective memory". Kåre Fog further pointed out that the future benefits of emissions reduction were [[Discounted Cash Flow|discounted]] at a higher rate than for any of the other 27 proposals,<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.lomborg-errors.dk/CopCons2008.htm|title = Index}}</ref> stating "so there is an obvious reason why the climate issue always is ranked last" in Lomborg's environmental studies. |
||
In a subsequent joint statement settling their differences, Lomborg and Yohe agreed that the "failure" of Lomborg's emissions reduction plan "could be traced to faulty design".<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2008/sep/01/climatechange.scienceofclimatechange1 | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=It's not about us | first=Björn | last=Lomborg | date=2008-09-01 | accessdate=2010-04-30}}</ref> |
In a subsequent joint statement settling their differences, Lomborg and Yohe agreed that the "failure" of Lomborg's emissions reduction plan "could be traced to faulty design".<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/commentisfree/2008/sep/01/climatechange.scienceofclimatechange1 | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=It's not about us | first=Björn | last=Lomborg | date=2008-09-01 | accessdate=2010-04-30}}</ref> |
||
==Climate Change Project== |
==Climate Change Project== |
||
In 2009, the Copenhagen |
In 2009, the Copenhagen convened an expert panel specifically to examine solutions to climate change.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Copenhagen Consensus on Climate {{!}} Copenhagen Consensus Center|url=http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus-climate|access-date=2021-01-02|website=www.copenhagenconsensus.com}}</ref> The process was similar to the 2004 and 2008 Copenhagen Consensus, involving papers by specialists considered by a panel of economists. The panel ranked 15 solutions, of which the top 5 were: |
||
# Research into marine cloud whitening (involving ships spraying sea-water into clouds so as to reflect more sunlight and thereby reduce temperatures) |
# Research into marine cloud whitening (involving ships spraying sea-water into clouds so as to reflect more sunlight and thereby reduce temperatures) |
||
# Technology-led policy response |
# Technology-led policy response |
||
# Research into stratospheric aerosol injection (involving injected ?sulphur dioxide into the upper atmosphere to reduce sunlight) |
# Research into [[stratospheric aerosol injection]] (involving injected ?sulphur dioxide into the upper atmosphere to reduce sunlight) |
||
# Research into carbon storage |
# Research into carbon storage |
||
# Planning for adaptation |
# Planning for [[climate change adaptation|adaptation]] |
||
The benefits of the number 1 solution are that if the research proved successful this solution could be deployed relatively cheaply and quickly. Potential problems include environmental impacts e.g. from changing rainfall patterns. |
The benefits of the number 1 solution are that if the research proved successful this solution could be deployed relatively cheaply and quickly. Potential problems include environmental impacts e.g. from changing rainfall patterns. |
||
Line 129: | Line 132: | ||
=== Economists === |
=== Economists === |
||
''[[Bank of Sweden Prize in Economic Sciences in Memory of Alfred Nobel|Nobel Prize]] winners marked with (''¤'')'' |
|||
* [[Jagdish Bhagwati]] |
* [[Jagdish Bhagwati]] |
||
* [[Robert Fogel]] |
* [[Robert Fogel]] |
||
* [[Bruno Frey]] |
* [[Bruno Frey]] |
||
* [[Justin Yifu Lin]] |
* [[Justin Yifu Lin]] |
||
* [[Douglass North]] |
* [[Douglass North]] |
||
* [[Thomas Schelling]] |
* [[Thomas Schelling]] |
||
* [[Vernon L. Smith]] |
* [[Vernon L. Smith]] |
||
* [[Nancy Stokey]] |
* [[Nancy Stokey]] |
||
Line 147: | Line 149: | ||
* [[Education]] ([[Lant Pritchett]]) |
* [[Education]] ([[Lant Pritchett]]) |
||
* [[Currency crisis|Financial instability]] ([[Barry Eichengreen]]) |
* [[Currency crisis|Financial instability]] ([[Barry Eichengreen]]) |
||
* [[Global Warming]] sometimes also called Climate change ([[William R. Cline]]) |
* [[Global warming|Global Warming]] sometimes also called Climate change ([[William R. Cline]]) |
||
* [[Government]] and [[Political corruption|corruption]] ([[Susan Rose-Ackerman]]) |
* [[Government]] and [[Political corruption|corruption]] ([[Susan Rose-Ackerman]]) |
||
* [[Malnutrition]] and [[hunger]] ([[Jere Behrman]]) |
* [[Malnutrition]] and [[hunger]] ([[Jere Behrman]]) |
||
Line 165: | Line 167: | ||
Third on the list was [[free trade|trade liberalization]]; the experts agreed that modest costs could yield large benefits for the world as a whole and for [[developing nation]]s. |
Third on the list was [[free trade|trade liberalization]]; the experts agreed that modest costs could yield large benefits for the world as a whole and for [[developing nation]]s. |
||
The fourth priority identified was controlling and treating [[malaria]]; $13 billion costs were judged to produce very good benefits, particularly if applied toward chemically-treated [[mosquito]] netting for beds.<ref> |
The fourth priority identified was controlling and treating [[malaria]]; $13 billion costs were judged to produce very good benefits, particularly if applied toward chemically-treated [[mosquito]] netting for beds.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.iht.com/articles/110312.html|title=Search – International Herald Tribune<!-- Bot generated title -->|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
====Good==== |
====Good==== |
||
Line 174: | Line 176: | ||
====Poor==== |
====Poor==== |
||
Ranked fourteenth to seventeenth were: a migration project (guest-worker programmes for the unskilled), which was deemed to discourage integration; and three projects addressing climate change ([[optimal carbon tax]], the [[Kyoto Protocol]] and [[value-at-risk carbon tax]]), which the panel judged to be least cost-efficient of the proposals. |
Ranked fourteenth to seventeenth were: a migration project (guest-worker programmes for the unskilled), which was deemed to discourage integration; and three projects [[Climate change mitigation|addressing climate change]] ([[optimal carbon tax]], the [[Kyoto Protocol]] and [[value-at-risk carbon tax]]), which the panel judged to be least cost-efficient of the proposals. |
||
=== Global warming === |
=== Global warming === |
||
The panel found that all three climate policies presented have "costs that were likely to exceed the benefits". It further stated "global warming must be addressed, but agreed that approaches based on too abrupt a shift toward lower emissions of carbon are needlessly expensive." |
