Jump to content

Economy of the Soviet Union: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
period (only) after sentence
 
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Short description|none}}
The '''economy of the Soviet Union''' was based on a system of state ownership and administrative planning. The [[Soviet Union]] created the modern world's first [[centrally planned economy]]. The first major project of economic planning was the [[GOELRO plan]], which was introduced in 1920 and basically fulfilled by 1931. It included construction of a network of 30 regional [[power plants]], including ten large [[hydroelectric power plant]]s, and numerous electric-powered large industrial enterprises. The Plan became the prototype for subsequent [[Five-Year Plan (USSR)|five-year plans]].


{{More footnotes needed|date=February 2019}}
From [[1928]] to [[1991]] the entire course of the economy was guided by a series of Five-Year Plans. The nation became among the world's three top manufacturers of a large number of basic and heavy industrial products, but lagged far behind in the output of light industrial production and [[consumer goods in the Soviet Union|consumer durables]]. Since the dissolution of the Soviet Union in [[1991]], all but a handful of the 15 former [[Soviet republics]] have dismantled their Soviet-style economies (''see'' [[History of the Soviet Union (1985-1991)#Restructuring the Soviet system|Transition from economic planning in the former Soviet Union]]).


{{Update|date=December 2023|reason=More recent sources}}
==Planning==


{{Use dmy dates|date=June 2022}}
Based on a system of state ownership, the Soviet economy was managed through ''[[Gosplan]]'' (the State Planning Commission), ''[[Gosbank]]'' (the State Bank) and the [[Gossnab]] (State Commission for Materials and Equipment Supply). Beginning in [[1928]], the economy was directed by a series of [[Five-Year Plan (USSR)|five-year plan]]s, with a brief attempt at seven-year planning. For every enterprise, planning ministries (also known as the "fund holders" or ''fondoderzhateli'') defined the mix of economic inputs (e.g., labor and raw materials), a schedule for completion, all [[wholesale price]]s and almost all [[retail price]]s.
ur gay
Industry was long concentrated after 1928 on the production of [[capital goods]] through [[metallurgy]], machine manufacture, and chemical industry. In Soviet terminology, the capital goods were known as ''group A goods'', or ''[[means of production]]''. This emphasis was based on the perceived necessity for a very fast industrialization and modernization of the Soviet Union. After the death of Stalin in [[1953]], [[consumer goods]] (''group B goods'') received more emphasis. ''For further details see [[consumer goods in the Soviet Union]].''


{{Infobox economy
Most information in the Soviet economy flowed from the top down. There were several mechanisms in place for producers and consumers to provide input and information that would help in the drafting of economic plans (as detailed below), but the political climate was such that few people ever provided negative input or criticism of the plan. Thus, Soviet planners had very little reliable feedback which they could use to determine the success of their plans. This meant that economic planning was often done based on faulty or outdated information, particularly in sectors with large numbers of consumers.
| country = the Soviet Union
| image = DneproGES 1947.JPG
| gdp = $820 billion in 1977<br>(nominal; 2nd)<br>$1.21 trillion in 1980<br>(nominal; 2nd)<br>$1.57 trillion in 1982<br>(nominal; 2nd)<br>$2.20 trillion in 1985<br>(nominal; 2nd)<br>$2.66 trillion in 1990<br>(PPP; 2nd){{Unreliable source?|date=May 2024}}<ref name="GDPinfobox1990"/>
| gdp rank = 2nd<ref name="GDPinfobox1990">{{cite web|title=GDP – Million 1990|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1991|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1990/rankings/gdp_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref><ref>{{cite web|title=GDP – Million 1991|location=KayLee|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/gdp_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| caption = The [[Dnieper Hydroelectric Station|DniproHES]] [[Hydropower|hydro-electric power plant]], one of the symbols of Soviet economic power, was completed in 1932.
| width = 250
| currency = [[Soviet rouble|Rouble]] (SUR)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox">{{cite web|title=Soviet Union Economy 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb1991/soviet_union/soviet_union_economy.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| year = 1 January–31 December ([[calendar year]])<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| organs = [[Comecon]], [[ESCAP]] and others<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| per capita = $6,577 in 1977<br>(nominal)<br>$7,568 in 1980<br>(nominal)<br>$7,943 in 1982<br>(nominal)<br>$8,896 in 1985<br>(nominal)<br>$9,931 in 1991<br>(GNP; 28th)<ref>{{cite web|title=GDP Per Capita 1990|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1991|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1990/rankings/gdp_per_capita_1.html|access-date=16 January 2017}}</ref>
| sectors = Agriculture: (20%)<br>Industry: (80%)<br>(1988 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| inflation = 14% (43rd) (in 1991)
3.9% (in 1984)<ref>{{cite web|title=Inflation Rate % 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/inflation_rate_pct_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| growth = 4.7% (in 1977)
4.2% ( in 1980) 3.8% (in 1982) 3.5% (in 1985) 0.9% (in 1990)
| poverty = 1-3% of population (1980 est.)<br>12% of population (1991 est.)
| gini = 0.290 (1980 est.)<br>0.275 (1989 est.)<ref>{{cite web|last1=Alexeev|first1=Michael V.|title=Income Distribution in the USSR in the 1980s|url=http://www.roiw.org/1993/23.pdf|website=Review of Income and Wealth (1993)|publisher=Indiana University|access-date=16 April 2017}}</ref>
| labor = 152.3 million (3rd)<br>(1989 est.)<ref>{{cite web|title=Labor Force 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/labor_force_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| occupations = 80% in industry and other non-agricultural sectors; 20% in agriculture (1989 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| unemployment = 1–2% (1990 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| industries = [[Petroleum]], [[steel]], [[motor vehicles]], [[aerospace]], [[machinery]], [[telecommunications]], [[Chemical industry|chemicals]], [[heavy industries]], [[electronics]], [[food processing]], [[lumber]], [[mining]] and [[Defense industry|defense]] (1989 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| exports = $124.7 billion (9th)<br>(1989 est.)<ref>{{cite web|title=Exports Million 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/exports_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| export-goods = Petroleum and petroleum products, [[natural gas]], [[metals]], [[wood]], machinery, agricultural products and a wide variety of manufactured goods<br>(1989 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| export-partners = [[Eastern Bloc]] 49%, [[European Community]] 14%, [[Cuba]] 5%, [[United States]], [[Democratic Republic of Afghanistan|Afghanistan]]<br>(1988 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| imports = $114.7 billion (10th)<br>(1989 est.)<ref>{{cite web|title=Imports Million 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/imports_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| import-goods = Grain and other agricultural products, machinery and equipment, steel products (including large-diameter pipe), consumer manufactures<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| import-partners = Eastern Bloc 54%, [[European Community]] 11%, Cuba, [[People's Republic of China|China]], United States<br>(1988 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| FDI =
| debt =
| gross external debt = $55 billion (11th)<br>(1989 est.)<ref>{{cite web|title=Budget External Debt Million 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/budget_expenditures_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121101175311/http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/budget_expenditures_million_1.html|archive-date=1 November 2012|url-status=dead}}</ref><br>$27.3 billion<br>(1988 est.)<ref name=cia1990/>
| revenue = $422 billion (5th)<br>(1990 est.)<ref>{{cite web|title=Budget Revenues Million Million 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/budget_revenues_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010}}</ref>
| expenses = $510 billion (1989 est.)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/><br>$53 million (2nd; [[capital expenditures]]) (1991 est.)<ref>{{citation |title=Budget Expenditures Million 1991|work=[[CIA Factbook]]|year=1992|url=http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/budget_expenditures_million_1.html|access-date=12 June 2010|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20121101175311/http://www.theodora.com/wfb/1991/rankings/budget_expenditures_million_1.html|archive-date=1 November 2012|url-status=dead}}</ref>
| aid = $147.6 billion (1954–1988)<ref name="CIAFactbookinfobox"/>
| cianame =
| spelling =
}}


The '''economy of the Soviet Union''' was based on [[state ownership]] of the [[means of production]], [[collective farming]], and [[Industrial engineering|industrial manufacturing]]. An [[administrative-command system]] managed a [[Soviet-type economic planning|distinctive form]] of [[Economic planning#Soviet Union|central planning]]. The Soviet economy was second only to the United States and was characterized by state control of [[investment]], [[prices]], a dependence on [[natural resources]], lack of [[Final good|consumer goods]], little [[foreign trade]], public ownership of industrial assets, [[Economic stability|macroeconomic stability]], low [[unemployment]] and high [[job security]].<ref>Hanson, Philip (2003). ''The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy'' (Routledge). pp. 1–8.</ref>
As a result of the above, some goods tended to be underproduced, leading to shortages (''defitsit'', дефицит), while other goods were overproduced and accumulated in storage. Low-level managers often did not report such problems to their superiors, relying instead on each other for support. Some factories developed a system of [[barter (economics)|barter]] and either exchanged or shared raw materials and parts without the knowledge of the authorities and outside the parameters of the economic plan.


Beginning in 1930, the course of the economy of the [[Soviet Union]] was guided by a series of [[Five-year plans of the Soviet Union|five-year plans]]. By the 1950s, the Soviet Union had rapidly evolved from a mainly [[agrarian society]] into a major industrial power.{{sfn|Davies|1998|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=mNffDWnt25wC&pg=PA1 1], [https://books.google.com/books?id=mNffDWnt25wC&pg=PA3 3]}} Its transformative capacity meant [[communism]] consistently appealed to the intellectuals of [[Developing country|developing countries]] in Asia.<ref>{{Harvnb|Peck|2006|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=AA-jbmyfl54C&pg=PA47 p. 47]}}.<br>One notable person in this regard was [[Jawaharlal Nehru|Nehru]], "who visited the Soviet Union in the late 1920s and was deeply impressed by Soviet industrial progress." See {{Harvnb|Bradley|2010|pp=475–476}}.</ref> In fact, Soviet economic authors like [[Lev Gatovsky]] (who participated in the elaboration of the [[First five-year plan (Soviet Union)|first]] and [[Five-year plans of the Soviet Union|second]] five-year plans) frequently used their economic analysis of this period to praise the effectiveness of the October Revolution. The impressive growth rates during the first three five-year plans (1928–1940) are particularly notable given that this period is nearly congruent with the [[Great Depression]].{{sfn|Allen|2003|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=FX4o33jOIX0C&pg=PA153 153]}} During this period, the Soviet Union saw rapid industrial growth while other regions were suffering from crisis.<ref>{{cite book|author=Baten, Jörg |title=A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present.|date=2016|publisher=Cambridge University Press|pages=62–63|isbn=9781107507180}}</ref> The [[White House]] [[United States National Security Council|National Security Council]] of the [[United States]] described the continuing growth as a "proven ability to carry backward countries speedily through the crisis of modernization and industrialization", and the impoverished base upon which the five-year plans sought to build meant that at the commencement of [[Operation Barbarossa]] in 1941 the country was still poor.{{sfn|Harrison|1996|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=yJcD7_Q_rQ8C&pg=PA123 123]}}{{sfn|Davies|1998|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=mNffDWnt25wC&pg=PA2 2]}}<!-- *** commenting out till later *** it lagged far behind in the output of [[light industrial]] production and consumer durables, mostly because of the inability of [[Gosplan]], the economic planning committee, to predict the demand for such products.{{cn}} -->
Heavy industry was always the focus of the Soviet economy, even in its later years. The fact that it received special attention from the planners, combined with the fact that industrial production was relatively easy to plan even without minute feedback, led to significant growth in that sector. The Soviet Union became one of the leading industrial nations of the world. Industrial production was disproportionately high in the Soviet Union compared to Western economies. However, the production of consumer goods was disproportionately low. Economic planners made little effort to determine the wishes of household consumers, resulting in severe shortages of many consumer goods. Whenever these consumer goods would become available on the market, consumers routinely had to stand in long lines (queues) to buy them. A black market developed for goods that were particularly sought after but constantly underproduced (such as [[cigarette]]s).


Even so, the Soviet Union had the second largest economy in the world from the end of World War II until the mid-1980s. A major strength of the Soviet economy was its enormous supply of oil and gas, which became much more valuable as exports after the world [[price of oil]] [[1970s energy crisis|skyrocketed in the 1970s]]. As [[Daniel Yergin]] notes, the Soviet economy in its final decades was "heavily dependent on vast natural resources–oil and gas in particular". World oil prices collapsed in 1986, putting heavy pressure on the economy.<ref>Daniel Yergin, ''The Quest: Energy, Security, and the Remaking of the Modern World'' (2011); quotes on pp 23, 24.</ref> After [[Mikhail Gorbachev]] became the [[General Secretary of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union]] and came to power in 1985, he began a process of [[economic liberalization]] by [[Perestroika|dismantling]] the [[command economy]] and moving towards a [[mixed economy]] modeled after Lenin's [[New Economic Policy]]. At its [[Dissolution of the Soviet Union|dissolution at the end of 1991]], the Soviet Union began a [[Russian Federation]] with a growing pile of $66 billion in external debt and with barely a few billion dollars in net gold and foreign exchange reserves.<ref name="Boughton 2012 288">{{Harvnb|Boughton|2012|p=288}}.</ref>
===Drafting the five-year plans===
Under [[Joseph Stalin|Stalin]]'s tutelage, a complex system of planning arrangements had developed since the introduction of the first five-year plan in 1928. Until the late-[[1980s]] and early-[[1990s]], when economic reforms backed by Soviet leader [[Mikhail Gorbachev]] introduced significant changes in the traditional system (''see'' ''[[Perestroika]]''), the allocation of resources was directed by a planning apparatus rather than through the interplay of [[market economy|market]] forces.


The complex demands of the modern economy somewhat constrained the central planners. Data fiddling became common practice among the [[Government of the Soviet Union|bureaucracy]] by reporting fulfilled targets and quotas, thus entrenching the crisis. From the [[History of the Soviet Union (1927–53)|Stalin-era]] to the early [[History of the Soviet Union (1964–82)|Brezhnev-era]], the Soviet economy grew slower than [[Economy of Japan|Japan]] and faster than the [[Economy of the United States|United States]]. GDP levels in 1950 (in billion 1990 dollars) were 510 (100%) in the Soviet Union, 161 (100%) in Japan and 1,456 (100%) in the United States. By 1965, the corresponding values were 1,011 (198%), 587 (365%) and 2,607 (179%).<ref>Angus Maddison, ''The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective'' (2001) pp. 274, 275, 298.</ref> The Soviet Union maintained itself as the world's second largest economy in both nominal and purchasing power parity values throughout the [[Cold War]], until 1990 when Japan's economy exceeded $3 trillion in nominal value.<ref>[http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/weo/2014/02/weodata/weorept.aspx?pr.x=61&pr.y=11&sy=1987&ey=1989&scsm=1&ssd=1&sort=country&ds=.&br=1&c=158%2C111&s=NGDPD&grp=0&a= "Japan's IMF nominal GDP Data 1987 to 1989 (October 2014)"].</ref>
====Timeframe====
From the Stalin era through the late [[1980s]], the [[Five year plan|five-year plan]] integrated short-range planning into a longer timeframe. It delineated the chief thrust of the country's economic development and specified the way the economy could meet the desired goals of the [[Communist Party of the Soviet Union|Communist Party]]. Although the five-year plan was enacted into law, it contained a series of guidelines rather than a set of direct orders.


The Soviet Union's relatively medium consumer sector accounted for just 60% of the country's GDP in 1990 while the industrial and agricultural sectors contributed 22% and 20% respectively in 1991. [[Agriculture in the Soviet Union|Agriculture]] was the predominant occupation in the Soviet Union before the massive industrialization under Soviet general secretary [[Joseph Stalin]]. The [[Service (economics)|service]] sector was of low importance in the Soviet Union, with the majority of the labor force employed in the [[industrial sector]]. The labor force totaled 152.3 million people. Though its GDP crossed $1 trillion in the 1970s and $2 trillion in the 1980s, the effects of [[central planning]] were progressively distorted due to the growth of the [[black market]] [[Informal economy|informal]] [[second economy in the Soviet Union]].<ref name="treadle">Vladimir G. Treml and Michael V. Alexeev, [https://www.ucis.pitt.edu/nceeer/1993-900-03-Treml.pdf "THE SECOND ECONOMY AND THE DESTABILIZING EFFECT OF ITS GROWTH ON THE STATE ECONOMY IN THE SOVIET UNION: 1965–1989"], BERKELEY-DUKE OCCASIONAL PAPERS ON THE SECOND ECONOMY IN THE USSR, Paper No. 36, December 1993</ref>
Periods covered by the five-year plans coincided with those covered by the gatherings of the [[Congress of the CPSU|CPSU Party Congress]]. At each CPSU Congress, the party leadership presented the targets for the next five-year plan. Thus, each plan had the approval of the most authoritative body of the country's leading political institution.


