Jump to content

User:Jonhanke496/AtlasModels: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Changed t^{-1} to 1/t in the coherence defintion Asymptotic stability
Added a comment about the importance of the drift in the relative return decomposition, fixed typos, and mentioned the explicit canonical portfolio drift
 
(12 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
= History of Stochastic Portfolio Theory =
= Atlas models =


Once upon a time, in a far away land, there lived a stochastic portfolio ... =)
An '''Atlas Model''' is a stochastic model for a market of <math>n</math> stocks where the stock with the smallest total capitalization is given a large positive growth rate of <math>ng,</math> while all other stocks are assumed to have zero growth rate. The name "atlas model" stems from the fact that the growth of the market is supported entirely by the growth of the smallest stock, by analogy with the mythological [[Atlas_(mythology)|Atlas]]. Atlas models are useful as a way of understanding the stability of the [[:File:U.S._Stock_market_capital_distribution_curves_1929-2009.pdf|capital distribution curve]]. Their mathematical simplicity allows one to prove that in such a market the capital distribution curve is stable and given by [[Pareto distribution]]. The fact that even these simple models have a [[:File:U.S._Stock_market_capital_distribution_curves_1929-2009.pdf|capital distribution curve]] that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape, shows that the stability of the capital distribution curve is a fairly universal market phenomenon.


'''Note to Authors:''' Compare this with the introduction of the article [[Modern Portfolio Theory]]
More mathematically, the atlas model with parameters <math>g,\sigma</math> is defined by the stochastic differential equation

:<math>
= Capital distributon curve =
d\log(X_i(t)) = \gamma_i(t) \, dt + \sigma \, dW_i(t)

</math>
[[Image:U.S. Stock market capital distribution curves 1929-2009.pdf|thumb|300px|right|alt=Figure 1: U.S. stock market capital distribution curves, 1929–2009.|Figure A plots the (ranked) capital distribution curves at the end of each of the last nine decades. This log-log plot has exhibited remarkable stability over long periods of time.
where for all <math>1\leq i \leq n</math> the <math>W_i(t)</math> are independent Brownian motions, and the positive real
<!--
parameters <math>g, \sigma >0</math> are respectively called the '''growth rate''' and '''variance''' of the Atlas model.
The study of such stability is one of the major goals of [[Stochastic Portfolio Theory]].
-->
]]

The '''capital distribution curve''' of a market of <math>n</math> stocks is defined to be the plot of the ranked log market weights <math>\log(\mu_{(k)}(t))</math>
of the stocks in decreasing order (i.e. by their rank <math>k</math>) as a function of <math>k,</math> where the ranked market weights <math>\mu_{(k)}(t)</math> are a permutation of the unranked market weights <math>\mu_{i}(t),</math> defined for all <math>1 \leq i \leq n</math> by
:<math>\mu_i(t) := \frac{X_i(t)}{X_1(t) + \cdots + X_n(t)}</math>
where <math>X_i(t)</math> is the price of the <math>i</math>-th stock at time <math>t</math>. This curve shows a remarkable stability over time (see Figure A), and various market models (e.g. [[#Atlas models|Atlas models]], first-order models, second-order models) have been constructed to understand its stability and shape. In many markets this appears to follow a [[Pareto distribution]].