The panel found that all three climate policies presented have "costs that were likely to exceed the benefits". It further stated "global warming must be addressed, but agreed that approaches based on too abrupt a shift toward lower emissions of carbon are needlessly expensive."<ref>{{cite web|url=http://copenhagenconsensus.com/sites/default/files/CC04-final_result.pdf|title=HIV/AIDS, Hunger, Free Trade and Malaria Top Experts’ List|website=copenhagenconsensus.com|access-date=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
In regard to the science of global warming, the paper presented by Cline relied primarily on the framework set by [[Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change]], and accepted the consensus view on global warming that greenhouse gas emissions from human activities are the primary cause of the global warming. Cline relies on various research studies published in the field of economics and attempted to compare the estimated cost of mitigation policies against the expected reduction in the damage of the global warming. |
In regard to the science of global warming, the paper presented by Cline relied primarily on the framework set by [[Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change]], and accepted the consensus view on global warming that greenhouse gas emissions from human activities are the primary cause of the global warming. Cline relies on various research studies published in the field of economics and attempted to compare the estimated cost of mitigation policies against the expected reduction in the damage of the global warming. |
||
Cline used a discount rate of 1.5%. (Cline's summary is on the project webpage <ref name="autogenerated3"> |
Cline used a discount rate of 1.5%. (Cline's summary is on the project webpage <ref name="autogenerated3">{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/research-topic/climate-change-energy|title=Climate Change & Energy|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref>) He justified his choice of discount rate on the ground of "utility-based discounting", that is there is zero bias in terms of preference between the present and the [[future generation]] (see [[time preference]]). Moreover, Cline extended the time frame of the analysis to three hundred years in the future. Because the expected net damage of the global warming becomes more apparent beyond the present generation(s), this choice had the effect of increasing the present-value cost of the damage of global warming as well as the benefit of abatement policies. |
||
== Criticism == |
== Criticism == |
||
Members of the panel including Thomas Schelling and one of the two perspective paper writers [[Robert O. Mendelsohn]] (both opponents of the Kyoto protocol) criticised Cline, mainly on the issue of discount rates. (See "The opponent notes to the paper on Climate Change" <ref name=autogenerated3 />) Mendelsohn, in particular, characterizing Cline's position, said that "[i]f we use a large discount rate, they will be judged to be small effects" and called it "circular reasoning, not a justification". Cline responded to this by arguing that there is no obvious reason to use a large discount rate just because this is what is usually done in economic analysis. In other words, climate change ought to be treated differently from other, more imminent problems. The Economist quoted Mendelsohn as worrying that "climate change was [[setting up to fail|set up to fail]]".<ref>{{cite news| url= |
Members of the panel including Thomas Schelling and one of the two perspective paper writers [[Robert O. Mendelsohn]] (both opponents of the Kyoto protocol) criticised Cline, mainly on the issue of discount rates. (See "The opponent notes to the paper on Climate Change" <ref name=autogenerated3 />) Mendelsohn, in particular, characterizing Cline's position, said that "[i]f we use a large discount rate, they will be judged to be small effects" and called it "circular reasoning, not a justification". Cline responded to this by arguing that there is no obvious reason to use a large discount rate just because this is what is usually done in economic analysis. In other words, climate change ought to be treated differently from other, more imminent problems. The Economist quoted Mendelsohn as worrying that "climate change was [[setting up to fail|set up to fail]]".<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.economist.com/agenda/displayStory.cfm?story_id=3630425 | newspaper=The Economist | title=Hotting up | date=2005-02-04}}</ref> |
||
Moreover, Mendelsohn argued that Cline's damage estimates were excessive. Citing various recent articles, including some of his own, he stated that "[a] series of studies on the impacts of climate change have systematically shown that the older literature overestimated climate damages by failing to allow for adaptation and for climate benefits." |
Moreover, Mendelsohn argued that Cline's damage estimates were excessive. Citing various recent articles, including some of his own, he stated that "[a] series of studies on the impacts of climate change have systematically shown that the older literature overestimated climate damages by failing to allow for adaptation and for climate benefits." |
||
Members of the panel, including Schelling, criticised the way this issue was handled in the Consensus project.{{Citation needed|date=January 2009}} |
|||
The 2004 Copenhagen Consensus attracted various criticisms: |
The 2004 Copenhagen Consensus attracted various criticisms: |
||
Line 196: | Line 196: | ||
===Approach and alleged bias=== |
===Approach and alleged bias=== |
||
The 2004 report, especially its conclusion regarding climate change was subsequently criticised from a variety of perspectives. The general approach adopted to set priorities was criticised by [[Jeffrey Sachs]], an American economist and advocate of both the Kyoto protocol <ref> |
The 2004 report, especially its conclusion regarding climate change, was subsequently criticised from a variety of perspectives. The general approach adopted to set priorities was criticised by [[Jeffrey Sachs]], an American economist and advocate of both the Kyoto protocol <ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/changing-climate-change|title=Changing Climate Change | by Jeffrey D. Sachs|first=Jeffrey D.|last=Sachs|date=21 November 2005|website=Project Syndicate|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> and increased development aid, who argued that the analytical framework was inappropriate and biased and that the project "failed to mobilize an expert group that could credibly identify and communicate a true consensus of expert knowledge on the range of issues under consideration.".<ref name="autogenerated1">{{Cite journal|url=https://www.nature.com/articles/430725a|title=Seeking a global solution|first=Jeffrey D.|last=Sachs|date=21 August 2004|journal=Nature|volume=430|issue=7001|pages=725–726|accessdate=21 August 2023|via=www.nature.com|doi=10.1038/430725a}}</ref> |
||
