Jump to content

The Ultimate Resource: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
... indicate "abundance".
 
(46 intermediate revisions by 35 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|1981 book by Julian Lincoln Simon}}
{{Infobox book|
{{Infobox book
| name = The Ultimate Resource
| image = The Ultimate Resource.jpg
| author = [[Julian Lincoln Simon|Julian Simon]]
| country = [[United States]]
| caption = First edition
| name = The Ultimate Resource
| language = [[English language|English]]
| genre = [[Nonfiction]]
| author = [[Julian Lincoln Simon|Julian Simon]]
| country = United States
| publisher = [[Princeton University Press]]
| language = English
| release_date = [[1981 in literature|1981]], [[1996 in literature|1996]]
| subject = [[Natural resource]]s
| media_type = Print ([[Hardback]] & [[Paperback]])
| pages = 734 (1996 edition)
| publisher = [[Princeton University Press]]
| isbn = ISBN 0-691-00381-5 (Revised 1996 edition, pbk)
| release_date = 1981, 1996
| media_type = Print ([[hardcover]] & [[paperback]])
| oclc= 39842255
| pages = 734 (1996 edition)
| isbn = 0-691-00381-5
| isbn_note = (Revised 1996 edition, paperback)
| oclc = 39842255
}}
}}
'''''The Ultimate Resource''''' is a 1981 book written by [[Julian Lincoln Simon]] challenging the notion that humanity was running out of [[natural resource]]s. It was revised in 1996 as ''The Ultimate Resource 2''.
'''''The Ultimate Resource''''' is a 1981 book written by [[Julian Lincoln Simon]] challenging the notion that humanity was running out of [[natural resource]]s.<ref name="Simon-1981">{{cite book|last1=Simon|first1=Julian|title=The Ultimate Resource|date=August 1981|publisher=Princeton University Press|location=Princeton|isbn=069109389X|edition=Hardcover|url=https://archive.org/details/ultimateresource00juli|accessdate=6 December 2017}}</ref> It was updated in 1996 as ''The Ultimate Resource 2''.<ref name="Simon-1996">{{cite book|last1=Simon|first1=Julian L|title=The Ultimate Resource 2|date=1996|publisher=Princeton University Press|location=Princeton|isbn=0691042691|edition=Paperback|url=https://archive.org/details/ultimateresource00simo|accessdate=6 December 2017}}</ref>


==Overview==
==Overview==
The overarching [[thesis]] on why there is no resource [[crisis]] is that as a particular resource becomes more [[scarce]], its [[price]] rises; this rise of price creates an incentive for people to discover more of the resource, ration and recycle it and, eventually, develop substitutes. The “ultimate resource” is not any particular physical object but the capacity for humans to invent and adapt.
The overarching [[thesis]] on why there is no resource [[crisis]] is that as a particular resource becomes more [[scarce]], its [[price]] rises. This price rise creates an incentive for people to discover more of the resource, ration and recycle it, and eventually, develop substitutes. The "ultimate resource" is not any particular physical object but the capacity for humans to invent and adapt.


===Scarcity===
===Scarcity===
The work opens with an explanation of scarcity, noting its relation to price; high prices denote relative scarcity and low prices indicate [[abundance]]. Simon usually measures prices in wage adjusted terms, since this is a measure of how much labor is required to purchase a fixed amount of a particular resource. Since prices for most raw materials (e.g. [[copper]]) have fallen between 1800 and 1990 (adjusting for [[wages]] and adjusting for [[inflation]]), Simon argues that this indicates that those materials have become less scarce.
The work opens with an explanation of scarcity, noting its relation to price; high prices denote relative scarcity and low prices indicate [[:wikt:abundance|abundance]]. Simon usually measures prices in wage-adjusted terms, since this is a measure of how much labor is required to purchase a fixed amount of a particular resource. Since prices for most raw materials (e.g., [[copper]]) have fallen between 1800 and 1990 (adjusting for [[wages]] and adjusting for [[inflation]]), Simon argues that this indicates that those materials have become less scarce.