= Asymptotic stability =
= Asymptotic stability =


To understand the existence and stability of the capital distribution curve in a general stochastic market it is necessary to make some reasonable assumptions about its behavior. A useful class of markets to consider are those which are '''asymptotically stable''', which is defined in <ref name="SPT Book">{{cite book|last=Fernholz|first=E. Robert|title=Stochastic Portfolio Theory|year=2002|publisher=Springer Science+Business Media, Inc.|isbn=0-387-95405-8|page=100}}</ref> by the technical conditions of being [[Stochastic portfolio theory#Stocks, portfolios and markets|coherent]] and that the difference of the adjacent stocks log market weights (when ranked by their capitalization in decreasing order) have local time and variance with asymptotically constant slope. In more mathematical language, asymptotic stability of a stochastic market with <math>n</math> stocks requires that
To understand the existence and stability of the capital distribution curve in a general stochastic market it is necessary to make some reasonable assumptions about its behavior. A useful class of markets to consider are those which are '''asymptotically stable''', which is defined in <ref name="SPT Book">{{cite book|last=Fernholz|first=E. Robert|title=Stochastic Portfolio Theory|year=2002|publisher=Springer Science+Business Media, Inc.|isbn=0-387-95405-8|page=100}}</ref> by the technical conditions of being [[Stochastic portfolio theory#Stocks, portfolios and markets|coherent]] and that the difference of the log market weights of adjacent stocks (when ranked by their capitalization in decreasing order) have local time and variance with asymptotically constant slope. In more mathematical language, asymptotic stability of a stochastic market with <math>n</math> stocks requires that


:<math>\operatorname{lim}_{t\rightarrow\infty} \tfrac{1}{t} \log(\mu_i(t)) = 0 </math> for all <math>1 \leq i \leq n</math> {{pad|2em}}('''Coherence''')
:<math>\operatorname{lim}_{t\rightarrow\infty} \tfrac{1}{t} \log(\mu_i(t)) = 0 </math> for all <math>1 \leq i \leq n</math> {{pad|2em}}('''Coherence''')
Line 21: Line 29:
# <math>\mathbb{V}_{k:k+1} := \lim_{t \rightarrow \infty} \tfrac{1}{t} \langle\log(\mu_{(k)}) - \log(\mu_{(k+1)})\rangle_t</math>
# <math>\mathbb{V}_{k:k+1} := \lim_{t \rightarrow \infty} \tfrac{1}{t} \langle\log(\mu_{(k)}) - \log(\mu_{(k+1)})\rangle_t</math>


exist for all <math> 1 \leq k \leq n-1</math>. (Here <math>\Lambda_{X}(t)</math> and <math>\langle X \rangle_{t}</math> respectively denote the [[Local_time_(mathematics)|local time]] and [[Quadratic_variation|quadratic variation]] process of a given [[Semimartingale#Continuous_semimartingales|continuous semimartingale]] process <math>X(t),</math> and <math>\mu_{(k)}</math> denotes the <math>k^{\mathrm{th}}</math> ranked market weight process (ranked in decreasing order).)
exist for all <math> 1 \leq k \leq n-1</math>. (Here <math>\Lambda_{X}(t)</math> and <math>\langle X \rangle_{t}</math> respectively denote the [[Local_time_(mathematics)|local time]] and [[Quadratic_variation|quadratic variation]] process of a given [[Semimartingale#Continuous_semimartingales|continuous semimartingale]] process <math>X(t),</math> and <math>\mu_{(k)}</math> denotes the <math>k</math>-th ranked market weight process (i.e. in non-increasing order as <math>k</math> increases).)


= Functionally generated portfolios =

A '''functionally generated portfolio''' (generated by a function <math>S(\vec\mu)</math>) is a portfolio <math>\vec\pi(t)</math> that is both given as a function of the market weights <math>\mu_i(t)</math> and whose relative log-return with respect to the market portfolio satisfies the stochastic differential decomposition
:<math>
d \ln(Z_{\vec\pi}/Z_{\vec\mu}(t)) = d \ln(S(\vec\mu(t))) + d\Theta_{\vec\pi}(t)
</math>
where <math>d\Theta_{\vec\pi}(t)</math> has no stochastic differential component. The importance of this relative return decomposition comes from the observation that often the function <math>\ln(S(\mu))</math> is known to be bounded, so the long-term behaviour of the relative performance comes from the behaviour of the drift process <math>\Theta_{\vec\pi}(t)</math>, and this drift can be usually given explicitly in terms of the generating function <math>S(\mu).</math>