Tom Burke, a former director of Friends of the Earth, repudiated the entire approach of the project, arguing that applying cost–benefit analysis in the way the Copenhagen panel did was "junk economics".<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/comment/story/0,3604,1334209,00.html | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense | date=2004-10-23 | accessdate=2010-04-30 | first=Tom | last=Burke}}</ref> |
Tom Burke, a former director of [[Friends of the Earth]], repudiated the entire approach of the project, arguing that applying cost–benefit analysis in the way the Copenhagen panel did was "junk economics".<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.theguardian.com/comment/story/0,3604,1334209,00.html | work=The Guardian | location=London | title=This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense | date=2004-10-23 | accessdate=2010-04-30 | first=Tom | last=Burke}}</ref> |
||
[[John Quiggin]], an Australian economics professor, commented that the project is a mix of "a substantial contribution to our understanding of important issues facing the world" and an "exercises in political propaganda" and argued that the selection of the panel members was slanted towards the conclusions previously supported by Lomborg.<ref name="autogenerated4"> |
[[John Quiggin]], an Australian economics professor, commented that the project is a mix of "a substantial contribution to our understanding of important issues facing the world" and an "exercises in political propaganda" and argued that the selection of the panel members was slanted towards the conclusions previously supported by Lomborg.<ref name="autogenerated4">{{Cite web|url=https://johnquiggin.com/2005/01/21/copenhagen-review/|title=Copenhagen review|first=John|last=Quiggin|date=20 January 2005|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> Quiggin observed that Lomborg had argued in his controversial book ''[[The Skeptical Environmentalist]]'' that resources allocated to mitigating global warming would be better spent on improving water quality and sanitation, and was therefore seen as having prejudged the issues. |
||
Under the heading "Wrong Question", Sachs further argued that: "The panel that drew up the Copenhagen Consensus was asked to allocate an additional US$50 billion in spending by wealthy countries, distributed over five years, to address the world’s biggest problems. This was a poor basis for decision-making and for informing the public. By choosing such a low sum — a tiny fraction of global income — the project inherently favoured specific low-cost schemes over bolder, larger projects. It is therefore no surprise that the huge and complex challenge of long-term climate change was ranked last, and that scaling up health services in poor countries was ranked lower than interventions against specific diseases, despite warnings in the background papers that such interventions require broader improvements in health services." |
Under the heading "Wrong Question", Sachs further argued that: "The panel that drew up the Copenhagen Consensus was asked to allocate an additional US$50 billion in spending by wealthy countries, distributed over five years, to address the world’s biggest problems. This was a poor basis for decision-making and for informing the public. By choosing such a low sum — a tiny fraction of global income — the project inherently favoured specific low-cost schemes over bolder, larger projects. It is therefore no surprise that the huge and complex challenge of long-term climate change was ranked last, and that scaling up health services in poor countries was ranked lower than interventions against specific diseases, despite warnings in the background papers that such interventions require broader improvements in health services." |
||
In response Lomborg argued that $50 billion was "an optimistic but realistic example of actual spending." "Experience shows that pledges and actual spending are two different things. In 1970 the UN set itself the task of doubling development assistance. Since then the percentage has actually |
In response Lomborg argued that $50 billion was "an optimistic but realistic example of actual spending." "Experience shows that pledges and actual spending are two different things. In 1970 the UN set itself the task of doubling development assistance. Since then the percentage has actually been dropping". "But even if Sachs or others could gather much more than $50 billion over the next 4 years, the Copenhagen Consensus priority list would still show us where it should be invested first." <ref name="autogenerated2">{{Cite web|url=https://copenhagenconsensus.com/copenhagen-consensus/outcome|title=Outcome|website=Copenhagen Consensus|accessdate=21 August 2023}}</ref> |
||
been dropping". "But even if Sachs or others could gather much more than $50 billion over the next 4 years, the Copenhagen Consensus priority list would still show us where it should be invested first." <ref name="autogenerated2">[http://copenhagenconsensus.com/projects/copenhagen-consensus-2004/outcome Copenhagen Consensus 2004 – addresses 10 major challenges in the world. – Press releases<!-- Bot generated title -->]</ref> |
|||
[[Thomas Schelling]], one of the Copenhagen Consensus panel experts, later distanced himself from the way in which the Consensus results have been interpreted in the wider debate, arguing that it was misleading to put climate change at the bottom of the priority list. The Consensus panel members were presented with a dramatic proposal for handling climate change. If given the opportunity, Schelling would have put a more modest proposal higher on the list. The Yale economist [[Robert O. Mendelsohn]] was the official critic of the proposal for climate change during the Consensus. He thought the proposal was way out of the mainstream and could only be rejected. Mendelsohn worries that climate change was set up to fail.<ref>{{cite news| url=https://www.economist.com/science/displaystory.cfm?story_id=E1_PGNPNNV | newspaper=The Economist | title=Hotting up | date=2005-02-03}}</ref> |
|||
<ref>{{cite news| url=http://www.economist.com/science/displaystory.cfm?story_id=E1_PGNPNNV | work=The Economist | title=Hotting up | date=2005-02-03}}</ref> |
|||
Michael Grubb, an economist and lead author for several [[Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change|IPCC]] reports, commented on the Copenhagen Consensus, writing:<ref name="grubbm">{{cite web |
Michael Grubb, an economist and lead author for several [[Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change|IPCC]] reports, commented on the Copenhagen Consensus, writing:<ref name="grubbm">{{cite web |
||
Line 221: | Line 219: | ||
===Panel membership=== |
===Panel membership=== |
||
Quiggin argued that the members of the 2004 panel, selected by Lomborg, were "generally towards the right and, to the extent that they had stated views, to be opponents of Kyoto."<ref name=autogenerated4 /> Sachs also noted that the panel members had not previously been much involved in issues of development economics and were unlikely to reach useful conclusions in the time available to them.<ref name=autogenerated1 /> Commenting on the 2004 Copenhagen Consensus, [[climatologist]] and IPCC author [[Stephen Schneider]] criticised Lomborg for only inviting economists to participate:<ref name="schneiders">{{cite web |