== Planning ==
====Guidelines for the plan====
{{see also|Analysis of Soviet-type economic planning}}
The [[Central Committee of the CPSU]] and, more specifically, its [[Politburo of the CPSU Central Committee|Politburo]], set basic guidelines for planning. The Politburo determined the general direction of the economy via control figures (preliminary plan targets), major investment projects (capacity creation), and general economic policies. These guidelines were submitted as a report of the Central Committee to the [[Congress of the CPSU]] to be approved there.
Based on a system of state ownership, the Soviet economy was managed through [[Gosplan]] (the State Planning Commission), [[Gosbank]] (the State Bank) and the [[Gossnab]] (State Commission for Materials and Equipment Supply). Beginning in 1928, the economy was directed by a series of [[Five-year plans of the Soviet Union|five-year plans]], with a brief attempt at seven-year planning. For every enterprise, planning ministries (also known as the "fund holders" or ''fondoderzhateli'') defined the mix of economic inputs (e.g. labor and raw materials), a schedule for completion, all [[wholesale price]]s and almost all [[retail price]]s. The planning process was based around [[Material balance planning|material balances]]—balancing economic inputs with planned output targets for the planning period. From 1930 until the late 1950s, the range of mathematics used to assist economic decision-making was, for ideological reasons, extremely restricted.<ref name="Smolinski 1973 1189">{{Harvnb|Smolinski|1973|pp=1189–90}}: "The mathematical sophistication of the tools actually employed was limited to those that had been used in ''Das Kapital'': the four arithmetical operations, percentages, and arithmetic (but not geometric) mean."</ref> On the whole, the plans were overoptimistic and plagued by falsified reporting.<ref>Holland Hunter, "The Overambitious First Soviet Five-Year Plan." ''Slavic Review'' 32.2 (1973): 237-257.</ref>


{{further|Consumer goods in the Soviet Union}}
After the approval at the congress, the list of priorities for the five-year plan was processed by the [[Sovnarkom|Council of Ministers]], which constituted the government of the USSR. The Council of Ministers was composed of industrial ministers, chairmen of various state committees, and chairmen of agencies with ministerial status. This committee stood at the apex of the vast economic administration, including the state planning apparatus, the industrial ministries, the trusts (the intermediate level between the ministries and the enterprises), and finally, the state enterprises. The Council of Ministers elaborated on Politburo plan targets and sent them to ''[[Gosplan]]'', which gathered data on plan fulfillment.
The industry was long concentrated after 1928 on the production of [[capital goods]] through [[metallurgy]], machine manufacture, and chemical industry. In Soviet terminology, goods were known as ''capital''.{{Citation needed|date=October 2020}} This emphasis was based on the perceived necessity for very fast industrialization and modernization of the Soviet Union. After the death of [[Joseph Stalin]] in 1953, [[consumer goods]] (group B goods) received somewhat more emphasis due to the efforts of [[Georgy Malenkov]]. However, when [[Nikita Khrushchev]] consolidated his power by sacking Malenkov, one of the accusations against him was that he permitted "theoretically incorrect and politically harmful opposition to the rate of development of heavy industry in favor of the rate of development of light and food industry".<ref>[http://archive.svoboda.org/programs/hd/2005/hd.020505.asp "Георгий Маленков. 50 лет со дня отставки"], ''[[Radio Liberty]]''</ref> Since 1955, the priorities were again given to capital goods, which was expressed in the decisions of the [[20th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union]] (CPSU) in 1956.<ref>Пыжиков А. В. ''Хрущевская "Оттепель" : 1953—1964,'' Olma-Press, 2002 {{ISBN|978-5224033560}}</ref>


Economist Naum Jasny says that while many of the official statistics were correctly reported:
====Gosplan====
:The fact is that the most important official general indices of economic development – those of national income, industrial output, real incomes of wage-earners and peasants, labour productivity and production costs in industry – have, over long periods of time....nothing in common with reality.<ref>Naum Jasny, "Some Thoughts on Soviet Statistics: An Evaluation," ''International Affairs'' (Royal Institute of International Affairs) 35#1 (1959), pp. 53-60, [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2606987 online]</ref>


Most information in the Soviet economy flowed from the top down. There were several mechanisms in place for producers and consumers to provide input and information that would help in the drafting of economic plans (as detailed below), but the political climate was such that few people ever provided negative input or criticism of the plan and thus Soviet planners had very little reliable feedback that they could use to determine the success of their plans. This meant that economic planning was often done based on faulty or outdated information, particularly in sectors with large numbers of consumers. As a result, some goods tended to be underproduced and led to shortages while other goods were overproduced and accumulated in storage. Low-level managers often did not report such problems to their superiors, relying instead on each other for support. Some factories developed a system of [[barter (economics)|barter]] and either exchanged or shared raw materials and parts without the knowledge of the authorities and outside the parameters of the economic plan.
''Main article: [[Gosplan]]''


Heavy industry was always the focus of the Soviet economy even in its later years. The fact that it received special attention from the planners, combined with the fact that industrial production was relatively easy to plan even without minute feedback, led to significant growth in that sector. The Soviet Union became one of the leading industrial nations of the world. Industrial production was disproportionately high in the Soviet Union compared to Western economies. By the 60s calorie consumption per person in the Soviet Union was at levels similar to the United States. However, the production of consumer goods was disproportionately low. Economic planners made little effort to determine the wishes of household consumers, resulting in severe shortages of many consumer goods. Whenever these consumer goods would become available on the market, consumers routinely had to stand in long lines (queues) to buy them.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.rbth.com/society/2013/10/16/a_look_at_the_old_ration_system_in_russia_30163|title=A look at the old ration system in Russia|last1=Revinskaya|first1=Elena|last2=RIR|date=2013-10-16|website=www.rbth.com|language=en-US|access-date=2019-03-21}}</ref> A [[black market]] developed for goods such as [[cigarette]]s that were particularly sought after, but it constantly underproduced. People were developing unique social "networks of favors" between people having access to sought after goods (for example, working in particular shops or factories).<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://blogs.commons.georgetown.edu/rees-577-fall2016/2016/10/18/the-importance-of-blats-in-soviet-everyday-life/|title=The Importance of Blats in Soviet Everyday Life {{!}} Socialist and Post-Socialist Cities|language=en-US|access-date=2019-03-21}}</ref>
Combining the broad goals laid out by the Council of Ministers with data supplied by lower administrative levels regarding the current state of the economy, [[Gosplan]] worked out, through trial and error, a set of preliminary plan targets. Among more than twenty state committees, ''Gosplan'' headed the government's planning apparatus and was by far the most important agency in the economic administration. The task of planners was to balance resources and requirements to ensure that the necessary inputs were provided for the planned output. The planning apparatus alone was a vast organizational arrangement consisting of councils, commissions, governmental officials, specialists, etc. charged with executing and monitoring economic policy.


=== Drafting the five-year plans ===
The state planning agency was subdivided into its own industrial departments, such as [[coal]], [[iron]], and [[machine]] building. It also had summary departments such as [[finance]], dealing with issues that crossed functional boundaries. With the exception of a brief experiment with regional planning during the [[Nikita Khrushchev|Khrushchev]] era in the [[1950s]], Soviet planning was done on a sectoral basis rather than on a regional basis. The departments of the state planning agency aided the agency's development of a full set of plan targets along with input requirements, a process involving bargaining between the ministries and their superiors.
[[File:Leon Trotsky in exile.webp|200x200px|thumb|Leon Trotsky was among the earliest Soviet figures that supported [[economic planning]] and [[decentralization]]<ref name=Twiss>{{cite book |last1=Twiss |first1=Thomas M. |title=Trotsky and the Problem of Soviet Bureaucracy |date=8 May 2014 |publisher=BRILL |isbn=978-90-04-26953-8 |pages=88–113 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=3o2fAwAAQBAJ&dq=Trotsky+economic+planning+1923&pg=PA135 |language=en}}</ref> but opposed the [[Stalinism|Stalinist]] model.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Van Ree |first1=Erik |title=Socialism in One Country: A Reassessment |journal=Studies in East European Thought |date=1998 |volume=50 |issue=2 |pages=77–117 |doi=10.1023/A:1008651325136 |jstor=20099669 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/20099669 |issn=0925-9392}}</ref>]]
Under [[Joseph Stalin]]'s close supervision, a complex system of planning arrangements had developed since the introduction of the first five-year plan in 1928.<ref>Nick Shepley, ''Stalin, the Five Year Plans and the Gulags: Slavery and Terror 1929-53'' (2015).</ref> Preceding this, [[Leon Trotsky]] had delivered a joint report to the April Plenum of the Central Committee in 1926 which proposed a program for national [[industrialisation]] and the replacement of annual plans with five-year plans. His proposals were rejected by the [[Central Committee]] majority which was controlled by the troika and derided by Stalin at the time.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Rogovin |first1=Vadim Zakharovich |title=Was There an Alternative? Trotskyism: a Look Back Through the Years |date=2021 |publisher=Mehring Books |isbn=978-1-893638-97-6 |page=358 |language=en}}</ref> Stalin's version of the five-year plan was implemented in 1928 and took effect until 1932.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://uwaterloo.ca/library/special-collections-archives/first-five-year-plan|title=The First Five Year Plan, 1928–1932|date=2015-10-07|website=Special Collections & Archives|language=en|access-date=2019-02-23}}</ref> According to historian [[Sheila Fitzpatrick]], the scholarly consensus was that Stalin appropriated the position of the [[Left Opposition]] on such matters as [[industrialisation]] and [[collectivisation]].<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Fitzpatrick |first1=Sheila |title=The Old Man |journal=London Review of Books |date=22 April 2010 |volume=32 |issue=8 |url=https://www.lrb.co.uk/the-paper/v32/n08/sheila-fitzpatrick/the-old-man |language=en |issn=0260-9592}}</ref>


Until the late 1980s and early 1990s, when economic reforms backed by Soviet leader [[Mikhail Gorbachev]] introduced significant changes in the traditional system (see [[perestroika]]), the allocation of resources was directed by a planning apparatus rather than through the interplay of [[market economy|market]] forces.
====Planning ministries====
[[Image:Kalinin-prospekt-cccp.jpg|250px|thumb|On Kalinin Prospekt, government buildings of the economic ministries in [[Moscow]] kept their lights on at night reading "СССР" the Russian abbreviation of USSR.]]


==== Time frame ====
Economic ministries performed key roles in the Soviet organizational structure. When the planning goals had been established by ''Gosplan'', economic ministries drafted plans within their jurisdictions and disseminated planning data to the subordinate enterprises.
From the Stalin era through the late 1980s, the [[Five-year plans of the Soviet Union|five-year plan]] integrated short-range planning into a longer time frame. It delineated the chief thrust of the country's economic development and specified the way the economy could meet the desired goals of the [[Communist Party of the Soviet Union]]. Although the five-year plan was enacted into law, it contained a series of guidelines rather than a set of direct orders.


Periods covered by the five-year plans coincided with those covered by the gatherings of the [[Congress of the CPSU|CPSU Party Congress]]. At each CPSU Congress, the party leadership presented the targets for the next five-year plan, therefore each plan had the approval of the most authoritative body of the country's leading political institution.
The planning data were sent downward through the planning hierarchy for progressively more detailed elaboration. The ministry received its control targets, which were then disaggregated by branches within the ministry, then by lower units, eventually until each enterprise received its own control figures (production targets).


====Enterprises====
==== Guidelines for the plan ====
The [[Central Committee of the CPSU]] and more specifically its [[Politburo of the CPSU Central Committee|Politburo]] set basic guidelines for planning. The Politburo determined the general direction of the economy via control figures (preliminary plan targets), major investment projects (capacity creation) and general economic policies. These guidelines were submitted as a report of the Central Committee to the Congress of the CPSU to be approved there. After the approval at the Congress, the list of priorities for the five-year plan was processed by the [[Sovnarkom|Council of Ministers]], which constituted the government of the Soviet Union. The Council of Ministers was composed of industrial ministers, chairmen of various state committees and chairmen of agencies with ministerial status. This committee stood at the apex of the vast economic administration, including the state planning apparatus, the industrial ministries, the trusts (the intermediate level between the ministries and the enterprises) and finally the state enterprises. The Council of Ministers elaborated on Politburo plan targets and sent them to Gosplan, which gathered data on plan fulfillment.<ref>R.W. Davies and Oleg Khlevnyuk, "Gosplan." in E. A. Rees, ed., ''Decision-making in the Stalinist Command Economy, 1932–37'' (1997). 32-66.</ref>
Enterprises were called upon to develop the most detailed plans covering all aspects of their operations so that they could assess the feasibility of targets, thus opening up the most intense bargaining phase in the planning process. As the individual enterprise drafted its detailed production plans, the flow of information was reversed; enterprise managers and even rank-and-file workers often participated in the planning process at this level. According to Soviet reports, roughly 110 million Soviet workers took part in discussions in the final period of state planning in the late-[[1980s]] and early-[[1990s]] (even though such participation was mostly limited to a rubber-stamping of prepared statements during huge pre-staged meetings).


==== Gosplan ====
The enterprises' draft plans were then sent back up through the planning ministries for review. This process entailed intensive bargaining, with all parties seeking the target levels and input figures that best suited their interests.
{{main|Gosplan}}
Combining the broad goals laid out by the Council of Ministers with data supplied by lower administrative levels regarding the current state of the economy, [[Gosplan]] worked out through trial and error a set of preliminary plan targets. Among more than twenty state committees, Gosplan headed the government's planning apparatus and was by far the most important agency in the economic administration. The task of planners was to balance resources and requirements to ensure that the necessary inputs were provided for the planned output. The planning apparatus alone was a vast organizational arrangement consisting of councils, commissions, governmental officials, specialists and so on charged with executing and monitoring economic policy.


The state planning agency was subdivided into its own industrial departments, such as coal, iron and machine building. It also had summary departments such as finance, dealing with issues that crossed functional boundaries. With the exception of a brief experiment with regional planning during the Khrushchev era in the 1950s, Soviet planning was done on a sectoral basis rather than on a regional basis. The departments of the state planning agency aided the agency's development of a full set of plan targets along with input requirements, a process involving bargaining between the ministries and their superiors. Economic ministries performed key roles in the Soviet organizational structure. When the planning goals had been established by Gosplan, economic ministries drafted plans within their jurisdictions and disseminated planning data to the subordinate enterprises. The planning data were sent downward through the planning hierarchy for progressively more detailed elaboration. The ministry received its control targets, which were then disaggregated by branches within the ministry, then by lower units, eventually until each enterprise received its own control figures (production targets).<ref>Michael Ellman, ''Socialist planning'' (Cambridge UP, 2014).</ref>
====Redrafting the plan====
After this bargaining process, ''Gosplan'' received the revised estimates and re-aggregated them as it saw fit. Then, the redrafted plan was sent to the Council of Ministers and the Party's Politburo and Central Committee Secretariat for approval. The Council of Ministers submitted the Plan to the [[Supreme Soviet]] and the Central Committee submitted the plan to the Party Congress, both for rubber stamp approval. By this time, the process had been completed and the plan became law.


Enterprises were called upon to develop in the final period of state planning in the late 1980s and early 1990s (even though such participation was mostly limited to a rubber-stamping of prepared statements during huge pre-staged meetings). The enterprises' draft plans were then sent back up through the planning ministries for review. This process entailed intensive bargaining, with all parties seeking the target levels and input figures that best suited their interests.
====Approval of the plan====
The review, revision, and approval of the five-year plan were followed by another downward flow of information, this time with the amended and final plans containing the specific targets for each sector of the economy. Implementation began at this point, and was largely the responsibility of enterprise managers.


After this bargaining process, Gosplan received the revised estimates and re-aggregated them as it saw fit. The redrafted plan was then sent to the Council of Ministers and the party's Politburo and Central Committee Secretariat for approval. The Council of Ministers submitted the plan to the [[Supreme Soviet of the Soviet Union]] and the Central Committee submitted the plan to the party congress, both for rubber stamp approval. By this time, the process had been completed and the plan became law.
==Economic development==
[[Image:Assembling-car.jpg|250px|left|thumb|An assembly-line worker works on the axle of a [[Moskvich]] car, made by [[AZLK]]. Enterprises in the Soviet Union were more than just places of work; they were responsible for a broad range of social welfare functions&mdash;building and maintaining housing for their workforces, and managing health, recreational, educational, and similar facilities.]]


The review, revision and approval of the five-year plan were followed by another downward flow of information, this time with the amended and final plans containing the specific targets for each sector of the economy. Implementation began at this point and was largely the responsibility of enterprise managers.
Starting in 1928, the five-year plans began building a heavy industrial base at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry, and without reliance on external financing. The country now became industrialized at an unbelievable pace, perhaps surpassing [[Germany]]'s pace of industrialization in the nineteenth century and [[Japan]]'s earlier in the twentieth. After the reconstruction of the economy (in the wake of the destruction caused by the [[Russian Civil War]]) was completed, and after the initial plans of further [[History of the Soviet Union (1927-1953)|industrialisation]] were fulfilled, the explosive growth slowed down, but still generally surpassed most of the other countries in terms of total material production ([[GNP]]) until the period of [[Brezhnev stagnation]] in the second half of the [[1970]]s.