[[Image:westmine.jpg|right|thumb|Simon contends that resources, such as copper, become less scarce as demand for them drives recycling, development of alternatives, new extraction techniques etc, which are all reflected in the drop in their wage-adjusted prices.]]
[[File:westmine.jpg|right|thumb|Simon contends that resources, such as copper, become less scarce as demand for them drives recycling, development of alternatives, and new extraction techniques, which are all reflected in the drop in their wage-adjusted prices.]]


===Forecasting===
===Forecasting===
Simon makes a distinction between "engineering” and “economic” forecasting. Engineering forecasting consists of estimating the amount of known physical amount of resources, [[extrapolate]]s the rate of use from current use and subtracts one from the other. Simon argues that these simple analyses are often wrong. While focusing only on proven resources is helpful in a [[business]] context, it is not appropriate for economy-wide forecasting; there exist undiscovered sources, sources not yet economically feasible to extract, sources not yet [[technology|technologically]] feasible to extract, and misconceived resources that could prove useful but are not yet worth trying to discover.
Simon makes a distinction between "engineering” and "economic" forecasting. Engineering forecasting consists of estimating the amount of known physical amount of resources, [[extrapolate]]s the rate of use from current use and subtracts one from the other. Simon argues that these simple analyses are often wrong. While focusing only on proven resources is helpful in a [[business]] context, it is not appropriate for economy-wide forecasting. There exist undiscovered sources, sources not yet economically feasible to extract, sources not yet [[technology|technologically]] feasible to extract, and ignored resources that could prove useful but are not yet worth trying to discover.


To counter the problems of engineering forecasting, Simon proposes economic forecasting, which proceeds in three steps in order to capture, in part, the unknowns the engineering method leaves out (p 27):
To counter the problems of engineering forecasting, Simon proposes economic forecasting, which proceeds in three steps in order to capture, in part, the unknowns the engineering method leaves out (p 27):
{{cquote|
{{cquote|
# Ask whether there is any convincing reason to think that the period for which you are forecasting will be different from the past, going back as far as the data will allow;
# Ask whether there is any convincing reason to think that the period for which you are forecasting will be different from the past, going back as far as the data will allow
# If there is no good reason to reject the past trend as representative of the future as well, ask whether there is a reasonable explanation for the observed trend;
# If there is no good reason to reject the past trend as representative of the future as well, ask whether there is a reasonable explanation for the observed trend
# If there is no reason to believe that the future will be different from the past, and if you have solid explanation for the trend—or even if you lack a solid theory, but the data are overwhelming—project the trend into the future.}}
# If there is no reason to believe that the future will be different from the past, and if you have solid explanation for the trend—or even if you lack a solid theory, but the data are overwhelming—project the trend into the future}}


===Infinite resources===
===Infinite resources===
Perhaps the most controversial claim in the book is that natural resources are infinite. Simon argues not that there is an infinite ''physical'' amount of, say, copper, but for human purposes that amount should be treated as infinite because it is not [[bounded]] or limited in any ''economic'' sense, because:
Perhaps the most controversial claim in the book is that natural resources are infinite. Simon argues not that there is an infinite ''physical'' amount of, say, copper, but for human purposes that amount should be treated as infinite because it is not [[wikt:bounded|bounded]] or limited in any ''economic'' sense, because:
* known reserves are of uncertain amounts
* known reserves are of uncertain quantity
* new reserves may become available, either through discovery or via the development of new extraction techniques
* new reserves may become available, either through discovery or via the development of new extraction techniques
* recycling
* recycling
* more efficient utilization of existing reserves (e.g. "It takes much less copper now to pass a given message than a hundred years ago." [''The Ultimate Resource 2'', 1996, footnote, page 62])
* more efficient utilization of existing reserves (e.g., "It takes much less copper now to pass a given message than a hundred years ago." [''The Ultimate Resource 2'', 1996, footnote, page 62])
* development of economic equivalents, e.g. [[optic fibre]] in the case of copper for [[telecommunications]]
* development of economic equivalents, e.g., [[optic fibre]] in the case of copper for [[telecommunications]]