Quiggin argued that the members of the 2004 panel, selected by Lomborg, were "generally towards the right and, to the extent that they had stated views, to be opponents of Kyoto."<ref name=autogenerated4 /> Sachs also noted that the panel members had not previously been much involved in issues of [[development economics]] and were unlikely to reach useful conclusions in the time available to them.<ref name=autogenerated1 /> Commenting on the 2004 Copenhagen Consensus, [[climatologist]] and IPCC author [[Stephen Schneider (scientist)|Stephen Schneider]] criticised Lomborg for only inviting economists to participate:<ref name="schneiders">{{cite web |
||
|date=n.d. |
|date=n.d. |
||
|title=Climate Science: Contrarians. |
|title=Climate Science: Contrarians. |
||
Line 234: | Line 232: | ||
<blockquote>In order to achieve a true consensus, I think Lomborg would've had to invite ecologists, social scientists concerned with justice and how climate change impacts and policies are often inequitably distributed, philosophers who could challenge the economic paradigm of "one dollar, one vote" implicit in cost–benefit analyses promoted by economists, and [[climate scientist]]s who could easily show that Lomborg's claim that climate change will have only minimal effects is not sound science.</blockquote> |
<blockquote>In order to achieve a true consensus, I think Lomborg would've had to invite ecologists, social scientists concerned with justice and how climate change impacts and policies are often inequitably distributed, philosophers who could challenge the economic paradigm of "one dollar, one vote" implicit in cost–benefit analyses promoted by economists, and [[climate scientist]]s who could easily show that Lomborg's claim that climate change will have only minimal effects is not sound science.</blockquote> |
||
Lomborg countered criticism of the panel membership by stating that "Sachs disparaged the Consensus 'dream team' because it only consisted of economists. But that was the very point of the project. Economists have expertise in economic prioritization. It is they and not climatologists or malaria experts who can prioritize between battling global warming or communicable disease |
Lomborg countered criticism of the panel membership by stating that "Sachs disparaged the Consensus 'dream team' because it only consisted of economists. But that was the very point of the project. Economists have expertise in economic prioritization. It is they and not climatologists or malaria experts who can prioritize between battling global warming or communicable disease".<ref name=autogenerated2 /> |
||
== See also == |
== See also == |
||
Line 255: | Line 253: | ||
* Sachs, Jeffrey D. (12 August 2004). [https://web.archive.org/web/20081117201736/http://www.earthinstitute.columbia.edu/sitefiles/File/about/director/documents/nature081204.pdf Seeking a global solution. ''Nature'' 430:725–726] |
* Sachs, Jeffrey D. (12 August 2004). [https://web.archive.org/web/20081117201736/http://www.earthinstitute.columbia.edu/sitefiles/File/about/director/documents/nature081204.pdf Seeking a global solution. ''Nature'' 430:725–726] |
||
* Lind, Robert C. (1982) (ed.): Discounting for time and risk in energy policy. 468 pp. Published by Resources for the Future. inc., Washington D.C. |
* Lind, Robert C. (1982) (ed.): Discounting for time and risk in energy policy. 468 pp. Published by Resources for the Future. inc., Washington D.C. |
||
* Lomborg, Bjorn (2013). '' |
* Lomborg, Bjorn (2013). ''How to Spend $75 Billion to Make the World a Better Place. ''Published by the Copenhagen Consensus Center. {{ISBN|978-1-940-00300-9}} |
||
== External links == |
== External links == |
||
* [http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com/ The Copenhagen Consensus website] |
* [http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com/ The Copenhagen Consensus website] |
||
* [ |
* [https://www.economist.com/finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=2592716 The Copenhagen Consensus] ''The Economist'''s home page for the project] |
||
* [http://www.economist.com/finance/displaystory.cfm?story_id=2592716 ''The Economist'''s home page for the project] |
|||
* [http://www.sourcewatch.org/index.php?title=Copenhagen_Consensus SourceWatch entry on Copenhagen Consensus] |
* [http://www.sourcewatch.org/index.php?title=Copenhagen_Consensus SourceWatch entry on Copenhagen Consensus] |
||
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20060927143829/http://www.cceia.org/resources/transcripts/5090.html Global Crises, Global Solutions] Transcript of Lomborg's talk at the Carnegie Council. |
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20060927143829/http://www.cceia.org/resources/transcripts/5090.html Global Crises, Global Solutions] Transcript of Lomborg's talk at the Carnegie Council. |
||
Line 266: | Line 263: | ||
* Criticism: [https://www.theguardian.com/comment/story/0,3604,1334209,00.html Tom Burke: This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense: Why is Bjorn Lomborg's work on climate change taken seriously?] ''The Guardian'', 23 October 2004: ("Cost-benefit analysis can help you choose different routes to a goal you have agreed, but it cannot help you choose goals. For that we have politics.") |
* Criticism: [https://www.theguardian.com/comment/story/0,3604,1334209,00.html Tom Burke: This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense: Why is Bjorn Lomborg's work on climate change taken seriously?] ''The Guardian'', 23 October 2004: ("Cost-benefit analysis can help you choose different routes to a goal you have agreed, but it cannot help you choose goals. For that we have politics.") |
||
* [http://www.lomborg-errors.dk/CopCons.htm What is wrong about Copenhagen Consensus?] on the Lomborg-errors web site. |
* [http://www.lomborg-errors.dk/CopCons.htm What is wrong about Copenhagen Consensus?] on the Lomborg-errors web site. |
||
{{Bjørn Lomborg}} |
|||
[[Category:Welfare economics]] |
[[Category:Welfare economics]] |
||
[[Category:The Economist]] |
[[Category:The Economist]] |
||
[[Category:Climate change organizations based in the United States]] |
|||
[[Category:Think tanks based in the United States]] |
Latest revision as of 11:33, 9 December 2024
Copenhagen Consensus is a project that seeks to establish priorities for advancing global welfare using methodologies based on the theory of welfare economics, using cost–benefit analysis. It was conceived and organized around 2004 by Bjørn Lomborg,[1] the author of The Skeptical Environmentalist and the then director of the Danish government's Environmental Assessment Institute.