The national [[state budget]] was prepared by the [[Ministry of Finance (Soviet Union)|Ministry of Finance of the Soviet Union]] by negotiating with its [[all-Union]] local organizations. If the state budget was accepted by the Soviet Union, it was then adopted.<ref>{{cite book | author = the IMF | title = A Study of the Soviet economy | publisher = [[International Monetary Fund]] (IMF) | year = 1991 | volume = 1 | pages = 287 | url = https://books.google.com/books?id=xJpygdfiyHUC | isbn = 978-92-64-13468-3 }}</ref>
Industrialization came with the extension of medical services, which improved labor [[Productivity (economics)|productivity]]. Campaigns were carried out against [[typhus]], [[cholera]], and [[malaria]]; the number of physicians increased as rapidly as facilities and training would permit; and death and [[infant mortality]] rates steadily decreased.


According to a number of scholars both inside and outside of USSR, it was specifically [[Soviet-type economic planning]] combined with political dogmatism which led to gradual degradation of Soviet economy and its collapse.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Dembinski|first=Pawel|title=The Logic of Planned Economy: The Seeds of the Collapse|year=1991|publisher=Clarendon Press |isbn=978-0198286868}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|last=Ellman|first=Michael|title=Planning Problems in the USSR: The Contribution of Mathematical Economics to their Solution 1960-1971|year=1973|publisher=CUP Archive |isbn=978-0521202497}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=Optimizing things in the USSR · Chris Said|url=https://chris-said.io/2016/05/11/optimizing-things-in-the-ussr/|access-date=2020-11-15|website=chris-said.io}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=Николай Петрович Шмелёв (Nikolay Shmelyov) "Авансы и долги (Avansy i dolgi)" ("Credits and debts"), Новый мир (Novyi Mir) – 1987. - № 6.|url=https://echelon.pl/nikolay-shmelyov-avansy-i-dolgi-credits-and-debts-novyi-mir-1987-6.html|access-date=2020-11-15|website=echelon.pl}}</ref>
As weighed growth rates, economic planning performed very well during the early and mid-[[1930s]], [[World War II]]-era mobilization, and for the first two decades of the postwar era. The Soviet Union became the world's leading producer of [[Petroleum|oil]], [[coal]], [[iron ore]], and [[cement]]; [[manganese]], [[gold]], [[natural gas]] and other [[minerals]] were also of major importance.


{{See also|Soviet-type economic planning}}
Growth slowed after [[1960]], but this was considered characteristic of a mature, industrialized economy at the time. However, the planning ministries had failed to loosen their control of the enterprise level in time to stem the prolonged stagnation of the [[1970s]] and [[1980s]], which showed signs of a chronic problem.


== Agriculture ==
The Soviet planned economy was not tailored at a sufficient pace to the demands of the more complex modern economy it had helped to forge. As the economy grew, the volume of decisions facing planners in [[Moscow]] became overwhelming. The cumbersome procedures for bureaucratic administration did not enable the free communication and flexible response required at the enterprise level for dealing with worker alienation, innovation, customers, and suppliers.
{{main|Agriculture in the Soviet Union}}
[[File:“Strengthen working discipline in collective farms” – Uzbek, Tashkent, 1933 (Mardjani).jpg|thumb|''"Strengthen working discipline in collective farms"'', a Soviet propaganda poster issued in [[Uzbek Soviet Socialist Republic|Uzbekistan]], 1933]]
In the USSR, [[agriculture]] was organized into a system of collective farms ([[Kolkhoz|''kolkhozes'']]) and state farms ([[Sovkhoz|''sovkhozes'']]). These farms were collectivized distributed amongst the peasantry and yearly production quotas were set by administrators. Before Stalin, Soviet agriculture held its own. Data from the 1920s infers a positive supply response to increases in the terms of trade. Farmers increased grain sales to urban areas when the price of grain increased.<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal|last1=Antel|first1=John|last2=Gregory|first2=Paul|date=1994|title=Agricultural Surplus Models and Peasant Behavior: Soviet Agriculture in the 1920s|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1154447|journal=Economic Development and Cultural Change|volume=42|issue=2|pages=375–386|doi=10.1086/452085|jstor=1154447|s2cid=153635813|issn=0013-0079}}</ref> However, at the time, agricultural production was limited by technology, as the whole of Soviet Agriculture relied heavily on animal powered tilling. In the 1930s due to massive famines and animal die offs, the number of remaining animals doing farm work was reduced by half.<ref name=":0" /> This indicated the dire need of additional production outputs, which administrators predicted could be supplied by mechanical harvesters. The planning of Soviet leadership emphasized a mechanical agricultural industry, whereby technology and ideology met to create a booming agricultural industry.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Dekel-Chen|first=Jonathan|date=2020|title=Putting Agricultural History to Work: Global Action Today from a Communal Past|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512|journal=Agricultural History|volume=94|issue=4|pages=512–544|doi=10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512|jstor=10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512|s2cid=229207917|issn=0002-1482}}</ref> This way, the technological evolution of Soviet agricultural production could be linked to urban industry.<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal|last=Clayton|first=Elizabeth|date=September 1980|title=Productivity in Soviet Agriculture|url=https://www.cambridge.org/core/journals/slavic-review/article/abs/productivity-in-soviet-agriculture/6148F0C20A2E5E03DDF7475D5145BBE9|journal=Slavic Review|language=en|volume=39|issue=3|pages=446–458|doi=10.2307/2497164|jstor=2497164|s2cid=163496553 |issn=0037-6779}}</ref> Yet in reality, Soviet planners were more invested in industry than farmers, and the Soviet agricultural industry suffered as a result.<ref name=":2">{{Cite journal|last=HALE-DORRELL|first=AARON|date=2015|title=The Soviet Union, the United States, and Industrial Agriculture|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/43901754|journal=Journal of World History|volume=26|issue=2|pages=295–324|jstor=43901754|issn=1045-6007}}</ref> An example of this can be seen in the analysis published in 1929 by soviet economist [[Lev Gatovsky]] regarding government intervention on the grain market.<ref name=":02">{{Cite journal |author=Гатовский, Лев Маркович |date=1929 |title=О соотношениях цен в 1927/28 и начале 1928/29 гг. |url=https://istmat.org/files/uploads/43959/l.gatovskiy.o_sootnosheniyah_cen_v_1927_28_i_nachale_928_29_gg.pdf |format= |type= |series= |language= |edition=Сборник статей |location= |publisher= |volume= |issue= |page= |pages= |at= |arxiv= |bibcode= |doi= |isbn= |issn= |pmid= |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20220116105314/http://istmat.info/files/uploads/43959/l.gatovskiy.o_sootnosheniyah_cen_v_1927_28_i_nachale_928_29_gg.pdf |archive-date=2022-01-16 |quote= |editor= |orig-year= |agency= |number=}}</ref>


[[Leon Trotsky]] and the Opposition bloc had advocated a programme of industrialization which also proposed [[agricultural cooperatives]] and the formation of collective farms on a [[volunteering|voluntary]] basis.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Kemp |first1=Tom |title=Industrialisation in the Non-Western World |date=14 January 2014 |publisher=Routledge |isbn=978-1-317-90133-4 |pages=1–150 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=rjWtAgAAQBAJ&dq=trotsky+progressive+tax+left+opposition&pg=PT67 |language=en}}</ref> Several scholars have argued that the economic programme of Trotsky differed from the forced [[Stalinism|policy of collectivisation]] implemented by Stalin after 1928 due to the levels of brutality associated with its enforcement.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Mandel |first1=Ernest |title=Trotsky as alternative |date=1995 |publisher=[[Verso Books]] |location=London |isbn=978-1859840856 |page=59}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Daniels |first1=Robert V. |title=The Rise and Fall of Communism in Russia |date=1 October 2008 |publisher=Yale University Press |page=195 |isbn=978-0-300-13493-3 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=27JGzAoMLjoC |language=en}}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Rubenstein |first1=Joshua |title=Leon Trotsky : a revolutionary's life |date=2011 |publisher=New Haven : Yale University Press |isbn=978-0-300-13724-8 |page=161 |url=https://archive.org/details/leontrotskyrevol0000rube/page/160/mode/2up?q=forced+collectivization}}</ref>
Calls for greater freedom for managers to deal directly with suppliers and customers were gaining influence among reform-minded Communist cadres during the mid-1970s and 1980s were largely ignored. Following the dissolution of the Soviet Union, all of the former Soviet republics scrapped their Soviet-era systems of centralized planning and state ownership, to varying degrees, with mixed results (''see'' [[History of post-Soviet Russia]]). [[Image:GDP.jpg|thumb| [[Gross Domestic Product]] of former Soviet republics now in the region of [[Caucasia]]. Note the dramatic decrease after the breakup of the [[Soviet Union]].]]


Stalin's first Five year Plan (1929–1933) was a colossal failure. Soviet population declined after 1933, and would see modest growth until 1936.<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal|last=Hunter|first=Holland|date=1988|title=Soviet Agriculture with and without Collectivization, 1928-1940|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2498462|journal=Slavic Review|volume=47|issue=2|pages=203–216|doi=10.2307/2498462|jstor=2498462|s2cid=163882472 |issn=0037-6779}}</ref> The figures suggest a gap of about 15 million people between anticipated population and those that survived the five-year plan.<ref name=":3" /> Systemic inefficiencies plagued Soviet agriculture, such as obsolete technology, waste of fuel resources, and depreciating capital stock.<ref name=":4">{{Cite journal|last=Clairmonte|first=Frederick F.|date=1989|title=Rise and Fall of Soviet Agriculture|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/4394526|journal=Economic and Political Weekly|volume=24|issue=11|pages=555–560|jstor=4394526|issn=0012-9976}}</ref> These inefficiencies clogged the Soviet agricultural machine and reduced output. Additionally, climate greatly affected Soviet agricultural output. Many regions throughout the USSR had little rainfall, short growing seasons, low temperatures, and general extremes unsuitable for optimal agricultural production.<ref name=":2" /> This was detrimental to agricultural output and prevented cost minimization. When harvests fell short of production quotas due to a sudden frost or long drought, Soviet output could not make up the difference. Consequently, when agriculture was not producing as promised, some peasants refused to work over fear of starvation. However, since Soviet farms were collectivized, no individual grievances could be tolerated for the societal system to succeed. As a result, peasants unwilling to join ''kolkhozy'' were forced off of their land, which was then redistributed to other peasants.<ref name=":3" />
==Agriculture==
[[File:Joseph_Stalin_and_Nikita_Khrushchev,_1936.jpg|thumb|Nikita Khrushchev and Joseph Stalin, 1936]]
''Main article: [[Agriculture of the Soviet Union]].''


Following previous agricultural failures, Khrushchev abandoned Stalin's agricultural model.<ref name=":2" /> He instead looked comparatively at American agriculture through Soviet observers. He noticed that American agriculture flourished due to its specialization and interdependence on other farmers for goods and services. Similarly, Soviet farms could specialize in the crop which was best suited for growing in their region, and surplus could be transported throughout the USSR to satisfy quotas and distribute to people who needed the food. Khrushchev himself tended to suggest his favorite crops such as corn for planters.<ref name=":2" /> Paired with a need to proselytize mechanized agriculture to nearby countries, the Khrushchev administration began a campaign for an optimistic future of mechanized Soviet agriculture.<ref name=":2" /> However, Khrushchev was not able to fulfill his promises, and this contributed to his rising unpopularity which culminated in his removal from power.<ref name=":2" />
[[Agriculture]] was organized into a system of collective farms (''[[kolkhoz]]es'') and state farms (''[[sovkhoz]]es''). Organized on a large scale and highly mechanized, the Soviet Union was one of the world's leading producers of cereals, although bad harvests (as in [[1972]] and [[1975]]) necessitated imports and slowed the economy. The [[1976]]-[[1980]] five-year plan shifted resources to agriculture, and [[1978]] saw a record harvest followed by another drop in overall production in [[1979]] and [[1980]] back to levels attained in 1975. [[Cotton]], [[sugar beet]]s, [[potato]]es, and [[flax]] were also major crops.


Following Khrushchev's leadership, Soviet agriculture's legacy was defined by patchwork that attempted to fix the mistakes of the previous administrations. Crop harvests, tractors, fertilizer, and capital investment were all increasing since 1955.<ref name=":2" />  By 1965, the output of the Soviet worker was increasing, but still well below average for a developed country.<ref name=":1" /> Problems such as a scarcity of educated workers, saturation of unskilled workers and jobs made obsolete by technology, and poorly trained and educated farmers brought costs up and drove production down.<ref name=":1" /> These issues prevented the Soviet Union from producing enough food, as a lack of administration and management led to the mismanagement of farms and reduced worker productivity. From 1972 to 1986, the Soviet Union failed to produce more wheat than the Western European average.<ref name=":4" /> This failure to produce resulted in forced Soviet imports of food. Between 1961 and 1985, Soviet food imports from foreign producers cost a total of nearly 152 billion dollars.<ref name=":4" /> The root of this expense can be identified in the inefficiencies of the Soviet agricultural sector, such as the shortage of workers, lag in technology, or natural factors such as drought or frosts. Although the Soviet Union aimed to establish a mechanized agricultural giant, the shortcomings of Soviet agriculture put the sector behind other countries from the beginning. Soviet agriculture had the inability to meet basic consumer demands and expectations, requiring policy change culminating in the dissolution of the USSR in 1991.<ref name=":4" />
However, despite immense land resources, extensive machinery and chemical industries, and a large rural work force, Soviet agriculture was relatively unproductive, hampered in many areas by the [[climate]] (only 10 percent of the Soviet Union's land was arable), and poor worker productivity since the [[collectivisation in the USSR|collectivization]] in the 1930s. Lack of transport infrastructure also caused much waste.


==Foreign trade and currency==
== Foreign trade and currency ==
{{main|Foreign trade of the Soviet Union}}
{{main|Foreign trade of the Soviet Union}}
Largely self-sufficient, the Soviet Union traded little in comparison to its economic strength. However, trade with noncommunist countries increased in the [[1970s]] as the government sought to compensate gaps in domestic production with imports.
Largely self-sufficient, the Soviet Union traded little in comparison to its economic strength. However, trade with non-communist countries increased in the 1970s as the government sought to compensate gaps in domestic production with imports.


In general, [[fuel]]s, [[metal]]s, and [[timber]] were exported. [[Machinery]], [[consumer goods]], and sometimes [[cereal|grain]] were imported. In the [[1980]]s trade with the [[Council for Mutual Economic Assistance]] (COMECON) member states accounted for about half the country's volume of trade. Although often associated with alcohol production, such as that of [[vodka]], none of these were leading Soviet exports.
In general, [[fuel]]s, [[metal]]s and [[timber]] were exported, while [[consumer goods]] and sometimes [[cereal|grain]] were imported. In the 1980s, trade with the [[Council for Mutual Economic Assistance]] (COMECON) member states accounted for about half the country's volume of trade.


The Soviet currency (ruble) was non-convertible after 1932 (when trade in gold-convertible "[[chervonets]]", introduced by Lenin in NEP years was suspended) until the late eighties. It was impossible (both for citizens and state-owned businesses) to freely buy or sell foreign currency even though the "exchange rate" was set and published regularly.
The Soviet rouble was non-convertible after 1932 (when trade in gold-convertible [[chervonets]], introduced by Lenin in the [[New Economic Policy]] years, was suspended) until the late 1980s. It was impossible (both for citizens and state-owned businesses) to freely buy or sell foreign currency even though the "exchange rate" was set and published regularly. Buying or selling foreign currency on a black market was a serious crime until the late 1980s. Individuals who were paid from abroad (for example writers whose books were published abroad) normally had to spend their currency in a foreign-currency-only chain of state-owned [[Beryozka (Russian retail store)|Beryozka]] ("Birch-tree") stores. Once a free conversion of currency was allowed, the exchange rate plummeted from its official values by almost a factor of 10.
Buying or selling foreign currency on a black market was a serious crime until the late eighties. Individuals who were paid from abroad (for example writers whose books were published abroad) normally had to spend their currency in a foreign-currency-only chain of state-owned "[[Beryozka]]" ("Birch-tree") stores. Once a free conversion of currency was allowed, the exchange rate plummeted from its official values by almost a factor of 10.


Overall, the banking system was highly centralized and fully controlled by a single state-owned [[Gosbank]], responsive to the fulfillment of the government's economic plans. Soviet [[bank]]s furnished short-term credit to state-owned enterprises.
Overall, the banking system was highly centralized and fully controlled by a single state-owned [[Gosbank]], responsive to the fulfillment of the government's economic plans. Soviet [[bank]]s furnished short-term credit to state-owned enterprises.


== Forms of property ==
== Forms of property ==
There were two basic forms of property in the Soviet Union: individual property and collective property. These differed greatly in their content and legal status. According to communist theory, capital ([[means of production]]) should not be individually owned, with certain negligible exceptions. In particular, after the end of a short period of the [[New Economic Policy]] and with [[Collectivisation in the USSR|collectivization]] completed, all industrial property and virtually all land were collective.