The ever-decreasing prices (and thus decreasing scarcity) despite population growth suggest an enduring trend that will not cease in the foreseeable future.
The ever-decreasing prices, in [[wage inflation|wage-adjusted terms]], indicate decreasing scarcity, in that it takes less time for the average worker to earn the money required to purchase a set amount of some commodity. This suggests, Simon claims, an enduring trend of increased availability that will not cease in the foreseeable future, despite continued population growth.


==Evidence==
==Evidence==
Line 47: Line 51:
Simon argues that for thousands of years, people have always worried about the end of [[civilization]] brought on by a crisis of resources. Simon lists several past unfounded [[Environmentalism|environmental]] fears in order to back his claim that modern fears are nothing new and will also be disproven.
Simon argues that for thousands of years, people have always worried about the end of [[civilization]] brought on by a crisis of resources. Simon lists several past unfounded [[Environmentalism|environmental]] fears in order to back his claim that modern fears are nothing new and will also be disproven.


Some of the “crises” he notes are a shortage of [[tin]] in the 13th century [[BCE]]; disappearing [[forest]]s in [[Greece]] in 550 BCE and in [[England]] in the 16th century to 18th century [[Common Era|CE]]; [[food]] in 1798; [[coal]] in Great Britain in the 19th century; [[oil]] since the 1850s; and various [[metal]]s since the 1970s.
Some of the "crises" he notes are a shortage of [[tin]] in the 13th century [[BCE]]; [[deforestation|disappearing forests]] in [[Greece]] in 550 BCE and in England in the 16th century to 18th century [[Common Era|CE]]; food in 1798; coal in Great Britain in the 19th century; oil since the 1850s; and various metals since the 1970s.


== Simon–Ehrlich wager ==
== Simon–Ehrlich wager ==
{{main|Simon–Ehrlich wager}}
{{main|Simon–Ehrlich wager}}


Based on preliminary research for The Ultimate Resource, Julian L. Simon and Paul Ehrlich entered in a famous wager in 1980, betting on a mutually agreed upon measure of resource scarcity over the decade leading up to 1990.
Based on preliminary research for ''The Ultimate Resource'', Simon and Paul Ehrlich made a famous wager in 1980, betting on a mutually agreed upon measure of resource scarcity over the decade leading up to 1990.


Ehrlich was the author of a popular book, [[The Population Bomb]], which argued that mankind was facing a demographic catastrophe with the rate of population growth quickly outstripping growth in the supply of food and resources. Simon was highly skeptical of such claims.
Ehrlich was the author of a popular book, ''[[The Population Bomb]]'', which argued that mankind was facing a demographic catastrophe with the rate of population growth quickly outstripping growth in the supply of food and resources. Simon was highly skeptical of such claims.


Simon had Ehrlich choose five of several commodity metals. Ehrlich chose 5 metals: copper, chromium, nickel, tin, and tungsten. Simon bet that their prices would go down. Ehrlich bet they would go up.
Simon had Ehrlich choose five of several commodity metals. Ehrlich chose five metals: copper, chromium, nickel, tin, and tungsten. Simon bet that their prices would go down. Ehrlich bet they would go up.


The basket of goods, costing $1,000 in 1980, fell in price by over 57% over the following decade. As a result, in October 1990, Paul Ehrlich mailed Julian Simon a check for $576.07 to settle the wager in Simon's favor.
The basket of goods, costing US$1,000 in 1980, fell in price by over 57 percent over the following decade. As a result, in October 1990, Paul Ehrlich mailed Julian Simon a check for US$576.07 to settle the wager in Simon's favor.