The project is run by the Copenhagen Consensus Center,[2] which is directed by Lomborg and was part of the Copenhagen Business School, but it is now an independent 501(c)(3) non-profit organisation registered in the USA. The project considers possible solutions to a wide range of problems, presented by experts in each field. These are evaluated and ranked by a panel of economists. The emphasis is on rational prioritization by economic analysis. The panel is given an arbitrary budget constraint and instructed to use cost–benefit analysis to focus on a bottom line approach in solving/ranking presented problems. The approach is justified as a corrective to standard practice in international development, where, it is alleged, media attention and the "court of public opinion" results in priorities that are often far from optimal.
History
[edit]The project has held conferences in 2004, 2007, 2008, 2009, 2011 and 2012. The 2012 conference ranked bundled micronutrient interventions the highest priority,[3] and the 2008 report identified supplementing vitamins for undernourished children as the world’s best investment.[4] The 2009 conference, dealing specifically with global warming, proposed research into marine cloud whitening (ships spraying seawater into clouds to make them reflect more sunlight and thereby reduce temperature) as the top climate change priority, though climate change itself is ranked well below other world problems. In 2011 the Copenhagen Consensus Center carried out the Rethink HIV project together with the RUSH Foundation, to find smart solutions to the problem of HIV/AIDS. In 2007 looked into which projects would contribute most to welfare in Copenhagen Consensus for Latin America in cooperation with the Inter-American Development Bank.
The initial project was co-sponsored by the Danish government and The Economist. A book summarizing the Copenhagen Consensus 2004 conclusions, Global Crises, Global Solutions, edited by Lomborg, was published in October 2004 by Cambridge University Press, followed by the second edition published in 2009 based on the 2008 conclusions.
Copenhagen Consensus 2012
[edit]In May 2012, the third global Copenhagen Consensus[5] was held, gathering economists to analyze the costs and benefits of different approaches to tackling the world‘s biggest problems. The aim was to provide an answer to the question: If you had $75bn for worthwhile causes, where should you start? A panel including four Nobel laureates met in Copenhagen, Denmark, in May 2012. The panel’s deliberations were informed by thirty new economic research papers that were written just for the project by scholars from around the world.[6]
Economists
[edit]The panel members were the following, four of whom are Nobel Laureate economists.
Challenges
[edit]- Armed conflict[7]
- Biodiversity[8]
- Chronic disease[9]
- Climate Change[10]
- Education[11]
- Hunger and malnutrition[12]
- Infectious disease[13]
- Natural disasters[14]
- Population growth[15]
- Water and sanitation[16]
In addition, the Center commissioned research on Corruption[17] and trade barriers,[18] but the Expert Panel did not rank these for Copenhagen Consensus 2012, because the solutions to these challenges are political rather than investment-related.