Given a function <math>S(\vec\mu)</math> satisfying mild continuity conditions (e.g. twice continuously differentiable), one can always write down a '''canonical functionally generated portfolio''' <math>\vec\pi_{S}(t)</math> generated by <math>S,</math> given explicitly as
:<math>
\vec\pi_S(\vec\mu) := \vec\mu + \vec{F}_{S}(\vec\mu) - \vec\mu (\vec{1} \cdot \vec{F}_{S}(\vec\mu))
</math>
where
:<math>
\vec{F}_{S}(\vec\mu) := \vec\mu (\nabla\ln(S))(\vec\mu)
</math>
and where the product <math>\vec{z} := \vec{x}\vec{y}</math> of two vectors is defined componentwise by <math>z_i := x_i y_i</math>. The drift process of this portfolio is given by the formula
:<math>
\Theta_{\vec\pi_S}(t) = \cdots .
</math>

= Atlas models =

An '''atlas model''' is a stochastic model for a market of <math>n</math> stocks where the stock with the smallest total capitalization is given a large positive growth rate of <math>ng,</math> while all other stocks are assumed to have zero growth rate. The name "atlas model" stems from the fact that the growth of the market is supported entirely by the growth of the smallest stock, by analogy with the mythological [[Atlas_(mythology)|Atlas]]. Atlas models are useful as a way of understanding the stability of the [[:File:U.S._Stock_market_capital_distribution_curves_1929-2009.pdf|capital distribution curve]]. Their mathematical simplicity allows one to prove that they are [[#Asymptotic stability|asymptotically stable]] and that in such a market the capital distribution curve is stable and given by an explicit [[Pareto distribution]]. The fact that even these simple models have a [[:File:U.S._Stock_market_capital_distribution_curves_1929-2009.pdf|capital distribution curve]] that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape shows that the stability of the capital distribution curve is a fairly universal market phenomenon.

More mathematically, the atlas model with (positive) real parameters <math>g,\sigma</math> is defined by the stochastic differential equations
:<math>
d\log(X_i(t)) = \gamma_i(t) \, dt + \sigma \, dW_i(t)
</math>
for all <math>1\leq i \leq n,</math> where the individual stock growth rates are given by
:<math>
\gamma_i(t) :=
\begin{cases}
ng & \mathrm{if }\, X_{i}(t) = X_{(n)}(t),\\
0 & \mathrm{otherwise},
\end{cases}
</math>
and the <math>W_i(t)</math> are independent Brownian motions. Here the parameters <math>g, \sigma^2</math> are respectively called the '''growth rate''' and '''variance''' of the atlas model.


= Misc fragments =
= Misc fragments =
Line 29: Line 77:
Even these simple models have a capital distribution curve that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape,
Even these simple models have a capital distribution curve that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape,


as a first-order approximation to market
as a first-order approximation to market








= Capital distributon curve =

[[Image:U.S. Stock market capital distribution curves 1929-2009.pdf|thumb|300px|right|alt=Figure 1: U.S. stock market capital distribution curves, 1929–2009.|Figure A plots the (ranked) capital distribution curves at the end of each of the last nine decades. This log-log plot has exhibited remarkable stability over long periods of time. The study of such stability is one of the major goals of SPT.]]

The '''capital distribution curve''' of a market of <math>n</math> stocks is defined to be the plot of the ranked log market weights <math>\log(\mu_{(k)}(t))</math>
of the stocks in decreasing order (i.e. by their rank <math>k</math>) as a function of <math>k,</math> where the ranked market weights <math>\mu_{(k)}(t)</math> are a permutation of the unranked market weights <math>\mu_{i}(t),</math> defined for all <math>1 \leq i \leq n</math> by
:<math>\mu_i(t) := \frac{X_i(t)}{X_1(t) + \cdots + X_n(t)}</math>
where <math>X_i(t)</math> is the price of the <math>i</math>-th stock at time <math>t</math>. This curve shows a remarkable stability over time (see Figure A), and various market models (e.g. [[#Atlas models|Atlas models]], first-order models, second-order models) have been constructed to understand its stability and shape. In many markets this appears to follow a [[Pareto distribution]].