Land in rural areas was allotted for housing and some sustenance farming, and persons had certain rights to it, but it was not their property in full. In particular, in [[kolkhoz]]es and [[sovkhoz]]es there was a practice to rotate individual farming lots with collective lots. This resulted in situations where people would [[Land improvement|ameliorate]], till and cultivate their lots carefully, adapting them to small-scale farming and in 5–7 years those lots would be swapped for kolkhoz ones, typically with exhausted soil due to intensive, large-scale agriculture.{{citation needed|date=January 2020}} There was an extremely small number of remaining individual [[farmstead]]s (''[[khutor]]s''; хутор), located in isolated rural areas in the [[Baltic state]]s, [[Ukraine]], [[Siberia]] and [[cossack]] lands.
There were two basic forms of property in the Soviet Union: individual property and collective property. These differed greatly in their content and legal status. According to communist theory, capital ([[means of production]]) could not be individually owned, with certain negligible exceptions. In particular, after the end of a short period of the [[New Economic Policy]] and with [[Collectivisation in the USSR|collectivization]] completed, all industrial property and virtually all land were collective.

Land in rural areas was allotted for housing and some sustenance farming, and persons had certain rights to it, but it was not their property in full. In particular, in [[kolkhoz]]es and [[sovkhoz]]es there was a practice to rotate individual farming lots with collective lots. This resulted in situations where people would [[Land improvement|ameliorate]], till and cultivate their lots carefully, adapting them to small-scale farming, and in 5-7 years those lots would be swapped for kolkhoz ones, typically with exhausted soil due to intensive, large-scale agriculture. There was an extremely small number of remaining individual [[farmstead]]s (''[[khutor]]s'' хутор), located in isolated rural areas in the [[Baltic state]]s, [[Ukraine]], [[Siberia]] and [[cossack]] lands.


=== Individual property ===
=== Individual property ===
To distinguish "capitalist" and "socialist" types of property ownership further, two different forms of individual property were recognized: private property (частная собственность, ''chastnaya sobstvennost'') and personal property (личная собственность, ''lichnaya sobstvennost''). The former encompassed capital (means of production) while the latter described everything else in a person's possession.

To distinguish "capitalist" and "socialist" types of property ownership further, two different forms of individual property were recognized: ''private property'' (''частная собственность'', chastnaya sobstvennost) and ''personal property'' (''личная собственность'', lichnaya sobstvennost). The former encompassed capital (means of production), while the latter described everything else in a person's possession. This distinction has been a source of confusion when interpreting phrases such as ''"socialism (communism) abolished private property"''; one might conclude that all individual property was abolished, when this was in fact not the case.


=== Collective property ===
=== Collective property ===
There were several forms of collective ownership, the most significant being state property, ''kolkhoz'' property and cooperative property. The most common forms of cooperative property were housing cooperatives (жилищные кооперативы) in urban areas, consumer cooperatives (потребительская кооперация, потребкооперация) and rural consumer societies (сельские потребительские общества, сельпо).


== History ==
There were several forms of collective ownership, the most significant being ''state property'', ''kolkhoz property'', and ''cooperative property''.
[[File:GDP per capita development of the Soviet Union.svg|thumb|GDP per capita in the former USSR, 1922 to 1991]]
''See also [[History of the Soviet Union]]''


=== Early development ===
The most common forms of cooperative property were ''housing cooperatives'' (жилищные кооперативы) in urban areas, ''consumer cooperatives'' (потребительская кооперация, потребкооперация), and ''rural consumer societies'' (сельские потребительские общества, сельпо).
Both the [[Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic]] and later the [[Soviet Union]] were countries in the process of [[industrialization]]. For both, this development occurred slowly and from a low initial starting-point. Because of [[World War I]] (1914–1918), the [[Russian Revolution (1917)|Russian Revolution]] of 1917 and the ensuing [[Russian Civil War]] (1917–1922), industrial production had only managed to barely recover its 1913 level by 1926.<ref>Dyker 1992, p. 2.</ref> By this time, about 18% of the population lived in non-rural areas, although only about 7.5% were employed in the non-agricultural sector. The remainder remained stuck in [[marginal product of labor|low-productivity]] agriculture.<ref name="industrialization"/>


[[David A. Dyker]] sees the Soviet Union of circa 1930 as in some ways a typical developing country, characterized by low capital-investment and with most of its population residing in the countryside. Part of the reason{{citation needed|date=October 2015}} for low investment-rates lay in the inability to acquire capital from abroad. This in turn, resulted from the [[Sovereign default|repudiation]] of the debts of the [[Russian Empire]] by the [[Bolsheviks]] in 1918<ref>{{cite book|editor1-last=Rempel|editor1-first=Richard A.|editor2-last=Haslam|editor2-first=Beryl|title=Uncertain Paths to Freedom: Russia and China, 1919–22|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=qnaqY4gUyrAC|series=Collected papers of Bertrand Russell|volume=15|publisher=Psychology Press|date=2000|page=529|isbn=9780415094115|access-date =18 October 2015|quote=French creditors were owed forty-three percent of the total Russian debt repudiated by the Bolsheviks on 28 January 1918.}}</ref> as well as from the worldwide financial troubles. Consequently, any kind of economic growth had to be financed by domestic savings.<ref name="industrialization">{{cite book|last1=Dyker|first1=David A.|year=1992|title=Restructuring the Soviet Economy|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=uUWIAgAAQBAJ|publisher=Routledge|publication-date=2002|page=3|isbn=9781134917464|access-date=18 October 2015|quote =Repudiation of the international debts of the tsarist regime, coupled with the difficult economic conditions of the post-Wall Street crash period, ensured that any increase in the rate of accumulation would have to be internally financed. [...] In some ways, then, the Soviet Union ''c''. 1930 was a typical developing country, with a relatively low level of accumulation and substantial surplus agricultural population. But she could not count on large-scale capital transfer from abroad – for better or worse.}}</ref>
==Further reading==


The economic problems in agriculture were further exacerbated by natural conditions, such as long cold winters across the country, droughts in the south and acidic soils in the north. However, according to Dyker, the Soviet economy did have "extremely good" potential in the area of raw materials and mineral extraction, for example in the oil fields in [[Transcaucasia]], and this, along with a small but growing manufacturing base, helped the Soviet Union avoid any kind of [[balance of payments]] problems.<ref name="industrialization"/><!-- I've stolen this four-period division from Davies, pp 3, 4: https://books.google.com/books?id=mNffDWnt25wC&pg=PA3
* Paul Gregory and Robert Stuart, ''Soviet and Post Soviet Economic Structure and Performance'' 7th edition (Boston: Addison Wesley, 2001).
== Tsarist economy ==
* [[Marshall Goldman]], ''What Went Wrong With Perestroika'' (New York: Norton, 1991).
== War Communism (1918–1920) ==
* Marshall Goldman, ''Lost Opportunity: Why Economic Reforms in Russia Have Not Worked'' (New York: W. W. Norton, 1994).
=== New Economic Policy (1921–1929) ===
* Moshe Lewin, ''The Making of the Soviet System'' (New Press, 1994)
== Administrative economy (early 1930s–1991) == -->
* Mary McCauley, ''Soviet Politics 1917-1991'' (Oxford University Press, 1992).


=== New Economic Policy (1921–1929) ===
==See also==
{{main|New Economic Policy}}
[[File:Lenin and stalin crop.jpg|thumb|180px|One of the several photographs<ref>[https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:19220900-lenin_stalin_gorky-02.jpg Lenin and Stalin in Gorki] ([https://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:19220901-lenin_stalin_at_gorki.jpg close up])</ref> intended to show the two major economic policy makers of the Soviet Union together, [[Vladimir Lenin]] (left) who created the [[New Economic Policy|NEP]] and [[Joseph Stalin]] (right) who created the [[Soviet-type economic planning|command economy]]]]
By early 1921, it became apparent to the Bolsheviks that forced requisitioning of grain had resulted in low agricultural production and widespread opposition. As a result, the decision was made by Lenin and the Politburo to try an alternative approach.{{sfn|Moss|2005|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=yMwdWFtgV0QC&pg=PA228 228]}} The so-called [[New Economic Policy]] (NEP) was approved at the [[10th Congress of the Russian Communist Party (Bolsheviks)]].<ref>{{cite book |last1=Hosking |first1=Geoffrey A. |title=The First Socialist Society: A History of the Soviet Union from Within |date=1993 |publisher=Harvard University Press |isbn=978-0-674-30443-7 |page=119 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=l9wbbiJV5WkC |access-date=24 March 2022 |language=en}}</ref>


Everything except "the commanding heights", as Lenin put it, of the economy would be [[privatized]]. The commanding heights included [[foreign trade]], [[heavy industry]], [[communication]] and [[transport]] among others.{{sfn|Moss|2005|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=yMwdWFtgV0QC&pg=PA228 228]}} In practice this limited the [[private sector]] to artisan and agricultural production/trade.<ref name="Carr and Davies, 1988">Carr, E.H. and Davies, R.W, (1988), Foundations of a Planned Economy, Vol. 1</ref> The NEP encountered strong resistance within the Bolshevik party. Lenin had to persuade communist skeptics that "[[state capitalism]]" was a necessary step in achieving [[communism]], while he himself harbored suspicions that the policy could be abused by private businessmen ("[[NEPmen]]").{{sfn|Moss|2005|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=yMwdWFtgV0QC&pg=PA227 227]}}
* [[Economy of Russia|Economy of post-Soviet Russia]]

* [[History of the Soviet Union]]
As [[novelist]] [[Andrei Platonov]], among others, noted, the improvements were immediate. Rationing cards and queues, which had become [[hallmark]]s of [[war communism]], had disappeared. However, due to prolonged war, low harvests, and several natural disasters the Soviet economy was still in trouble, particularly its agricultural sector. In 1921, [[Russian famine of 1921|widespread famine]] broke out in the [[Volga-Ural region]]. The Soviet government changed its previous course and allowed international relief to come in from abroad, and established a special committee chaired by prominent communists and non-communists alike. Despite this, an estimated five million people died in the famine.{{sfn|Hosking|1993|page=120}}
* [[History of post-Soviet Russia]]

*[[Enterprises in the Soviet Union]]
=== Armenian Soviet Socialist Republic ===
The Soviet-era republic's centralized economy forbade private ownership of property with an income. Privately owned farms in Armenia were collectivized and put under the control of the state starting in the late 1920s, however this was frequently met with vigorous opposition by the peasantry. During the same period (1929–1936), Armenia's industrialization process was also launched by the government. The socialist economic system and socialist ownership of the means of production, which come in two forms: state property and cooperative and collective-farm property, form the basis of the republic's economy. The legislation authorizes small private ventures of individual peasants and craftsmen based on their own labor and forbids the exploitation of the labor of others, in addition to the socialist system of economy, which is the major type of economy in the Republic. The official economic plan sets and directs the Republic's economic course. By 1935, the gross product of agriculture was 132% higher than that of 1928, and the gross product of industry was 650% more than that of 1928. However, the 1930s economic revolution came at a high price: it destroyed the conventional peasant family and village institution and caused many people who lived in the remote countryside to relocate to cities. As private enterprise was essentially brought under government control, it came to an end.<ref>{{cite web | url=https://evnreport.com/raw-unfiltered/armenian-attitudes-toward-work-and-the-soviet-legacy/ | title=Armenian Attitudes Toward Work and the Soviet Legacy | date=18 April 2022 }}</ref>

=== Stalinism ===
{{further|History of the Soviet Union (1927–1953)}}
Starting in 1928, the five-year plans began building a heavy industrial base at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry, and without reliance on external financing. The New Economic Policy was [[Great Break (USSR)|rapidly abandoned]] and replaced by [[Stalinism]]. The country now became industrialized at a hitherto unprecedented pace, surpassing [[Germany]]'s pace of industrialization in the 19th century and [[Japan]]'s earlier in the 20th century.

After the reconstruction of the economy in the wake of the destruction caused by the [[Russian Civil War]] was completed and after the initial plans of further [[Industrialization in the USSR|industrialization]] were fulfilled, the explosive growth slowed down until the period of [[Brezhnev stagnation]] in the 1970s and 1980s.

Trotsky maintained that the disproportions and imbalances which became characteristic of Stalinist planning in the 1930s such as the underdeveloped [[consumer base]] along with the priority focus on [[heavy industry]] were due to a number of avoidable problems. He argued that the industrial drive had been enacted under more severe circumstances, several years later and in a less rational manner than proposal originally conceived by the Left Opposition.<ref>{{cite book |last1=Deutscher |first1=Isaac |title=The Prophet: The Life of Leon Trotsky |date=5 January 2015 |publisher=Verso Books |isbn=978-1-78168-721-5 |page=1141|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=YGznDwAAQBAJ&q=isaac+deutscher+trotsky+the+prophet |language=en}}</ref>

Led by the creation of [[NAMI (car company)|NAMI]] and by the [[GAZ]] copy of the [[Ford Model A (1927–1931)|Ford Model A]] in 1929,<ref>[[G.N. Georgano]] ''Cars: Early and Vintage, 1886–1930''. (London: Grange-Universal, 1985)</ref><ref>Wikipedia, [[GAZ]].</ref>{{Circular reference|date=April 2017}} industrialization came with the extension of medical services, which improved labor [[Productivity (economics)|productivity]]. Campaigns were carried out against [[typhus]], [[cholera]] and [[malaria]]; the number of physicians increased as rapidly as facilities and training would permit; and death and [[infant mortality]] rates steadily decreased.

In 1947 [[politburo]] announced a [[Monetary reform in the Soviet Union, 1947|monetary reform (1947)]] that basically intended to confiscate "excessive" amount of money in order to weaken rampant illegal trade (which was banned at the time) and fill up budget at cost of people.

[[Ration stamp]]s in Soviet Union were abolished in December 1947, six months after rationing ended in the US, and two years before France. [[Soviet famine of 1946–1947|Soviet post-war famine of 1946–1947]] was still ravaging the country.

=== 1930–1970 ===
{{further|Soviet industry in World War II|Soviet combat vehicle production during World War II}}
[[File:Znak kachestva.svg|thumb|left|100px|The [[State quality mark of the USSR|State Quality Mark of the Soviet Union]], introduced in 1967, was used to certify that goods met quality standards and to improve the efficiency of production.]]
As weighed growth rates, economic planning performed very well during the early and mid-1930s, [[World War II]]-era mobilization, and for the first two decades of the postwar era. The Soviet Union became the world's leading producer of [[Petroleum|oil]], [[coal]], [[iron ore]] and [[cement]]; [[manganese]], [[gold]], [[natural gas]] and other [[minerals]] were also of major importance. However, information about the [[Soviet famine of 1932–1933]] was suppressed by the Soviet authorities until [[perestroika]].

To some estimations, in 1933 workers' real earnings sank on more than 11.4% from 1926 level,<ref>{{citation|first=Alec|last=Nove|title=An Economic History of the U.S.S.R.|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=vyX6PH0NYScC&pg=PA206|year=1969|publisher=IICA|page=206}}</ref> though it needs an adjustment due to elimination of unemployment and perks at work (such as inexpensive meals).<ref>{{harvnb|Nove|1969|p=207}}</ref> Common and political prisoners in labor camps were forced to do unpaid labor and communists and [[Komsomol]] members were frequently "mobilized" for various construction projects. The German invasion of World War II inflicted punishing blows to the economy of the Soviet Union, with Soviet GDP falling 34% between 1940 and 1942.{{sfn|Harrison|1996|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=yJcD7_Q_rQ8C&pg=PA124 p. 124]}}<!-- The war effort swallowed nearly 60% of Soviet GDP in 1942 *** Will add more soon, don't snip it yet. ColaXtra, 1 November 2012 **** --> Industrial output did not recover to its 1940 level for almost a decade.{{sfn|Davies|1998|p=[https://books.google.com/books?id=mNffDWnt25wC&pg=PA2 2]}}

In 1961, a new redenominated [[Soviet rouble]] was issued with an exchange rate of [[Pound sterling|£]]1 = Rbl&nbsp;1. The rouble maintained exchange parity with sterling until the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991. After a new leadership, headed by [[Leonid Brezhnev]], had come to power, attempts were made to revitalize the economy through [[1965 Soviet economic reform|economic reform]]. Starting in 1965, enterprises and organizations were made to rely on economic methods of profitable production, rather than follow orders from the state administration. By 1970, the Soviet economy had reached its zenith and was estimated at 60 percent of the size of the United States<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.foia.cia.gov/sites/default/files/document_conversions/89801/DOC_0000497165.pdf|title=A Comparison of the US and Soviet Economies: Evaluating the Performance of the Soviet System|work=foia.cia.gov|date=October 1985|access-date=7 April 2015|archive-date=4 March 2016|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304052208/http://www.foia.cia.gov/sites/default/files/document_conversions/89801/DOC_0000497165.pdf|url-status=dead}}</ref> in terms of the estimated commodities (like steel and coal). In 1989, the official GDP of the Soviet Union was $2,500 billion<ref>[http://www.theodora.com/wfb1989/soviet_union/soviet_union_economy.html "Soviet Union Economy - 1989"].</ref> while the GDP of the United States was $4,862 billion<ref>[http://www.theodora.com/wfb1989/united_states/united_states_economy.html "United States Economy - 1989"]</ref> with per capita income figures as $8,700 and $19,800 respectively.