Outcome
[edit]Given the budget restraints, they found 16 investments worthy of investment (in descending order of desirability):[3]
- Bundled micronutrient interventions to fight hunger and improve education
- Expanding the subsidy for malaria combination treatment
- Expanded childhood immunization coverage
- Deworming of schoolchildren, to improve educational and health outcomes
- Expanding tuberculosis treatment
- R&D to Increase yield enhancements, to decrease hunger, fight biodiversity destruction, and lessen the effects of climate change
- Investing in effective early warning systems to protect populations against natural disaster
- Strengthening surgical capacity
- Hepatitis B immunization
- Using low‐Cost drugs in the case of acute heart attacks in poorer nations (these are already available in developed countries)
- Salt reduction campaign to reduce chronic disease
- Geo‐engineering R&D into the feasibility of solar radiation management
- Conditional cash transfer for school attendance
- Accelerated HIV vaccine R&D
- Extended field trial of information campaigns on the benefits from schooling
- Borehole and public hand pump intervention
Slate ranking
[edit]During the days of the Copenhagen Consensus 2012 conference, a series of articles was published in Slate Magazine[19] each about a challenge that was discussed, and Slate readers could make their own ranking, voting for the solutions which they thought were best. Slate readers' ranking corresponded with that of the Expert Panel on many points, including the desirability of bundled micronutrient intervention; however, the most striking difference was in connection with the problem of overpopulation. Family planning ranked highest on the Slate priority list, whereas it didn't feature in the top 16 of the Expert Panel's prioritisation.[20]
Copenhagen Consensus 2008
[edit]Economists
[edit]Nobel Prize winners marked with (¤)
- Jagdish Bhagwati
- François Bourguignon
- Finn E. Kydland (¤)
- Robert Mundell (¤)
- Douglass North (¤)
- Vernon L. Smith (¤)
- Thomas Schelling (¤)
- Nancy Stokey
Results
[edit]In the Copenhagen Consensus 2008, the solutions for global problems have been ranked in the following order:[21]
- Micronutrient supplements for children (vitamin A and zinc)
- The Doha development agenda
- Micronutrient fortification (iron and salt iodization)
- Expanded immunization coverage for children
- Biofortification
- Deworming and other nutrition programs at school
- Lowering the price of schooling
- Increase and improve girls’ schooling
- Community-based nutrition promotion
- Provide support for women’s reproductive role
- Heart attack acute management
- Malaria prevention and treatment
- Tuberculosis case finding and treatment
- R&D in low-carbon energy technologies
- Bio-sand filters for household water treatment
- Rural water supply
- Conditional cash transfer
- Peace-keeping in post-conflict situations
- HIV combination prevention
- Total sanitation campaign
- Improving surgical capacity at district hospital level
- Microfinance
- Improved stove intervention to combat Air Pollution
- Large, multipurpose dam in Africa
- Inspection and maintenance of diesel vehicles
- Low sulfur diesel for urban road vehicles
- Diesel vehicle particulate control technology
- Tobacco tax
- R&D and carbon dioxide emissions reduction
- Carbon dioxide emissions reduction
Unlike the 2004 results, these were not grouped into qualitative bands such as Good, Poor, etc.
Gary Yohe, one of the authors of the global warming paper, subsequently accused Lomborg of "deliberate distortion of our conclusions",[22] adding that "as one of the authors of the Copenhagen Consensus Project's principal climate paper, I can say with certainty that Lomborg is misrepresenting our findings thanks to a highly selective memory". Kåre Fog further pointed out that the future benefits of emissions reduction were discounted at a higher rate than for any of the other 27 proposals,[23] stating "so there is an obvious reason why the climate issue always is ranked last" in Lomborg's environmental studies.
In a subsequent joint statement settling their differences, Lomborg and Yohe agreed that the "failure" of Lomborg's emissions reduction plan "could be traced to faulty design".[24]
Climate Change Project
[edit]In 2009, the Copenhagen convened an expert panel specifically to examine solutions to climate change.[25] The process was similar to the 2004 and 2008 Copenhagen Consensus, involving papers by specialists considered by a panel of economists. The panel ranked 15 solutions, of which the top 5 were:
- Research into marine cloud whitening (involving ships spraying sea-water into clouds so as to reflect more sunlight and thereby reduce temperatures)
- Technology-led policy response
- Research into stratospheric aerosol injection (involving injected ?sulphur dioxide into the upper atmosphere to reduce sunlight)
- Research into carbon storage
- Planning for adaptation
The benefits of the number 1 solution are that if the research proved successful this solution could be deployed relatively cheaply and quickly. Potential problems include environmental impacts e.g. from changing rainfall patterns.
Measures to cut carbon and methane emissions, such as carbon taxes, came bottom of the results list, partly because they would take a long time to have much effect on temperatures.
Copenhagen Consensus 2004
[edit]Process
[edit]Eight economists met May 24–28, 2004 at a roundtable in Copenhagen. A series of background papers had been prepared in advance to summarize the current knowledge about the welfare economics of 32 proposals ("opportunities") from 10 categories ("challenges"). For each category, one assessment article and two critiques were produced. After a closed-door review of the background papers, each of the participants gave economic priority rankings to 17 of the proposals (the rest were deemed inconclusive).
Economists
[edit]- Jagdish Bhagwati
- Robert Fogel
- Bruno Frey
- Justin Yifu Lin
- Douglass North
- Thomas Schelling
- Vernon L. Smith
- Nancy Stokey
Challenges
[edit]Below is a list of the 10 challenge areas and the author of the paper on each. Within each challenge, 3–4 opportunities (proposals) were analyzed:
- Communicable diseases (Anne Mills)
- Conflicts (Paul Collier)
- Education (Lant Pritchett)
- Financial instability (Barry Eichengreen)
- Global Warming sometimes also called Climate change (William R. Cline)
- Government and corruption (Susan Rose-Ackerman)
- Malnutrition and hunger (Jere Behrman)
- Population: migration (Phillip L. Martin)
- Sanitation and water (Frank Rijsberman)
- Subsidies and trade barriers (Kym Anderson)
Results
[edit]The panel agreed to rate seventeen of the thirty-two opportunities within seven of the ten challenges. The rated opportunities were further classified into four groups: Very Good, Good, Fair and Bad; all results are based using cost–benefit analysis.
Very good
[edit]The highest priority was assigned to implementing certain new measures to prevent the spread of HIV and AIDS. The economists estimated that an investment of $27 billion could avert nearly 30 million new infections by 2010.
Policies to reduce malnutrition and hunger were chosen as the second priority. Increasing the availability of micronutrients, particularly reducing iron deficiency anemia through dietary supplements, was judged to have an exceptionally high ratio of benefits to costs, which were estimated at $12 billion.
Third on the list was trade liberalization; the experts agreed that modest costs could yield large benefits for the world as a whole and for developing nations.
The fourth priority identified was controlling and treating malaria; $13 billion costs were judged to produce very good benefits, particularly if applied toward chemically-treated mosquito netting for beds.[26]
Good
[edit]The fifth priority identified was increased spending on research into new agricultural technologies appropriate for developing nations. Three proposals for improving sanitation and water quality for a billion of the world’s poorest followed in priority (ranked sixth to eighth: small-scale water technology for livelihoods, community-managed water supply and sanitation, and research on water productivity in food production). Completing this group was the 'government' project concerned with lowering the cost of starting new businesses.