==Population==
==Population==
A large section of the book is dedicated to showing how population growth ultimately creates more resources. The basic argument echoes the overarching thesis: as resources become more scarce, the price rises, creating an incentive to adapt. The more a society has to [[invent]] and [[innovate]], ''[[ceteris paribus]]'' {{Clarify|date=July 2011}}, the easier the society will raise its living standards and lower resource scarcity. People, on average, add to a civilization more than they take away. People are the ultimate resource.{{Citation needed|date=July 2011}}
A large section of the book is dedicated to showing how population growth ultimately creates more resources. The basic argument echoes the overarching thesis: as resources become more scarce, the price rises, creating an incentive to adapt. It suggests that the more a society has to [[invent]] and [[innovate]], all else being equal, the more easily the society will raise its living standards and lower resource scarcity.
==Criticism==
{{Expand section|date=July 2023}}


==See also==
==See also==
Line 69: Line 76:
*[[Post scarcity]]
*[[Post scarcity]]


==Sources==
==References==
{{reflist}}
*Simon, Julian. ''The Ultimate Resource 2.'' (1996).


==External links==
==External links==
*[http://www.juliansimon.org/writings/Ultimate_Resource/ Full text of ''The Ultimate Resource 2'']
*[http://www.juliansimon.org/writings/Ultimate_Resource/ Full text of ''The Ultimate Resource 2'']
* [http://enough_already.tripod.com/dalysimon.htm Critique of 'The Ultimate Resource'] by Herman Daly, 1991, originally in Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, January 1982
* [[Wikiversity:What is the ultimate resource?]]
* [http://www.juliansimon.com/reply-critics.html Julian Simons's response to critics from ''The Ultimate Resource 2'']


{{population}}
{{population}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Ultimate Resource (Book)}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Ultimate Resource (Book)}}
[[Category:Capitalist books]]
[[Category:1981 non-fiction books]]
[[Category:1981 books]]
[[Category:1981 in the environment]]
[[Category:Economics books]]
[[Category:1996 in the environment]]
[[Category:Books about capitalism]]
[[Category:Environmental non-fiction books]]
[[Category:Environmental non-fiction books]]
[[Category:American non-fiction books]]
[[Category:English-language non-fiction books]]
[[Category:Works about scarcity]]
[[Category:Demography books]]
[[Category:Works about human overpopulation]]

Latest revision as of 02:01, 3 January 2025

The Ultimate Resource
First edition
AuthorJulian Simon
LanguageEnglish
SubjectNatural resources
PublisherPrinceton University Press
Publication date
1981, 1996
Publication placeUnited States
Media typePrint (hardcover & paperback)
Pages734 (1996 edition)
ISBN0-691-00381-5 (Revised 1996 edition, paperback)
OCLC39842255

The Ultimate Resource is a 1981 book written by Julian Lincoln Simon challenging the notion that humanity was running out of natural resources.[1] It was updated in 1996 as The Ultimate Resource 2.[2]

Overview

[edit]

The overarching thesis on why there is no resource crisis is that as a particular resource becomes more scarce, its price rises. This price rise creates an incentive for people to discover more of the resource, ration and recycle it, and eventually, develop substitutes. The "ultimate resource" is not any particular physical object but the capacity for humans to invent and adapt.

Scarcity

[edit]

The work opens with an explanation of scarcity, noting its relation to price; high prices denote relative scarcity and low prices indicate abundance. Simon usually measures prices in wage-adjusted terms, since this is a measure of how much labor is required to purchase a fixed amount of a particular resource. Since prices for most raw materials (e.g., copper) have fallen between 1800 and 1990 (adjusting for wages and adjusting for inflation), Simon argues that this indicates that those materials have become less scarce.

Simon contends that resources, such as copper, become less scarce as demand for them drives recycling, development of alternatives, and new extraction techniques, which are all reflected in the drop in their wage-adjusted prices.