The USSR was the first major non-Western country to close the developmental gap that had existed with the West since the 16th century.<ref name=":5">{{Cite book |last=Gnerre |first=Orazio Maria |url= |title=China and Eurasian powers in a Multipolar World Order 2.0: Security, Diplomacy, Economy and Cyberspace |date=2023 |publisher=[[Routledge]] |others=Mher Sahakyan |isbn=978-1-003-35258-7 |edition= |location=New York |chapter=Strengthening of the Sino-Russian Partnership |oclc=1353290533}}</ref>{{Rp|page=52}} In the period 1930 to 1960s, the USSR successfully implemented catch-up development.<ref name=":5" />{{Rp|page=52}}

=== 1970–1990 ===
{{further|Era of Stagnation|History of the Soviet Union (1964–1982)|History of the Soviet Union (1982–1991)}}
After 1976, the USSR stopped narrowing the developmental gap with the West, and the gap further widened beginning in 1990.<ref name=":5" />{{Rp|page=52}}

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles ($530 billion).<ref>[https://books.google.com/books?id=VV2irCX9gtgnfAC&dq=ussr+output+ruble&pg=PA36 Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972]</ref> The [[Era of Stagnation]] in the mid-1970s was triggered by the [[Nixon Shock]] and aggravated by the [[Soviet–Afghan War|war in Afghanistan]] in 1979 and led to a period of economic standstill between 1979 and 1985. Soviet military buildup at the expense of domestic development kept the Soviet Union's GDP at the same level during the first half of the 1980s.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.cia.gov/library/readingroom/docs/DOC_0000380724.pdf|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160920014857/https://www.cia.gov/library/readingroom/docs/DOC_0000380724.pdf|url-status=dead|archive-date=20 September 2016|title=The Economic Impact of Soviet Military Spending|date=April 1975|website=www.cia.gov|page=2|access-date=2018-12-09}}</ref> According to American journalist [[Scott Shane]], the massive quantities of goods produced often did not meet the needs or tastes of consumers.<ref name="ScottChapter3">{{cite book|last=Shane|first=Scott|title=Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union|year=1994|publisher=Ivan R. Dee|location=Chicago|isbn=978-1-56663-048-1|pages=75 to 98|chapter=What Price Socialism? An Economy Without Information|quote=It was not the gas pedal but the steering wheel that was failing}}</ref>

The volume of decisions facing planners in Moscow became overwhelming. The cumbersome procedures for bureaucratic administration foreclosed the free communication and flexible response required at the enterprise level for dealing with worker alienation, innovation, customers, and suppliers. During 1975–1985, data fiddling became common practice among bureaucracy to report satisfied targets and quotas thus entrenching the crisis. At the same time, the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the [[second economy in the Soviet Union]].<ref name="treadle" />

[[File:Graph of Soviet National Income Growth.png|thumb|350px|Soviet national income 1928–1987 growth in % based on estimates of the official statistical agency of the Soviet Union, the CIA and revised estimates by [[Grigorii Khanin]]]]
While all modernized economies were rapidly moving to computerization after 1965, the Soviet Union fell further and further behind. Even though Moscow decided to copy the IBM 360 of 1965, it had enormous difficulties in manufacturing the necessary chips reliably and in quantity, in programming workable and efficient programs, in coordinating entirely separate operations, and in providing support to computer users.<ref>James W. Cortada, "Public Policies and the Development of National Computer Industries in Britain, France, and the Soviet Union, 1940—80." ''Journal of Contemporary History'' (2009) 44#3 pp: 493–512, especially page 509-10.</ref><ref>Frank Cain, "Computers and the Cold War: United States restrictions on the export of computers to the Soviet Union and Communist China." ''Journal of Contemporary History'' (2005) 40#1 pp: 131–147. [https://www.jstor.org/stable/30036313 in JSTOR]</ref><ref>{{cite book|first=Bruce|last=Parrott|title=Trade, Technology, and Soviet-American Relations|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_MMSoIbbnzcC&pg=PA10|year=1985|publisher=Indiana UP|pages=10–12|isbn=978-0253360250}}</ref>

One of the greatest strengths of Soviet economy was its vast supplies of oil and gas; world oil prices quadrupled in the 1973–1974 and rose again in 1979–1981, making the energy sector the chief driver of the Soviet economy, and was used to cover multiple weaknesses. At one point, Soviet Premier [[Alexei Kosygin]] told the head of oil and gas production that "things are bad with bread. Give me 3 million tons [of oil] over the plan".<ref>Yergin, ''The Quest'' (2011) p 23</ref>

In 2007, economist and former [[Prime Minister of Russia|Prime Minister]] [[Yegor Gaidar]] wrote the following about looking back to these three decades: {{blockquote|The hard currency from oil exports stopped the growing food supply crisis, increased the import of equipment and consumer goods, ensured a financial base for the arms race and the achievement of nuclear parity with the United States, and permitted the realization of such risky foreign-policy actions as the war in Afghanistan.<ref>{{cite book|first=Yegor|last=Gaidar|title=Collapse of an Empire: Lessons for Modern Russia|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bDSfnxYjVwAC&pg=PA102|date= 2007|publisher=Brookings Institution Press|page=102|isbn=978-0815731153}}</ref>}}

Awareness of the growing crisis arose initially within the KGB which with its extensive network of informants in every region and institution had its finger on the pulse of the nation. [[Yuri Andropov]], director of the KGB, created a secret department during the 1970s within the KGB devoted to economic analysis and when he succeeded Brezhnev in 1982 sounded the alarm forcefully to the Soviet leadership. However, Andropov's remedy of increased discipline proved ineffective. It was only when Andropov's protege Gorbachev assumed power that a determined, but ultimately unsuccessful, assault on the economic crisis was undertaken.<ref name=ScottChapter4>{{cite book|last=Shane|first=Scott|title=Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union|year=1994|publisher=Ivan R. Dee|location=Chicago|isbn=978-1-56663-048-1|pages=59, 60, 99 to 120|chapter=The KGB, Father of Perestroika|quote=When he spoke to the leadership circle he said the country was faced with a question of survival}}</ref>

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1990 in retail prices was about 459 billion roubles ($2.1 trillion).<ref>{{cite book|author1=United States. Congress. Joint Economic Committee|author2=John Pearce Hardt|title=The Former Soviet Union in Transition|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=JSwstF6SEAkC&pg=PA495|year=1993|publisher=M.E. Sharpe|isbn=978-1-56324-318-9|page=495}}</ref> According to CIA estimates, by 1989 the size of the Soviet economy was roughly half that in the United States.<ref name="cia1990"/>

{|class="wikitable"
|-
! Sector (distribution of Soviet workforce) !! 1940 !! 1965 !! 1970 !! 1979 !! 1984
|-
| '''Primary''' (agriculture and forestry) || 54% || 31% || 25% || 21% || 20%
|-
| '''Secondary''' (including construction, transport and communication) || 28% || 44% || 46% || 48% || 47%
|-
| '''Tertiary''' (including trade, finance, health, education, science and administration) || 18% || 25% || 29% || 31% || 33%
|-
| '''Total''' || 100% || 100% || 100% || 100% || 100%
|}

==Comparisons with other countries==
{| class="wikitable"
|+ GDP per capita (1990 [[Int$]]) comparison involving the area of Russia/USSR, United States, and Western Europe from 1820 to 1990<ref>{{cite book|last1=Maddison|first1=Angus|title=The World Economy|date=2006|publisher=Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD)|location=Paris, France|isbn=978-92-64-02261-4|pages=185|url=https://www.stat.berkeley.edu/~aldous/157/Papers/world_economy.pdf}}</ref>
|-
! !! Russia/USSR !! United States !! Western Europe !! Russia/USSR as a % of United States !! Russia/USSR as a % of Western Europe
|-
| '''1820''' || 689 || 1,257 || 1,232 || 55 || 56
|-
| '''1870''' || 943 || 2,445 || 1,974 || 39 || 48
|-
| '''1913''' || 1,488 || 5,301 || 3,473 || 28 || 43
|-
| '''1950''' || 2,834 || 9,561 || 4,594 || 30 || 62
|-
| '''1973''' || 6,058 || 16,689 || 11,534 || 36 || 53
|-
| '''1990''' || 9,931 || 23,214 || 15,988 || 43 || 62
|}

{|class="wikitable"
|+ Evolution of GNP in comparison with European powers<br>(in millions of dollars of 1960)
|-
! Country !! 1890 !! 1900 !! 1913 !! 1925 !! 1938
|-
| '''Russia/Soviet Union''' || 21,180 || 32,000 || 52,420 || 32,600 || 75,964
|-
| '''Germany''' || 26,454 || 35,800 || 49,760 || 45,002 || 77,178
|-
| '''United Kingdom''' || 29,441 || 36,273 || 44,074 || 43,700 || 56,102
|-
| '''France''' || 19,758 || 23,500 || 27,401 || 36,262 || 39,284
|}

{|class="wikitable"
|+ Comparison between the economies of the Soviet Union and the United States (1989) according to 1990 [[CIA World Factbook]] data<ref name=cia1990>{{cite web|url=http://www.umsl.edu/services/govdocs/wofact90/world12.txt|publisher=[[Central Intelligence Agency]]|access-date=23 July 2010|title=1990 CIA World Factbook|archive-date=27 April 2011|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110427053700/http://www.umsl.edu/services/govdocs/wofact90/world12.txt|url-status=dead}}</ref>
|-
! !! Soviet Union !! United States
|-
| '''GDP (GNP) (1989; millions $)''' || 2,659,500 || 5,233,300
|-
| '''Population (July 1990)''' || 290,938,469 || 250,410,000
|-
| '''GDP per capita (GNP) ($)''' || 9,931 || 21,082
|-
| '''Labor force (1989)''' || 152,300,000 || 125,557,000
|-
|}

== See also ==
{{colbegin}}
* [[Economy of Russia]]
* [[Second economy of the Soviet Union]]
* [[1965 Soviet economic reform]]
* [[1973 Soviet economic reform]]
* [[1979 Soviet economic reform]]
* {{section link|Bibliography of the Russian Revolution and Civil War|Economy}}
* {{section link|Bibliography of Stalinism and the Soviet Union|Economy}}
* {{section link|Bibliography of the Post Stalinist Soviet Union|Economy}}
* [[Banking in the Soviet Union]]
* [[Bureaucratic collectivism]]
* [[Command economy|Administrative command economy]]
* [[Eastern Bloc economies]]
* [[Enterprises in the Soviet Union]]
* [[Five-year plans of the Soviet Union|Five-year plans]]
* [[Forced labor in the Soviet Union]]
* [[Gosplan|State Planning Committee]]
* [[Material balance planning]]
* [[Ministry of Finance (Soviet Union)|Soviet Ministry of Finance]]
* {{annotated link|New Soviet man}}
* [[Primitive socialist accumulation]]
* [[Soviet-type economic planning]]
* [[State capitalism]]
* [[State socialism]]
* [[Trade unions in the Soviet Union]]
{{colend}}


== References ==
== References ==
{{reflist|30em}}
* ''Soviet Civilization: from the great victory till our time'', [[S. Kara-Murza]], 2004.
* ''The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers'', [[Paul Kennedy]], Random House, New York, 1987.


=== Works cited ===
==External links==
{{refbegin}}
* {{cite book|last=Allen|first=Robert C.|author-link=Robert C. Allen|year=2003|title=Farm to Factory: A Reinterpretation of the Soviet Industrial Revolution|location=Princeton, NJ|publisher=[[Princeton University Press]]}}
* {{cite book|last=Boughton|first=James M.|year=2012|title=Tearing Down Walls: The International Monetary Fund, 1990–1999|url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/history/2012/index.htm|location=Washington, D.C.|publisher=[[International Monetary Fund]]|isbn=978-1-616-35084-0}}
* {{cite book|last=Bradley|first=Mark Philip|year=2010|chapter=Decolonization, the global South, and the Cold War, 1919–1962|title=''In Melvyn P. Leffler and Odd Arne Westad, eds., ''The Cambridge History of the Cold War, Volume 1: Origins'' (pp. 464–485)''|location=Cambridge|publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]|isbn=978-0-521-83719-4}}
* {{cite book|last=Davies|first=R.W.|author-link=Robert William Davies|year=1998|title=Soviet Economic Development from Lenin to Khrushchev|location=Cambridge|publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]}}
* {{cite book|last=Harrison|first=Mark|year=1996|title=Accounting for War: Soviet Production, Employment, and the Defense Burden, 1940–1945|location=Cambridge|publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]}}
* {{cite book|last=Moss|first=Walter Gerald|year=2005|title=A History Of Russia, Volume 2: Since 1855|edition=2nd|location=London|publisher=Anthem Press}}
* {{cite book|last=Peck|first=James|year=2006|title= Washington's China: The National Security World, the Cold War, and the Origins of Globalism|location=Amherst, MA|publisher=[[University of Massachusetts Press]]}}
* {{cite journal|last=Smolinski|first=Leon|year=1973|title=Karl Marx and Mathematical Economics|journal=[[Journal of Political Economy]]|volume=81|number=5|pages=1189–1204|jstor=1830645|doi=10.1086/260113|s2cid=154938992}}
{{refend}}


== Further reading ==
* [http://www.hubbertpeak.com/reynolds/SovietDecline.htm Douglas B. Reynolds, "Soviet Economic Decline: Did an Oil Crisis Cause the Transition in the Soviet Union?"]
{{refbegin}}
* [http://faculty.washington.edu/aseem/afganwar.pdf Rafael Reuveny and Aseem Prakash, "The Afghanistan war and the breakdown of the Soviet Union," Review of International Studies, 25 (1999), 25, 693-708].
* Autio-Sarasmo, Sari. "Technological Modernisation in the Soviet Union and Post-Soviet Russia: Practices and Continuities." ''Europe-Asia Studies'' 68.1 (2016): 79–96.
* [http://rrojasdatabank.info/agfrank/what_went_wrong.html Andre Gunder Frank, "What Went Wrong in the 'Socialist' East?"]
* Bergson, Abram. ''The real national income of Soviet Russia since 1928'' (1961)
* [http://www.unitedhumanrights.org/Genocide/Ukraine_famine.htm "The five year plan and its effect on famine in Ukraine."]
* Connolly, Richard. ''The Russian Economy: A Very Short Introduction'' (Oxford University Press, 2020). [https://eh.net/book_reviews/the-russian-economy-a-very-short-introduction/ Online review]
* {{cite book|last=Daniels|first=Robert Vince|year=1993|title=The End of the Communist Revolution|location=London|publisher=[[Routledge]]}}
* Davies, R. W. ''Soviet economic development from Lenin to Khrushchev'' (1998) [https://www.amazon.com/Economic-Development-Khrushchev-Studies-History-dp-0521622603/dp/0521622603/ excerpt]
* Davies, R. W. ed. ''From Tsarism to the New Economic Policy: Continuity and Change in the Economy of the USSR'' (London, 1990).
* Davies, R. W. ed. ''The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945'' (Cambridge, 1994).
* Goldman, Marshall (1994). ''Lost Opportunity: Why Economic Reforms in Russia Have Not Worked''. New York: W. W. Norton.
* {{cite book|author-link1=Paul Roderick Gregory|last1=Gregory|first1=Paul|last2=Stuart|first2=Robert|year=2001|title=Soviet and Post Soviet Economic Structure and Performance|edition=7th|location=Boston|publisher=Addison Wesley}}
* Gregory, Paul, and Mark Harrison. 2005. "Allocation under Dictatorship: Research in Stalin's Archives." ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 43 (3): 721–761.
* Harrison, Mark. "The Soviet Union after 1945: Economic Recovery and Political Repression," ''Past & Present'' (2011 Supplement 6) Vol. 210 Issue suppl_6, p.&nbsp;103–120.
* [[Marshall Goldman|Goldman, Marshall]] (1991). ''What Went Wrong With Perestroika''. New York: W. W. Norton.
* [[Paul Kennedy|Kennedy, Paul]]. ''[[The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers]]'' (New York: Random House, 1987).
* {{cite journal|author=Laird, Robbin F.|title=Soviet Arms Trade with the Noncommunist Third World |journal=Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science|year=1984|volume=35|issue=3|pages=196–213|doi=10.2307/1174128|jstor=1174128}}
* Moser, Nat. ''Oil and the Economy of Russia: From the Late-Tsarist to the Post-Soviet Period'' (Routledge, 2017).
* [[Alec Nove|Nove, Alec]]. ''An Economic History of the USSR, 1917–1991''. (3rd ed. 1993) [https://archive.org/details/economichistoryo00nove online free to borrow]
* Ofer, Gur. "Soviet Economic Growth: 1928-1985," ''Journal of Economic Literature'' (1987) 25#4: 1767–1833. [https://www.jstor.org/stable/2726445 online]
* {{cite book|last=Pravda|first=Alex|chapter=The collapse of the Soviet Union, 1990–1991|year=2010|editor1-last=Leffler|editor1-first=Melvyn P.|editor1-link=Melvyn P. Leffler|editor2-last=Westad|editor2-first=Odd Arne|editor2-link=Odd Arne Westad|title=The Cambridge History of the Cold War, Volume 3: Findings|location=Cambridge|publisher=[[Cambridge University Press]]|pages=356–377}}
* Rutland, Robert (1985). ''The Myth of the Plan: Lessons of Soviet Planning Experience''. London: Hutchinson.
* Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina, Sergei Guriev, and Andrei Markevich. 2024. "New Russian Economic History." ''Journal of Economic Literature'', 62 (1): 47–114.