Fair
[edit]Ranked tenth was the project on lowering barriers to migration for skilled workers. Eleventh and twelfth on the list were malnutrition projects – improving infant and child nutrition and reducing the prevalence of low birth weight. Ranked thirteenth was the plan for scaled-up basic health services to fight diseases.
Poor
[edit]Ranked fourteenth to seventeenth were: a migration project (guest-worker programmes for the unskilled), which was deemed to discourage integration; and three projects addressing climate change (optimal carbon tax, the Kyoto Protocol and value-at-risk carbon tax), which the panel judged to be least cost-efficient of the proposals.
Global warming
[edit]The panel found that all three climate policies presented have "costs that were likely to exceed the benefits". It further stated "global warming must be addressed, but agreed that approaches based on too abrupt a shift toward lower emissions of carbon are needlessly expensive."[27]
In regard to the science of global warming, the paper presented by Cline relied primarily on the framework set by Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change, and accepted the consensus view on global warming that greenhouse gas emissions from human activities are the primary cause of the global warming. Cline relies on various research studies published in the field of economics and attempted to compare the estimated cost of mitigation policies against the expected reduction in the damage of the global warming.
Cline used a discount rate of 1.5%. (Cline's summary is on the project webpage [28]) He justified his choice of discount rate on the ground of "utility-based discounting", that is there is zero bias in terms of preference between the present and the future generation (see time preference). Moreover, Cline extended the time frame of the analysis to three hundred years in the future. Because the expected net damage of the global warming becomes more apparent beyond the present generation(s), this choice had the effect of increasing the present-value cost of the damage of global warming as well as the benefit of abatement policies.
Criticism
[edit]Members of the panel including Thomas Schelling and one of the two perspective paper writers Robert O. Mendelsohn (both opponents of the Kyoto protocol) criticised Cline, mainly on the issue of discount rates. (See "The opponent notes to the paper on Climate Change" [28]) Mendelsohn, in particular, characterizing Cline's position, said that "[i]f we use a large discount rate, they will be judged to be small effects" and called it "circular reasoning, not a justification". Cline responded to this by arguing that there is no obvious reason to use a large discount rate just because this is what is usually done in economic analysis. In other words, climate change ought to be treated differently from other, more imminent problems. The Economist quoted Mendelsohn as worrying that "climate change was set up to fail".[29]
Moreover, Mendelsohn argued that Cline's damage estimates were excessive. Citing various recent articles, including some of his own, he stated that "[a] series of studies on the impacts of climate change have systematically shown that the older literature overestimated climate damages by failing to allow for adaptation and for climate benefits."
The 2004 Copenhagen Consensus attracted various criticisms:
Approach and alleged bias
[edit]The 2004 report, especially its conclusion regarding climate change, was subsequently criticised from a variety of perspectives. The general approach adopted to set priorities was criticised by Jeffrey Sachs, an American economist and advocate of both the Kyoto protocol [30] and increased development aid, who argued that the analytical framework was inappropriate and biased and that the project "failed to mobilize an expert group that could credibly identify and communicate a true consensus of expert knowledge on the range of issues under consideration.".[31]
Tom Burke, a former director of Friends of the Earth, repudiated the entire approach of the project, arguing that applying cost–benefit analysis in the way the Copenhagen panel did was "junk economics".[32]
John Quiggin, an Australian economics professor, commented that the project is a mix of "a substantial contribution to our understanding of important issues facing the world" and an "exercises in political propaganda" and argued that the selection of the panel members was slanted towards the conclusions previously supported by Lomborg.[33] Quiggin observed that Lomborg had argued in his controversial book The Skeptical Environmentalist that resources allocated to mitigating global warming would be better spent on improving water quality and sanitation, and was therefore seen as having prejudged the issues.
Under the heading "Wrong Question", Sachs further argued that: "The panel that drew up the Copenhagen Consensus was asked to allocate an additional US$50 billion in spending by wealthy countries, distributed over five years, to address the world’s biggest problems. This was a poor basis for decision-making and for informing the public. By choosing such a low sum — a tiny fraction of global income — the project inherently favoured specific low-cost schemes over bolder, larger projects. It is therefore no surprise that the huge and complex challenge of long-term climate change was ranked last, and that scaling up health services in poor countries was ranked lower than interventions against specific diseases, despite warnings in the background papers that such interventions require broader improvements in health services."
In response Lomborg argued that $50 billion was "an optimistic but realistic example of actual spending." "Experience shows that pledges and actual spending are two different things. In 1970 the UN set itself the task of doubling development assistance. Since then the percentage has actually been dropping". "But even if Sachs or others could gather much more than $50 billion over the next 4 years, the Copenhagen Consensus priority list would still show us where it should be invested first." [34]
Thomas Schelling, one of the Copenhagen Consensus panel experts, later distanced himself from the way in which the Consensus results have been interpreted in the wider debate, arguing that it was misleading to put climate change at the bottom of the priority list. The Consensus panel members were presented with a dramatic proposal for handling climate change. If given the opportunity, Schelling would have put a more modest proposal higher on the list. The Yale economist Robert O. Mendelsohn was the official critic of the proposal for climate change during the Consensus. He thought the proposal was way out of the mainstream and could only be rejected. Mendelsohn worries that climate change was set up to fail.[35]
Michael Grubb, an economist and lead author for several IPCC reports, commented on the Copenhagen Consensus, writing:[36]
To try and define climate policy as a trade-off against foreign aid is thus a forced choice that bears no relationship to reality. No government is proposing that the marginal costs associated with, for example, an emissions trading system, should be deducted from its foreign aid budget. This way of posing the question is both morally inappropriate and irrelevant to the determination of real climate mitigation policy.