Forecasting

[edit]

Simon makes a distinction between "engineering” and "economic" forecasting. Engineering forecasting consists of estimating the amount of known physical amount of resources, extrapolates the rate of use from current use and subtracts one from the other. Simon argues that these simple analyses are often wrong. While focusing only on proven resources is helpful in a business context, it is not appropriate for economy-wide forecasting. There exist undiscovered sources, sources not yet economically feasible to extract, sources not yet technologically feasible to extract, and ignored resources that could prove useful but are not yet worth trying to discover.

To counter the problems of engineering forecasting, Simon proposes economic forecasting, which proceeds in three steps in order to capture, in part, the unknowns the engineering method leaves out (p 27):

# Ask whether there is any convincing reason to think that the period for which you are forecasting will be different from the past, going back as far as the data will allow

  1. If there is no good reason to reject the past trend as representative of the future as well, ask whether there is a reasonable explanation for the observed trend
  2. If there is no reason to believe that the future will be different from the past, and if you have solid explanation for the trend—or even if you lack a solid theory, but the data are overwhelming—project the trend into the future

Infinite resources

[edit]

Perhaps the most controversial claim in the book is that natural resources are infinite. Simon argues not that there is an infinite physical amount of, say, copper, but for human purposes that amount should be treated as infinite because it is not bounded or limited in any economic sense, because:

  • known reserves are of uncertain quantity
  • new reserves may become available, either through discovery or via the development of new extraction techniques
  • recycling
  • more efficient utilization of existing reserves (e.g., "It takes much less copper now to pass a given message than a hundred years ago." [The Ultimate Resource 2, 1996, footnote, page 62])
  • development of economic equivalents, e.g., optic fibre in the case of copper for telecommunications

The ever-decreasing prices, in wage-adjusted terms, indicate decreasing scarcity, in that it takes less time for the average worker to earn the money required to purchase a set amount of some commodity. This suggests, Simon claims, an enduring trend of increased availability that will not cease in the foreseeable future, despite continued population growth.

Evidence

[edit]

A plurality of the book consists of chapters showcasing the economics of one resource or another and proposing why this resource is, for human purposes, infinite.

Historical precedent

[edit]

Simon argues that for thousands of years, people have always worried about the end of civilization brought on by a crisis of resources. Simon lists several past unfounded environmental fears in order to back his claim that modern fears are nothing new and will also be disproven.

Some of the "crises" he notes are a shortage of tin in the 13th century BCE; disappearing forests in Greece in 550 BCE and in England in the 16th century to 18th century CE; food in 1798; coal in Great Britain in the 19th century; oil since the 1850s; and various metals since the 1970s.

Simon–Ehrlich wager

[edit]

Based on preliminary research for The Ultimate Resource, Simon and Paul Ehrlich made a famous wager in 1980, betting on a mutually agreed upon measure of resource scarcity over the decade leading up to 1990.

Ehrlich was the author of a popular book, The Population Bomb, which argued that mankind was facing a demographic catastrophe with the rate of population growth quickly outstripping growth in the supply of food and resources. Simon was highly skeptical of such claims.

Simon had Ehrlich choose five of several commodity metals. Ehrlich chose five metals: copper, chromium, nickel, tin, and tungsten. Simon bet that their prices would go down. Ehrlich bet they would go up.

The basket of goods, costing US$1,000 in 1980, fell in price by over 57 percent over the following decade. As a result, in October 1990, Paul Ehrlich mailed Julian Simon a check for US$576.07 to settle the wager in Simon's favor.

Population

[edit]

A large section of the book is dedicated to showing how population growth ultimately creates more resources. The basic argument echoes the overarching thesis: as resources become more scarce, the price rises, creating an incentive to adapt. It suggests that the more a society has to invent and innovate, all else being equal, the more easily the society will raise its living standards and lower resource scarcity.

Criticism

[edit]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ Simon, Julian (August 1981). The Ultimate Resource (Hardcover ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 069109389X. Retrieved 6 December 2017.
  2. ^ Simon, Julian L (1996). The Ultimate Resource 2 (Paperback ed.). Princeton: Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691042691. Retrieved 6 December 2017.
[edit]