=== In Russian ===
* [[Sergey Kara-Murza|Kara-Murza, Sergey]] (2004). ''Soviet Civilization: From 1917 to the Great Victory'' (in Russian) Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От начала до Великой Победы. {{ISBN|5-699-07590-9}}.
* Kara-Murza, Sergey (2004). ''Soviet Civilization: From the Great Victory Till Our Time'' (in Russian). Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От Великой Победы до наших дней. {{ISBN|5-699-07591-7}}.
{{refend}}

== External links ==
* Andre Gunder Frank. [http://rrojasdatabank.info/agfrank/what_went_wrong.html "What Went Wrong in the 'Socialist' East?"].

{{Soviet Union topics}}
{{Fall of Communism}}
{{Economic history}}
{{Economic history}}
{{Eastern Bloc economies}}
{{Economy of Europe}}


[[Category:Economy of the Soviet Union| ]]
[[Category:Economy of the Soviet Union| ]]
[[Category:Economies of former countries|Soviet Union]]
[[Category:Economies by former country|Soviet Union]]
[[Category:Former communist economies|Soviet Union]]
[[Category:Former communist economies|Soviet Union]]
[[Category:Collectivism]]

[[es:Economía de la URSS]]
[[fr:Économie de l'URSS]]
[[it:Economia dell'Unione Sovietica]]
[[he:כלכלת ברית המועצות]]
[[ja:ソビエト連邦の経済]]
[[ro:Economia Uniunii Sovietice]]

Latest revision as of 12:15, 24 December 2024

Economy of the Soviet Union
The DniproHES hydro-electric power plant, one of the symbols of Soviet economic power, was completed in 1932.
CurrencyRouble (SUR)[1]
1 January–31 December (calendar year)[1]
Trade organisations
Comecon, ESCAP and others[1]
Statistics
GDP$820 billion in 1977
(nominal; 2nd)
$1.21 trillion in 1980
(nominal; 2nd)
$1.57 trillion in 1982
(nominal; 2nd)
$2.20 trillion in 1985
(nominal; 2nd)
$2.66 trillion in 1990
(PPP; 2nd)[unreliable source?][2]
GDP rank2nd[2][3]
GDP growth
4.7% (in 1977) 4.2% ( in 1980) 3.8% (in 1982) 3.5% (in 1985) 0.9% (in 1990)
GDP per capita
$6,577 in 1977
(nominal)
$7,568 in 1980
(nominal)
$7,943 in 1982
(nominal)
$8,896 in 1985
(nominal)
$9,931 in 1991
(GNP; 28th)[4]
GDP by sector
Agriculture: (20%)
Industry: (80%)
(1988 est.)[1]
14% (43rd) (in 1991) 3.9% (in 1984)[5]
Population below poverty line
1-3% of population (1980 est.)
12% of population (1991 est.)
0.290 (1980 est.)
0.275 (1989 est.)[6]
Labour force
152.3 million (3rd)
(1989 est.)[7]
Labour force by occupation
80% in industry and other non-agricultural sectors; 20% in agriculture (1989 est.)[1]
Unemployment1–2% (1990 est.)[1]
Main industries
Petroleum, steel, motor vehicles, aerospace, machinery, telecommunications, chemicals, heavy industries, electronics, food processing, lumber, mining and defense (1989 est.)[1]
External
Exports$124.7 billion (9th)
(1989 est.)[8]
Export goods
Petroleum and petroleum products, natural gas, metals, wood, machinery, agricultural products and a wide variety of manufactured goods
(1989 est.)[1]
Main export partners
Eastern Bloc 49%, European Community 14%, Cuba 5%, United States, Afghanistan
(1988 est.)[1]
Imports$114.7 billion (10th)
(1989 est.)[9]
Import goods
Grain and other agricultural products, machinery and equipment, steel products (including large-diameter pipe), consumer manufactures[1]
Main import partners
Eastern Bloc 54%, European Community 11%, Cuba, China, United States
(1988 est.)[1]
$55 billion (11th)
(1989 est.)[10]
$27.3 billion
(1988 est.)[11]
Public finances
Revenues$422 billion (5th)
(1990 est.)[12]
Expenses$510 billion (1989 est.)[1]
$53 million (2nd; capital expenditures) (1991 est.)[13]
Economic aid$147.6 billion (1954–1988)[1]
All values, unless otherwise stated, are in US dollars.


The economy of the Soviet Union was based on state ownership of the means of production, collective farming, and industrial manufacturing. An administrative-command system managed a distinctive form of central planning. The Soviet economy was second only to the United States and was characterized by state control of investment, prices, a dependence on natural resources, lack of consumer goods, little foreign trade, public ownership of industrial assets, macroeconomic stability, low unemployment and high job security.[14]

Beginning in 1930, the course of the economy of the Soviet Union was guided by a series of five-year plans. By the 1950s, the Soviet Union had rapidly evolved from a mainly agrarian society into a major industrial power.[15] Its transformative capacity meant communism consistently appealed to the intellectuals of developing countries in Asia.[16] In fact, Soviet economic authors like Lev Gatovsky (who participated in the elaboration of the first and second five-year plans) frequently used their economic analysis of this period to praise the effectiveness of the October Revolution. The impressive growth rates during the first three five-year plans (1928–1940) are particularly notable given that this period is nearly congruent with the Great Depression.[17] During this period, the Soviet Union saw rapid industrial growth while other regions were suffering from crisis.[18] The White House National Security Council of the United States described the continuing growth as a "proven ability to carry backward countries speedily through the crisis of modernization and industrialization", and the impoverished base upon which the five-year plans sought to build meant that at the commencement of Operation Barbarossa in 1941 the country was still poor.[19][20]

Even so, the Soviet Union had the second largest economy in the world from the end of World War II until the mid-1980s. A major strength of the Soviet economy was its enormous supply of oil and gas, which became much more valuable as exports after the world price of oil skyrocketed in the 1970s. As Daniel Yergin notes, the Soviet economy in its final decades was "heavily dependent on vast natural resources–oil and gas in particular". World oil prices collapsed in 1986, putting heavy pressure on the economy.[21] After Mikhail Gorbachev became the General Secretary of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and came to power in 1985, he began a process of economic liberalization by dismantling the command economy and moving towards a mixed economy modeled after Lenin's New Economic Policy. At its dissolution at the end of 1991, the Soviet Union began a Russian Federation with a growing pile of $66 billion in external debt and with barely a few billion dollars in net gold and foreign exchange reserves.[22]

The complex demands of the modern economy somewhat constrained the central planners. Data fiddling became common practice among the bureaucracy by reporting fulfilled targets and quotas, thus entrenching the crisis. From the Stalin-era to the early Brezhnev-era, the Soviet economy grew slower than Japan and faster than the United States. GDP levels in 1950 (in billion 1990 dollars) were 510 (100%) in the Soviet Union, 161 (100%) in Japan and 1,456 (100%) in the United States. By 1965, the corresponding values were 1,011 (198%), 587 (365%) and 2,607 (179%).[23] The Soviet Union maintained itself as the world's second largest economy in both nominal and purchasing power parity values throughout the Cold War, until 1990 when Japan's economy exceeded $3 trillion in nominal value.[24]

The Soviet Union's relatively medium consumer sector accounted for just 60% of the country's GDP in 1990 while the industrial and agricultural sectors contributed 22% and 20% respectively in 1991. Agriculture was the predominant occupation in the Soviet Union before the massive industrialization under Soviet general secretary Joseph Stalin. The service sector was of low importance in the Soviet Union, with the majority of the labor force employed in the industrial sector. The labor force totaled 152.3 million people. Though its GDP crossed $1 trillion in the 1970s and $2 trillion in the 1980s, the effects of central planning were progressively distorted due to the growth of the black market informal second economy in the Soviet Union.[25]

Planning

[edit]

Based on a system of state ownership, the Soviet economy was managed through Gosplan (the State Planning Commission), Gosbank (the State Bank) and the Gossnab (State Commission for Materials and Equipment Supply). Beginning in 1928, the economy was directed by a series of five-year plans, with a brief attempt at seven-year planning. For every enterprise, planning ministries (also known as the "fund holders" or fondoderzhateli) defined the mix of economic inputs (e.g. labor and raw materials), a schedule for completion, all wholesale prices and almost all retail prices. The planning process was based around material balances—balancing economic inputs with planned output targets for the planning period. From 1930 until the late 1950s, the range of mathematics used to assist economic decision-making was, for ideological reasons, extremely restricted.[26] On the whole, the plans were overoptimistic and plagued by falsified reporting.[27]

The industry was long concentrated after 1928 on the production of capital goods through metallurgy, machine manufacture, and chemical industry. In Soviet terminology, goods were known as capital.[citation needed] This emphasis was based on the perceived necessity for very fast industrialization and modernization of the Soviet Union. After the death of Joseph Stalin in 1953, consumer goods (group B goods) received somewhat more emphasis due to the efforts of Georgy Malenkov. However, when Nikita Khrushchev consolidated his power by sacking Malenkov, one of the accusations against him was that he permitted "theoretically incorrect and politically harmful opposition to the rate of development of heavy industry in favor of the rate of development of light and food industry".[28] Since 1955, the priorities were again given to capital goods, which was expressed in the decisions of the 20th Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union (CPSU) in 1956.[29]

Economist Naum Jasny says that while many of the official statistics were correctly reported:

The fact is that the most important official general indices of economic development – those of national income, industrial output, real incomes of wage-earners and peasants, labour productivity and production costs in industry – have, over long periods of time....nothing in common with reality.[30]

Most information in the Soviet economy flowed from the top down. There were several mechanisms in place for producers and consumers to provide input and information that would help in the drafting of economic plans (as detailed below), but the political climate was such that few people ever provided negative input or criticism of the plan and thus Soviet planners had very little reliable feedback that they could use to determine the success of their plans. This meant that economic planning was often done based on faulty or outdated information, particularly in sectors with large numbers of consumers. As a result, some goods tended to be underproduced and led to shortages while other goods were overproduced and accumulated in storage. Low-level managers often did not report such problems to their superiors, relying instead on each other for support. Some factories developed a system of barter and either exchanged or shared raw materials and parts without the knowledge of the authorities and outside the parameters of the economic plan.

Heavy industry was always the focus of the Soviet economy even in its later years. The fact that it received special attention from the planners, combined with the fact that industrial production was relatively easy to plan even without minute feedback, led to significant growth in that sector. The Soviet Union became one of the leading industrial nations of the world. Industrial production was disproportionately high in the Soviet Union compared to Western economies. By the 60s calorie consumption per person in the Soviet Union was at levels similar to the United States. However, the production of consumer goods was disproportionately low. Economic planners made little effort to determine the wishes of household consumers, resulting in severe shortages of many consumer goods. Whenever these consumer goods would become available on the market, consumers routinely had to stand in long lines (queues) to buy them.[31] A black market developed for goods such as cigarettes that were particularly sought after, but it constantly underproduced. People were developing unique social "networks of favors" between people having access to sought after goods (for example, working in particular shops or factories).[32]

Drafting the five-year plans

[edit]
Leon Trotsky was among the earliest Soviet figures that supported economic planning and decentralization[33] but opposed the Stalinist model.[34]

Under Joseph Stalin's close supervision, a complex system of planning arrangements had developed since the introduction of the first five-year plan in 1928.[35] Preceding this, Leon Trotsky had delivered a joint report to the April Plenum of the Central Committee in 1926 which proposed a program for national industrialisation and the replacement of annual plans with five-year plans. His proposals were rejected by the Central Committee majority which was controlled by the troika and derided by Stalin at the time.[36] Stalin's version of the five-year plan was implemented in 1928 and took effect until 1932.[37] According to historian Sheila Fitzpatrick, the scholarly consensus was that Stalin appropriated the position of the Left Opposition on such matters as industrialisation and collectivisation.[38]

Until the late 1980s and early 1990s, when economic reforms backed by Soviet leader Mikhail Gorbachev introduced significant changes in the traditional system (see perestroika), the allocation of resources was directed by a planning apparatus rather than through the interplay of market forces.

Time frame

[edit]

From the Stalin era through the late 1980s, the five-year plan integrated short-range planning into a longer time frame. It delineated the chief thrust of the country's economic development and specified the way the economy could meet the desired goals of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union. Although the five-year plan was enacted into law, it contained a series of guidelines rather than a set of direct orders.

Periods covered by the five-year plans coincided with those covered by the gatherings of the CPSU Party Congress. At each CPSU Congress, the party leadership presented the targets for the next five-year plan, therefore each plan had the approval of the most authoritative body of the country's leading political institution.

Guidelines for the plan

[edit]

The Central Committee of the CPSU and more specifically its Politburo set basic guidelines for planning. The Politburo determined the general direction of the economy via control figures (preliminary plan targets), major investment projects (capacity creation) and general economic policies. These guidelines were submitted as a report of the Central Committee to the Congress of the CPSU to be approved there. After the approval at the Congress, the list of priorities for the five-year plan was processed by the Council of Ministers, which constituted the government of the Soviet Union. The Council of Ministers was composed of industrial ministers, chairmen of various state committees and chairmen of agencies with ministerial status. This committee stood at the apex of the vast economic administration, including the state planning apparatus, the industrial ministries, the trusts (the intermediate level between the ministries and the enterprises) and finally the state enterprises. The Council of Ministers elaborated on Politburo plan targets and sent them to Gosplan, which gathered data on plan fulfillment.[39]

Gosplan

[edit]

Combining the broad goals laid out by the Council of Ministers with data supplied by lower administrative levels regarding the current state of the economy, Gosplan worked out through trial and error a set of preliminary plan targets. Among more than twenty state committees, Gosplan headed the government's planning apparatus and was by far the most important agency in the economic administration. The task of planners was to balance resources and requirements to ensure that the necessary inputs were provided for the planned output. The planning apparatus alone was a vast organizational arrangement consisting of councils, commissions, governmental officials, specialists and so on charged with executing and monitoring economic policy.

The state planning agency was subdivided into its own industrial departments, such as coal, iron and machine building. It also had summary departments such as finance, dealing with issues that crossed functional boundaries. With the exception of a brief experiment with regional planning during the Khrushchev era in the 1950s, Soviet planning was done on a sectoral basis rather than on a regional basis. The departments of the state planning agency aided the agency's development of a full set of plan targets along with input requirements, a process involving bargaining between the ministries and their superiors. Economic ministries performed key roles in the Soviet organizational structure. When the planning goals had been established by Gosplan, economic ministries drafted plans within their jurisdictions and disseminated planning data to the subordinate enterprises. The planning data were sent downward through the planning hierarchy for progressively more detailed elaboration. The ministry received its control targets, which were then disaggregated by branches within the ministry, then by lower units, eventually until each enterprise received its own control figures (production targets).[40]

Enterprises were called upon to develop in the final period of state planning in the late 1980s and early 1990s (even though such participation was mostly limited to a rubber-stamping of prepared statements during huge pre-staged meetings). The enterprises' draft plans were then sent back up through the planning ministries for review. This process entailed intensive bargaining, with all parties seeking the target levels and input figures that best suited their interests.

After this bargaining process, Gosplan received the revised estimates and re-aggregated them as it saw fit. The redrafted plan was then sent to the Council of Ministers and the party's Politburo and Central Committee Secretariat for approval. The Council of Ministers submitted the plan to the Supreme Soviet of the Soviet Union and the Central Committee submitted the plan to the party congress, both for rubber stamp approval. By this time, the process had been completed and the plan became law.

The review, revision and approval of the five-year plan were followed by another downward flow of information, this time with the amended and final plans containing the specific targets for each sector of the economy. Implementation began at this point and was largely the responsibility of enterprise managers.