Panel membership
[edit]Quiggin argued that the members of the 2004 panel, selected by Lomborg, were "generally towards the right and, to the extent that they had stated views, to be opponents of Kyoto."[33] Sachs also noted that the panel members had not previously been much involved in issues of development economics and were unlikely to reach useful conclusions in the time available to them.[31] Commenting on the 2004 Copenhagen Consensus, climatologist and IPCC author Stephen Schneider criticised Lomborg for only inviting economists to participate:[37]
In order to achieve a true consensus, I think Lomborg would've had to invite ecologists, social scientists concerned with justice and how climate change impacts and policies are often inequitably distributed, philosophers who could challenge the economic paradigm of "one dollar, one vote" implicit in cost–benefit analyses promoted by economists, and climate scientists who could easily show that Lomborg's claim that climate change will have only minimal effects is not sound science.
Lomborg countered criticism of the panel membership by stating that "Sachs disparaged the Consensus 'dream team' because it only consisted of economists. But that was the very point of the project. Economists have expertise in economic prioritization. It is they and not climatologists or malaria experts who can prioritize between battling global warming or communicable disease".[34]
See also
[edit]References
[edit]- ^ "Our story | Copenhagen Consensus Center". www.copenhagenconsensus.com. Retrieved 2 January 2021.
- ^ http://www.copenhagenconsensus.com Copenhagen Consensus Center – CCC Home Page
- ^ a b "Outcome". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Copenhagen Consensus II". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ Copenhagen Consensus 2012
- ^ "Copenhagen Consensus 2012".
- ^ "Armed Conflict". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Biodiversity". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Chronic Disease". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Climate Change". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Education". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Hunger and Malnutrition". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Infectious Disease". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Natural Disasters". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Population Growth". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Water and Sanitation". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Corruption". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Trade Barriers". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Copenhagen Consensus 2012". Slate Magazine. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ Lomborg, Bjørn (14 May 2012). "Slate priority list". Slate.
- ^ "Outcomes". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ Yohe, Gary (22 August 2008). "Climate change is real, compelling and urgent". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 30 April 2010.
- ^ "Index".
- ^ Lomborg, Björn (1 September 2008). "It's not about us". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 30 April 2010.
- ^ "Copenhagen Consensus on Climate | Copenhagen Consensus Center". www.copenhagenconsensus.com. Retrieved 2 January 2021.
- ^ "Search – International Herald Tribune". Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "HIV/AIDS, Hunger, Free Trade and Malaria Top Experts' List" (PDF). copenhagenconsensus.com. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ a b "Climate Change & Energy". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Hotting up". The Economist. 4 February 2005.
- ^ Sachs, Jeffrey D. (21 November 2005). "Changing Climate Change | by Jeffrey D. Sachs". Project Syndicate. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ a b Sachs, Jeffrey D. (21 August 2004). "Seeking a global solution". Nature. 430 (7001): 725–726. doi:10.1038/430725a. Retrieved 21 August 2023 – via www.nature.com.
- ^ Burke, Tom (23 October 2004). "This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense". The Guardian. London. Retrieved 30 April 2010.
- ^ a b Quiggin, John (20 January 2005). "Copenhagen review". Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ a b "Outcome". Copenhagen Consensus. Retrieved 21 August 2023.
- ^ "Hotting up". The Economist. 3 February 2005.
- ^ Grubb, M. (9 March 2005). "House of Lords Select Committee on Economic Affairs Minutes of Evidence. Memorandum by Professor Michael Grubb, Cambridge University, Imperial College, and the Carbon Trust". UK Parliament website. Retrieved 7 February 2009.
- ^ Schneider, S. (n.d.). "Climate Science: Contrarians". Stephen Schneider's website. Archived from the original on 11 May 2008. Retrieved 7 February 2009.
Further reading
[edit]- Lomborg, Bjorn (2006). How to Spend $50 Billion to Make the World a Better Place. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-68571-9.
- Lomborg, Bjørn (2007). Solutions for the World's Biggest Problems: Costs and Benefits. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-71597-3.
- Lomborg, Bjørn (2009). Global Crises, Global Solutions: Costs and Benefits. Cambridge University Press. ISBN 978-0-521-74122-4.
- Sachs, Jeffrey D. (12 August 2004). Seeking a global solution. Nature 430:725–726
- Lind, Robert C. (1982) (ed.): Discounting for time and risk in energy policy. 468 pp. Published by Resources for the Future. inc., Washington D.C.
- Lomborg, Bjorn (2013). How to Spend $75 Billion to Make the World a Better Place. Published by the Copenhagen Consensus Center. ISBN 978-1-940-00300-9
External links
[edit]- The Copenhagen Consensus website
- The Copenhagen Consensus The Economist's home page for the project]
- SourceWatch entry on Copenhagen Consensus
- Global Crises, Global Solutions Transcript of Lomborg's talk at the Carnegie Council.
- Can Development Priorities Be Prioritized?. A presentation by Bjorn Lomborg explaining the Copenhagen Consensus process to World Bank staff on October 12, 2004. Discussants include Robert Watson, Chief Scientist and Senior Advisor at the World Bank’s Environmentally and Socially Sustainable Development unit, and Shahid Yusuf, Economic Advisor, DEC Research Group.
- Criticism: Tom Burke: This is neither scepticism nor science – just nonsense: Why is Bjorn Lomborg's work on climate change taken seriously? The Guardian, 23 October 2004: ("Cost-benefit analysis can help you choose different routes to a goal you have agreed, but it cannot help you choose goals. For that we have politics.")
- What is wrong about Copenhagen Consensus? on the Lomborg-errors web site.