= References =
= References =
{{reflist}}
{{reflist}}
'''Bold text'''

Latest revision as of 21:32, 31 October 2013

History of Stochastic Portfolio Theory

[edit]

Once upon a time, in a far away land, there lived a stochastic portfolio ... =)

Note to Authors: Compare this with the introduction of the article Modern Portfolio Theory

Capital distributon curve

[edit]
Figure 1: U.S. stock market capital distribution curves, 1929–2009.
Figure A plots the (ranked) capital distribution curves at the end of each of the last nine decades. This log-log plot has exhibited remarkable stability over long periods of time.

The capital distribution curve of a market of stocks is defined to be the plot of the ranked log market weights of the stocks in decreasing order (i.e. by their rank ) as a function of where the ranked market weights are a permutation of the unranked market weights defined for all by

where is the price of the -th stock at time . This curve shows a remarkable stability over time (see Figure A), and various market models (e.g. Atlas models, first-order models, second-order models) have been constructed to understand its stability and shape. In many markets this appears to follow a Pareto distribution.

Asymptotic stability

[edit]

To understand the existence and stability of the capital distribution curve in a general stochastic market it is necessary to make some reasonable assumptions about its behavior. A useful class of markets to consider are those which are asymptotically stable, which is defined in [1] by the technical conditions of being coherent and that the difference of the log market weights of adjacent stocks (when ranked by their capitalization in decreasing order) have local time and variance with asymptotically constant slope. In more mathematical language, asymptotic stability of a stochastic market with stocks requires that

for all  (Coherence)

and that the parameters and defined by

exist for all . (Here and respectively denote the local time and quadratic variation process of a given continuous semimartingale process and denotes the -th ranked market weight process (i.e. in non-increasing order as increases).)


Functionally generated portfolios

[edit]

A functionally generated portfolio (generated by a function ) is a portfolio that is both given as a function of the market weights and whose relative log-return with respect to the market portfolio satisfies the stochastic differential decomposition

where has no stochastic differential component. The importance of this relative return decomposition comes from the observation that often the function is known to be bounded, so the long-term behaviour of the relative performance comes from the behaviour of the drift process , and this drift can be usually given explicitly in terms of the generating function

Given a function satisfying mild continuity conditions (e.g. twice continuously differentiable), one can always write down a canonical functionally generated portfolio generated by given explicitly as

where

and where the product of two vectors is defined componentwise by . The drift process of this portfolio is given by the formula

Atlas models

[edit]

An atlas model is a stochastic model for a market of stocks where the stock with the smallest total capitalization is given a large positive growth rate of while all other stocks are assumed to have zero growth rate. The name "atlas model" stems from the fact that the growth of the market is supported entirely by the growth of the smallest stock, by analogy with the mythological Atlas. Atlas models are useful as a way of understanding the stability of the capital distribution curve. Their mathematical simplicity allows one to prove that they are asymptotically stable and that in such a market the capital distribution curve is stable and given by an explicit Pareto distribution. The fact that even these simple models have a capital distribution curve that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape shows that the stability of the capital distribution curve is a fairly universal market phenomenon.

More mathematically, the atlas model with (positive) real parameters is defined by the stochastic differential equations

for all where the individual stock growth rates are given by

and the are independent Brownian motions. Here the parameters are respectively called the growth rate and variance of the atlas model.

Misc fragments

[edit]

Fun with bold characters:

Even these simple models have a capital distribution curve that fairly accurately approximates its observed shape,

as a first-order approximation to market



References

[edit]
  1. ^ Fernholz, E. Robert (2002). Stochastic Portfolio Theory. Springer Science+Business Media, Inc. p. 100. ISBN 0-387-95405-8.

Bold text