The national state budget was prepared by the Ministry of Finance of the Soviet Union by negotiating with its all-Union local organizations. If the state budget was accepted by the Soviet Union, it was then adopted.[41]

According to a number of scholars both inside and outside of USSR, it was specifically Soviet-type economic planning combined with political dogmatism which led to gradual degradation of Soviet economy and its collapse.[42][43][44][45]

Agriculture

[edit]
"Strengthen working discipline in collective farms", a Soviet propaganda poster issued in Uzbekistan, 1933

In the USSR, agriculture was organized into a system of collective farms (kolkhozes) and state farms (sovkhozes). These farms were collectivized distributed amongst the peasantry and yearly production quotas were set by administrators. Before Stalin, Soviet agriculture held its own. Data from the 1920s infers a positive supply response to increases in the terms of trade. Farmers increased grain sales to urban areas when the price of grain increased.[46] However, at the time, agricultural production was limited by technology, as the whole of Soviet Agriculture relied heavily on animal powered tilling. In the 1930s due to massive famines and animal die offs, the number of remaining animals doing farm work was reduced by half.[46] This indicated the dire need of additional production outputs, which administrators predicted could be supplied by mechanical harvesters. The planning of Soviet leadership emphasized a mechanical agricultural industry, whereby technology and ideology met to create a booming agricultural industry.[47] This way, the technological evolution of Soviet agricultural production could be linked to urban industry.[48] Yet in reality, Soviet planners were more invested in industry than farmers, and the Soviet agricultural industry suffered as a result.[49] An example of this can be seen in the analysis published in 1929 by soviet economist Lev Gatovsky regarding government intervention on the grain market.[50]

Leon Trotsky and the Opposition bloc had advocated a programme of industrialization which also proposed agricultural cooperatives and the formation of collective farms on a voluntary basis.[51] Several scholars have argued that the economic programme of Trotsky differed from the forced policy of collectivisation implemented by Stalin after 1928 due to the levels of brutality associated with its enforcement.[52][53][54]

Stalin's first Five year Plan (1929–1933) was a colossal failure. Soviet population declined after 1933, and would see modest growth until 1936.[55] The figures suggest a gap of about 15 million people between anticipated population and those that survived the five-year plan.[55] Systemic inefficiencies plagued Soviet agriculture, such as obsolete technology, waste of fuel resources, and depreciating capital stock.[56] These inefficiencies clogged the Soviet agricultural machine and reduced output. Additionally, climate greatly affected Soviet agricultural output. Many regions throughout the USSR had little rainfall, short growing seasons, low temperatures, and general extremes unsuitable for optimal agricultural production.[49] This was detrimental to agricultural output and prevented cost minimization. When harvests fell short of production quotas due to a sudden frost or long drought, Soviet output could not make up the difference. Consequently, when agriculture was not producing as promised, some peasants refused to work over fear of starvation. However, since Soviet farms were collectivized, no individual grievances could be tolerated for the societal system to succeed. As a result, peasants unwilling to join kolkhozy were forced off of their land, which was then redistributed to other peasants.[55]

Nikita Khrushchev and Joseph Stalin, 1936

Following previous agricultural failures, Khrushchev abandoned Stalin's agricultural model.[49] He instead looked comparatively at American agriculture through Soviet observers. He noticed that American agriculture flourished due to its specialization and interdependence on other farmers for goods and services. Similarly, Soviet farms could specialize in the crop which was best suited for growing in their region, and surplus could be transported throughout the USSR to satisfy quotas and distribute to people who needed the food. Khrushchev himself tended to suggest his favorite crops such as corn for planters.[49] Paired with a need to proselytize mechanized agriculture to nearby countries, the Khrushchev administration began a campaign for an optimistic future of mechanized Soviet agriculture.[49] However, Khrushchev was not able to fulfill his promises, and this contributed to his rising unpopularity which culminated in his removal from power.[49]

Following Khrushchev's leadership, Soviet agriculture's legacy was defined by patchwork that attempted to fix the mistakes of the previous administrations. Crop harvests, tractors, fertilizer, and capital investment were all increasing since 1955.[49]  By 1965, the output of the Soviet worker was increasing, but still well below average for a developed country.[48] Problems such as a scarcity of educated workers, saturation of unskilled workers and jobs made obsolete by technology, and poorly trained and educated farmers brought costs up and drove production down.[48] These issues prevented the Soviet Union from producing enough food, as a lack of administration and management led to the mismanagement of farms and reduced worker productivity. From 1972 to 1986, the Soviet Union failed to produce more wheat than the Western European average.[56] This failure to produce resulted in forced Soviet imports of food. Between 1961 and 1985, Soviet food imports from foreign producers cost a total of nearly 152 billion dollars.[56] The root of this expense can be identified in the inefficiencies of the Soviet agricultural sector, such as the shortage of workers, lag in technology, or natural factors such as drought or frosts. Although the Soviet Union aimed to establish a mechanized agricultural giant, the shortcomings of Soviet agriculture put the sector behind other countries from the beginning. Soviet agriculture had the inability to meet basic consumer demands and expectations, requiring policy change culminating in the dissolution of the USSR in 1991.[56]

Foreign trade and currency

[edit]

Largely self-sufficient, the Soviet Union traded little in comparison to its economic strength. However, trade with non-communist countries increased in the 1970s as the government sought to compensate gaps in domestic production with imports.

In general, fuels, metals and timber were exported, while consumer goods and sometimes grain were imported. In the 1980s, trade with the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (COMECON) member states accounted for about half the country's volume of trade.

The Soviet rouble was non-convertible after 1932 (when trade in gold-convertible chervonets, introduced by Lenin in the New Economic Policy years, was suspended) until the late 1980s. It was impossible (both for citizens and state-owned businesses) to freely buy or sell foreign currency even though the "exchange rate" was set and published regularly. Buying or selling foreign currency on a black market was a serious crime until the late 1980s. Individuals who were paid from abroad (for example writers whose books were published abroad) normally had to spend their currency in a foreign-currency-only chain of state-owned Beryozka ("Birch-tree") stores. Once a free conversion of currency was allowed, the exchange rate plummeted from its official values by almost a factor of 10.

Overall, the banking system was highly centralized and fully controlled by a single state-owned Gosbank, responsive to the fulfillment of the government's economic plans. Soviet banks furnished short-term credit to state-owned enterprises.

Forms of property

[edit]

There were two basic forms of property in the Soviet Union: individual property and collective property. These differed greatly in their content and legal status. According to communist theory, capital (means of production) should not be individually owned, with certain negligible exceptions. In particular, after the end of a short period of the New Economic Policy and with collectivization completed, all industrial property and virtually all land were collective.

Land in rural areas was allotted for housing and some sustenance farming, and persons had certain rights to it, but it was not their property in full. In particular, in kolkhozes and sovkhozes there was a practice to rotate individual farming lots with collective lots. This resulted in situations where people would ameliorate, till and cultivate their lots carefully, adapting them to small-scale farming and in 5–7 years those lots would be swapped for kolkhoz ones, typically with exhausted soil due to intensive, large-scale agriculture.[citation needed] There was an extremely small number of remaining individual farmsteads (khutors; хутор), located in isolated rural areas in the Baltic states, Ukraine, Siberia and cossack lands.

Individual property

[edit]

To distinguish "capitalist" and "socialist" types of property ownership further, two different forms of individual property were recognized: private property (частная собственность, chastnaya sobstvennost) and personal property (личная собственность, lichnaya sobstvennost). The former encompassed capital (means of production) while the latter described everything else in a person's possession.

Collective property

[edit]

There were several forms of collective ownership, the most significant being state property, kolkhoz property and cooperative property. The most common forms of cooperative property were housing cooperatives (жилищные кооперативы) in urban areas, consumer cooperatives (потребительская кооперация, потребкооперация) and rural consumer societies (сельские потребительские общества, сельпо).

History

[edit]
GDP per capita in the former USSR, 1922 to 1991

See also History of the Soviet Union

Early development

[edit]

Both the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic and later the Soviet Union were countries in the process of industrialization. For both, this development occurred slowly and from a low initial starting-point. Because of World War I (1914–1918), the Russian Revolution of 1917 and the ensuing Russian Civil War (1917–1922), industrial production had only managed to barely recover its 1913 level by 1926.[57] By this time, about 18% of the population lived in non-rural areas, although only about 7.5% were employed in the non-agricultural sector. The remainder remained stuck in low-productivity agriculture.[58]

David A. Dyker sees the Soviet Union of circa 1930 as in some ways a typical developing country, characterized by low capital-investment and with most of its population residing in the countryside. Part of the reason[citation needed] for low investment-rates lay in the inability to acquire capital from abroad. This in turn, resulted from the repudiation of the debts of the Russian Empire by the Bolsheviks in 1918[59] as well as from the worldwide financial troubles. Consequently, any kind of economic growth had to be financed by domestic savings.[58]

The economic problems in agriculture were further exacerbated by natural conditions, such as long cold winters across the country, droughts in the south and acidic soils in the north. However, according to Dyker, the Soviet economy did have "extremely good" potential in the area of raw materials and mineral extraction, for example in the oil fields in Transcaucasia, and this, along with a small but growing manufacturing base, helped the Soviet Union avoid any kind of balance of payments problems.[58]

New Economic Policy (1921–1929)

[edit]
One of the several photographs[60] intended to show the two major economic policy makers of the Soviet Union together, Vladimir Lenin (left) who created the NEP and Joseph Stalin (right) who created the command economy

By early 1921, it became apparent to the Bolsheviks that forced requisitioning of grain had resulted in low agricultural production and widespread opposition. As a result, the decision was made by Lenin and the Politburo to try an alternative approach.[61] The so-called New Economic Policy (NEP) was approved at the 10th Congress of the Russian Communist Party (Bolsheviks).[62]

Everything except "the commanding heights", as Lenin put it, of the economy would be privatized. The commanding heights included foreign trade, heavy industry, communication and transport among others.[61] In practice this limited the private sector to artisan and agricultural production/trade.[63] The NEP encountered strong resistance within the Bolshevik party. Lenin had to persuade communist skeptics that "state capitalism" was a necessary step in achieving communism, while he himself harbored suspicions that the policy could be abused by private businessmen ("NEPmen").[64]

As novelist Andrei Platonov, among others, noted, the improvements were immediate. Rationing cards and queues, which had become hallmarks of war communism, had disappeared. However, due to prolonged war, low harvests, and several natural disasters the Soviet economy was still in trouble, particularly its agricultural sector. In 1921, widespread famine broke out in the Volga-Ural region. The Soviet government changed its previous course and allowed international relief to come in from abroad, and established a special committee chaired by prominent communists and non-communists alike. Despite this, an estimated five million people died in the famine.[65]

Armenian Soviet Socialist Republic

[edit]

The Soviet-era republic's centralized economy forbade private ownership of property with an income. Privately owned farms in Armenia were collectivized and put under the control of the state starting in the late 1920s, however this was frequently met with vigorous opposition by the peasantry. During the same period (1929–1936), Armenia's industrialization process was also launched by the government. The socialist economic system and socialist ownership of the means of production, which come in two forms: state property and cooperative and collective-farm property, form the basis of the republic's economy. The legislation authorizes small private ventures of individual peasants and craftsmen based on their own labor and forbids the exploitation of the labor of others, in addition to the socialist system of economy, which is the major type of economy in the Republic. The official economic plan sets and directs the Republic's economic course. By 1935, the gross product of agriculture was 132% higher than that of 1928, and the gross product of industry was 650% more than that of 1928. However, the 1930s economic revolution came at a high price: it destroyed the conventional peasant family and village institution and caused many people who lived in the remote countryside to relocate to cities. As private enterprise was essentially brought under government control, it came to an end.[66]

Stalinism

[edit]

Starting in 1928, the five-year plans began building a heavy industrial base at once in an underdeveloped economy without waiting years for capital to accumulate through the expansion of light industry, and without reliance on external financing. The New Economic Policy was rapidly abandoned and replaced by Stalinism. The country now became industrialized at a hitherto unprecedented pace, surpassing Germany's pace of industrialization in the 19th century and Japan's earlier in the 20th century.

After the reconstruction of the economy in the wake of the destruction caused by the Russian Civil War was completed and after the initial plans of further industrialization were fulfilled, the explosive growth slowed down until the period of Brezhnev stagnation in the 1970s and 1980s.

Trotsky maintained that the disproportions and imbalances which became characteristic of Stalinist planning in the 1930s such as the underdeveloped consumer base along with the priority focus on heavy industry were due to a number of avoidable problems. He argued that the industrial drive had been enacted under more severe circumstances, several years later and in a less rational manner than proposal originally conceived by the Left Opposition.[67]

Led by the creation of NAMI and by the GAZ copy of the Ford Model A in 1929,[68][69][circular reference] industrialization came with the extension of medical services, which improved labor productivity. Campaigns were carried out against typhus, cholera and malaria; the number of physicians increased as rapidly as facilities and training would permit; and death and infant mortality rates steadily decreased.

In 1947 politburo announced a monetary reform (1947) that basically intended to confiscate "excessive" amount of money in order to weaken rampant illegal trade (which was banned at the time) and fill up budget at cost of people.

Ration stamps in Soviet Union were abolished in December 1947, six months after rationing ended in the US, and two years before France. Soviet post-war famine of 1946–1947 was still ravaging the country.

1930–1970

[edit]
The State Quality Mark of the Soviet Union, introduced in 1967, was used to certify that goods met quality standards and to improve the efficiency of production.

As weighed growth rates, economic planning performed very well during the early and mid-1930s, World War II-era mobilization, and for the first two decades of the postwar era. The Soviet Union became the world's leading producer of oil, coal, iron ore and cement; manganese, gold, natural gas and other minerals were also of major importance. However, information about the Soviet famine of 1932–1933 was suppressed by the Soviet authorities until perestroika.

To some estimations, in 1933 workers' real earnings sank on more than 11.4% from 1926 level,[70] though it needs an adjustment due to elimination of unemployment and perks at work (such as inexpensive meals).[71] Common and political prisoners in labor camps were forced to do unpaid labor and communists and Komsomol members were frequently "mobilized" for various construction projects. The German invasion of World War II inflicted punishing blows to the economy of the Soviet Union, with Soviet GDP falling 34% between 1940 and 1942.[72] Industrial output did not recover to its 1940 level for almost a decade.[20]

In 1961, a new redenominated Soviet rouble was issued with an exchange rate of £1 = Rbl 1. The rouble maintained exchange parity with sterling until the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991. After a new leadership, headed by Leonid Brezhnev, had come to power, attempts were made to revitalize the economy through economic reform. Starting in 1965, enterprises and organizations were made to rely on economic methods of profitable production, rather than follow orders from the state administration. By 1970, the Soviet economy had reached its zenith and was estimated at 60 percent of the size of the United States[73] in terms of the estimated commodities (like steel and coal). In 1989, the official GDP of the Soviet Union was $2,500 billion[74] while the GDP of the United States was $4,862 billion[75] with per capita income figures as $8,700 and $19,800 respectively.

The USSR was the first major non-Western country to close the developmental gap that had existed with the West since the 16th century.[76]: 52  In the period 1930 to 1960s, the USSR successfully implemented catch-up development.[76]: 52 

1970–1990

[edit]

After 1976, the USSR stopped narrowing the developmental gap with the West, and the gap further widened beginning in 1990.[76]: 52 

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1972 in retail prices was about 118 billion roubles ($530 billion).[77] The Era of Stagnation in the mid-1970s was triggered by the Nixon Shock and aggravated by the war in Afghanistan in 1979 and led to a period of economic standstill between 1979 and 1985. Soviet military buildup at the expense of domestic development kept the Soviet Union's GDP at the same level during the first half of the 1980s.[78] According to American journalist Scott Shane, the massive quantities of goods produced often did not meet the needs or tastes of consumers.[79]

The volume of decisions facing planners in Moscow became overwhelming. The cumbersome procedures for bureaucratic administration foreclosed the free communication and flexible response required at the enterprise level for dealing with worker alienation, innovation, customers, and suppliers. During 1975–1985, data fiddling became common practice among bureaucracy to report satisfied targets and quotas thus entrenching the crisis. At the same time, the effects of the central planning were progressively distorted due to the rapid growth of the second economy in the Soviet Union.[25]

Soviet national income 1928–1987 growth in % based on estimates of the official statistical agency of the Soviet Union, the CIA and revised estimates by Grigorii Khanin

While all modernized economies were rapidly moving to computerization after 1965, the Soviet Union fell further and further behind. Even though Moscow decided to copy the IBM 360 of 1965, it had enormous difficulties in manufacturing the necessary chips reliably and in quantity, in programming workable and efficient programs, in coordinating entirely separate operations, and in providing support to computer users.[80][81][82]

One of the greatest strengths of Soviet economy was its vast supplies of oil and gas; world oil prices quadrupled in the 1973–1974 and rose again in 1979–1981, making the energy sector the chief driver of the Soviet economy, and was used to cover multiple weaknesses. At one point, Soviet Premier Alexei Kosygin told the head of oil and gas production that "things are bad with bread. Give me 3 million tons [of oil] over the plan".[83]

In 2007, economist and former Prime Minister Yegor Gaidar wrote the following about looking back to these three decades:

The hard currency from oil exports stopped the growing food supply crisis, increased the import of equipment and consumer goods, ensured a financial base for the arms race and the achievement of nuclear parity with the United States, and permitted the realization of such risky foreign-policy actions as the war in Afghanistan.[84]

Awareness of the growing crisis arose initially within the KGB which with its extensive network of informants in every region and institution had its finger on the pulse of the nation. Yuri Andropov, director of the KGB, created a secret department during the 1970s within the KGB devoted to economic analysis and when he succeeded Brezhnev in 1982 sounded the alarm forcefully to the Soviet leadership. However, Andropov's remedy of increased discipline proved ineffective. It was only when Andropov's protege Gorbachev assumed power that a determined, but ultimately unsuccessful, assault on the economic crisis was undertaken.[85]

The value of all consumer goods manufactured in 1990 in retail prices was about 459 billion roubles ($2.1 trillion).[86] According to CIA estimates, by 1989 the size of the Soviet economy was roughly half that in the United States.[11]

Sector (distribution of Soviet workforce) 1940 1965 1970 1979 1984
Primary (agriculture and forestry) 54% 31% 25% 21% 20%
Secondary (including construction, transport and communication) 28% 44% 46% 48% 47%
Tertiary (including trade, finance, health, education, science and administration) 18% 25% 29% 31% 33%
Total 100% 100% 100% 100% 100%

Comparisons with other countries

[edit]
GDP per capita (1990 Int$) comparison involving the area of Russia/USSR, United States, and Western Europe from 1820 to 1990[87]
Russia/USSR United States Western Europe Russia/USSR as a % of United States Russia/USSR as a % of Western Europe
1820 689 1,257 1,232 55 56
1870 943 2,445 1,974 39 48
1913 1,488 5,301 3,473 28 43
1950 2,834 9,561 4,594 30 62
1973 6,058 16,689 11,534 36 53
1990 9,931 23,214 15,988 43 62
Evolution of GNP in comparison with European powers
(in millions of dollars of 1960)
Country 1890 1900 1913 1925 1938
Russia/Soviet Union 21,180 32,000 52,420 32,600 75,964
Germany 26,454 35,800 49,760 45,002 77,178
United Kingdom 29,441 36,273 44,074 43,700 56,102
France 19,758 23,500 27,401 36,262 39,284
Comparison between the economies of the Soviet Union and the United States (1989) according to 1990 CIA World Factbook data[11]
Soviet Union United States
GDP (GNP) (1989; millions $) 2,659,500 5,233,300
Population (July 1990) 290,938,469 250,410,000
GDP per capita (GNP) ($) 9,931 21,082
Labor force (1989) 152,300,000 125,557,000

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m "Soviet Union Economy 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  2. ^ a b "GDP – Million 1990". CIA Factbook. 1991. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  3. ^ "GDP – Million 1991". CIA Factbook. KayLee. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  4. ^ "GDP Per Capita 1990". CIA Factbook. 1991. Retrieved 16 January 2017.
  5. ^ "Inflation Rate % 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  6. ^ Alexeev, Michael V. "Income Distribution in the USSR in the 1980s" (PDF). Review of Income and Wealth (1993). Indiana University. Retrieved 16 April 2017.
  7. ^ "Labor Force 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  8. ^ "Exports Million 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  9. ^ "Imports Million 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  10. ^ "Budget External Debt Million 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Archived from the original on 1 November 2012. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  11. ^ a b c "1990 CIA World Factbook". Central Intelligence Agency. Archived from the original on 27 April 2011. Retrieved 23 July 2010.
  12. ^ "Budget Revenues Million Million 1991". CIA Factbook. 1992. Retrieved 12 June 2010.
  13. ^ "Budget Expenditures Million 1991", CIA Factbook, 1992, archived from the original on 1 November 2012, retrieved 12 June 2010
  14. ^ Hanson, Philip (2003). The Rise and Fall of the Soviet Economy (Routledge). pp. 1–8.
  15. ^ Davies 1998, p. 1, 3.
  16. ^ Peck 2006, p. p. 47.
    One notable person in this regard was Nehru, "who visited the Soviet Union in the late 1920s and was deeply impressed by Soviet industrial progress." See Bradley 2010, pp. 475–476.
  17. ^ Allen 2003, p. 153.
  18. ^ Baten, Jörg (2016). A History of the Global Economy. From 1500 to the Present. Cambridge University Press. pp. 62–63. ISBN 9781107507180.
  19. ^ Harrison 1996, p. 123.
  20. ^ a b Davies 1998, p. 2.
  21. ^ Daniel Yergin, The Quest: Energy, Security, and the Remaking of the Modern World (2011); quotes on pp 23, 24.
  22. ^ Boughton 2012, p. 288.
  23. ^ Angus Maddison, The World Economy: A Millennial Perspective (2001) pp. 274, 275, 298.
  24. ^ "Japan's IMF nominal GDP Data 1987 to 1989 (October 2014)".
  25. ^ a b Vladimir G. Treml and Michael V. Alexeev, "THE SECOND ECONOMY AND THE DESTABILIZING EFFECT OF ITS GROWTH ON THE STATE ECONOMY IN THE SOVIET UNION: 1965–1989", BERKELEY-DUKE OCCASIONAL PAPERS ON THE SECOND ECONOMY IN THE USSR, Paper No. 36, December 1993
  26. ^ Smolinski 1973, pp. 1189–90: "The mathematical sophistication of the tools actually employed was limited to those that had been used in Das Kapital: the four arithmetical operations, percentages, and arithmetic (but not geometric) mean."
  27. ^ Holland Hunter, "The Overambitious First Soviet Five-Year Plan." Slavic Review 32.2 (1973): 237-257.
  28. ^ "Георгий Маленков. 50 лет со дня отставки", Radio Liberty
  29. ^ Пыжиков А. В. Хрущевская "Оттепель" : 1953—1964, Olma-Press, 2002 ISBN 978-5224033560
  30. ^ Naum Jasny, "Some Thoughts on Soviet Statistics: An Evaluation," International Affairs (Royal Institute of International Affairs) 35#1 (1959), pp. 53-60, online
  31. ^ Revinskaya, Elena; RIR (16 October 2013). "A look at the old ration system in Russia". www.rbth.com. Retrieved 21 March 2019.
  32. ^ "The Importance of Blats in Soviet Everyday Life | Socialist and Post-Socialist Cities". Retrieved 21 March 2019.
  33. ^ Twiss, Thomas M. (8 May 2014). Trotsky and the Problem of Soviet Bureaucracy. BRILL. pp. 88–113. ISBN 978-90-04-26953-8.
  34. ^ Van Ree, Erik (1998). "Socialism in One Country: A Reassessment". Studies in East European Thought. 50 (2): 77–117. doi:10.1023/A:1008651325136. ISSN 0925-9392. JSTOR 20099669.
  35. ^ Nick Shepley, Stalin, the Five Year Plans and the Gulags: Slavery and Terror 1929-53 (2015).
  36. ^ Rogovin, Vadim Zakharovich (2021). Was There an Alternative? Trotskyism: a Look Back Through the Years. Mehring Books. p. 358. ISBN 978-1-893638-97-6.
  37. ^ "The First Five Year Plan, 1928–1932". Special Collections & Archives. 7 October 2015. Retrieved 23 February 2019.
  38. ^ Fitzpatrick, Sheila (22 April 2010). "The Old Man". London Review of Books. 32 (8). ISSN 0260-9592.
  39. ^ R.W. Davies and Oleg Khlevnyuk, "Gosplan." in E. A. Rees, ed., Decision-making in the Stalinist Command Economy, 1932–37 (1997). 32-66.
  40. ^ Michael Ellman, Socialist planning (Cambridge UP, 2014).
  41. ^ the IMF (1991). A Study of the Soviet economy. Vol. 1. International Monetary Fund (IMF). p. 287. ISBN 978-92-64-13468-3.
  42. ^ Dembinski, Pawel (1991). The Logic of Planned Economy: The Seeds of the Collapse. Clarendon Press. ISBN 978-0198286868.
  43. ^ Ellman, Michael (1973). Planning Problems in the USSR: The Contribution of Mathematical Economics to their Solution 1960-1971. CUP Archive. ISBN 978-0521202497.
  44. ^ "Optimizing things in the USSR · Chris Said". chris-said.io. Retrieved 15 November 2020.
  45. ^ "Николай Петрович Шмелёв (Nikolay Shmelyov) "Авансы и долги (Avansy i dolgi)" ("Credits and debts"), Новый мир (Novyi Mir) – 1987. - № 6". echelon.pl. Retrieved 15 November 2020.
  46. ^ a b Antel, John; Gregory, Paul (1994). "Agricultural Surplus Models and Peasant Behavior: Soviet Agriculture in the 1920s". Economic Development and Cultural Change. 42 (2): 375–386. doi:10.1086/452085. ISSN 0013-0079. JSTOR 1154447. S2CID 153635813.
  47. ^ Dekel-Chen, Jonathan (2020). "Putting Agricultural History to Work: Global Action Today from a Communal Past". Agricultural History. 94 (4): 512–544. doi:10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512. ISSN 0002-1482. JSTOR 10.3098/ah.2020.094.4.512. S2CID 229207917.
  48. ^ a b c Clayton, Elizabeth (September 1980). "Productivity in Soviet Agriculture". Slavic Review. 39 (3): 446–458. doi:10.2307/2497164. ISSN 0037-6779. JSTOR 2497164. S2CID 163496553.
  49. ^ a b c d e f g HALE-DORRELL, AARON (2015). "The Soviet Union, the United States, and Industrial Agriculture". Journal of World History. 26 (2): 295–324. ISSN 1045-6007. JSTOR 43901754.
  50. ^ Гатовский, Лев Маркович (1929). "О соотношениях цен в 1927/28 и начале 1928/29 гг" (PDF) (Сборник статей ed.). Archived from the original (PDF) on 16 January 2022. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  51. ^ Kemp, Tom (14 January 2014). Industrialisation in the Non-Western World. Routledge. pp. 1–150. ISBN 978-1-317-90133-4.
  52. ^ Mandel, Ernest (1995). Trotsky as alternative. London: Verso Books. p. 59. ISBN 978-1859840856.
  53. ^ Daniels, Robert V. (1 October 2008). The Rise and Fall of Communism in Russia. Yale University Press. p. 195. ISBN 978-0-300-13493-3.
  54. ^ Rubenstein, Joshua (2011). Leon Trotsky : a revolutionary's life. New Haven : Yale University Press. p. 161. ISBN 978-0-300-13724-8.
  55. ^ a b c Hunter, Holland (1988). "Soviet Agriculture with and without Collectivization, 1928-1940". Slavic Review. 47 (2): 203–216. doi:10.2307/2498462. ISSN 0037-6779. JSTOR 2498462. S2CID 163882472.
  56. ^ a b c d Clairmonte, Frederick F. (1989). "Rise and Fall of Soviet Agriculture". Economic and Political Weekly. 24 (11): 555–560. ISSN 0012-9976. JSTOR 4394526.
  57. ^ Dyker 1992, p. 2.
  58. ^ a b c Dyker, David A. (1992). Restructuring the Soviet Economy. Routledge (published 2002). p. 3. ISBN 9781134917464. Retrieved 18 October 2015. Repudiation of the international debts of the tsarist regime, coupled with the difficult economic conditions of the post-Wall Street crash period, ensured that any increase in the rate of accumulation would have to be internally financed. [...] In some ways, then, the Soviet Union c. 1930 was a typical developing country, with a relatively low level of accumulation and substantial surplus agricultural population. But she could not count on large-scale capital transfer from abroad – for better or worse.
  59. ^ Rempel, Richard A.; Haslam, Beryl, eds. (2000). Uncertain Paths to Freedom: Russia and China, 1919–22. Collected papers of Bertrand Russell. Vol. 15. Psychology Press. p. 529. ISBN 9780415094115. Retrieved 18 October 2015. French creditors were owed forty-three percent of the total Russian debt repudiated by the Bolsheviks on 28 January 1918.
  60. ^ Lenin and Stalin in Gorki (close up)
  61. ^ a b Moss 2005, p. 228.
  62. ^ Hosking, Geoffrey A. (1993). The First Socialist Society: A History of the Soviet Union from Within. Harvard University Press. p. 119. ISBN 978-0-674-30443-7. Retrieved 24 March 2022.
  63. ^ Carr, E.H. and Davies, R.W, (1988), Foundations of a Planned Economy, Vol. 1
  64. ^ Moss 2005, p. 227.
  65. ^ Hosking 1993, p. 120.
  66. ^ "Armenian Attitudes Toward Work and the Soviet Legacy". 18 April 2022.
  67. ^ Deutscher, Isaac (5 January 2015). The Prophet: The Life of Leon Trotsky. Verso Books. p. 1141. ISBN 978-1-78168-721-5.
  68. ^ G.N. Georgano Cars: Early and Vintage, 1886–1930. (London: Grange-Universal, 1985)
  69. ^ Wikipedia, GAZ.
  70. ^ Nove, Alec (1969), An Economic History of the U.S.S.R., IICA, p. 206
  71. ^ Nove 1969, p. 207
  72. ^ Harrison 1996, p. p. 124.
  73. ^ "A Comparison of the US and Soviet Economies: Evaluating the Performance of the Soviet System" (PDF). foia.cia.gov. October 1985. Archived from the original (PDF) on 4 March 2016. Retrieved 7 April 2015.
  74. ^ "Soviet Union Economy - 1989".
  75. ^ "United States Economy - 1989"
  76. ^ a b c Gnerre, Orazio Maria (2023). "Strengthening of the Sino-Russian Partnership". China and Eurasian powers in a Multipolar World Order 2.0: Security, Diplomacy, Economy and Cyberspace. Mher Sahakyan. New York: Routledge. ISBN 978-1-003-35258-7. OCLC 1353290533.
  77. ^ Manufactured goods sector was worth 118 billion roubles in 1972
  78. ^ "The Economic Impact of Soviet Military Spending" (PDF). www.cia.gov. April 1975. p. 2. Archived from the original (PDF) on 20 September 2016. Retrieved 9 December 2018.
  79. ^ Shane, Scott (1994). "What Price Socialism? An Economy Without Information". Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee. pp. 75 to 98. ISBN 978-1-56663-048-1. It was not the gas pedal but the steering wheel that was failing
  80. ^ James W. Cortada, "Public Policies and the Development of National Computer Industries in Britain, France, and the Soviet Union, 1940—80." Journal of Contemporary History (2009) 44#3 pp: 493–512, especially page 509-10.
  81. ^ Frank Cain, "Computers and the Cold War: United States restrictions on the export of computers to the Soviet Union and Communist China." Journal of Contemporary History (2005) 40#1 pp: 131–147. in JSTOR
  82. ^ Parrott, Bruce (1985). Trade, Technology, and Soviet-American Relations. Indiana UP. pp. 10–12. ISBN 978-0253360250.
  83. ^ Yergin, The Quest (2011) p 23
  84. ^ Gaidar, Yegor (2007). Collapse of an Empire: Lessons for Modern Russia. Brookings Institution Press. p. 102. ISBN 978-0815731153.
  85. ^ Shane, Scott (1994). "The KGB, Father of Perestroika". Dismantling Utopia: How Information Ended the Soviet Union. Chicago: Ivan R. Dee. pp. 59, 60, 99 to 120. ISBN 978-1-56663-048-1. When he spoke to the leadership circle he said the country was faced with a question of survival
  86. ^ United States. Congress. Joint Economic Committee; John Pearce Hardt (1993). The Former Soviet Union in Transition. M.E. Sharpe. p. 495. ISBN 978-1-56324-318-9.
  87. ^ Maddison, Angus (2006). The World Economy (PDF). Paris, France: Development Centre of the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD). p. 185. ISBN 978-92-64-02261-4.

Works cited

[edit]

Further reading

[edit]
  • Autio-Sarasmo, Sari. "Technological Modernisation in the Soviet Union and Post-Soviet Russia: Practices and Continuities." Europe-Asia Studies 68.1 (2016): 79–96.
  • Bergson, Abram. The real national income of Soviet Russia since 1928 (1961)
  • Connolly, Richard. The Russian Economy: A Very Short Introduction (Oxford University Press, 2020). Online review
  • Daniels, Robert Vince (1993). The End of the Communist Revolution. London: Routledge.
  • Davies, R. W. Soviet economic development from Lenin to Khrushchev (1998) excerpt
  • Davies, R. W. ed. From Tsarism to the New Economic Policy: Continuity and Change in the Economy of the USSR (London, 1990).
  • Davies, R. W. ed. The Economic Transformation of the Soviet Union, 1913–1945 (Cambridge, 1994).
  • Goldman, Marshall (1994). Lost Opportunity: Why Economic Reforms in Russia Have Not Worked. New York: W. W. Norton.
  • Gregory, Paul; Stuart, Robert (2001). Soviet and Post Soviet Economic Structure and Performance (7th ed.). Boston: Addison Wesley.
  • Gregory, Paul, and Mark Harrison. 2005. "Allocation under Dictatorship: Research in Stalin's Archives." Journal of Economic Literature, 43 (3): 721–761.
  • Harrison, Mark. "The Soviet Union after 1945: Economic Recovery and Political Repression," Past & Present (2011 Supplement 6) Vol. 210 Issue suppl_6, p. 103–120.
  • Goldman, Marshall (1991). What Went Wrong With Perestroika. New York: W. W. Norton.
  • Kennedy, Paul. The Rise and Fall of the Great Powers (New York: Random House, 1987).
  • Laird, Robbin F. (1984). "Soviet Arms Trade with the Noncommunist Third World". Proceedings of the Academy of Political Science. 35 (3): 196–213. doi:10.2307/1174128. JSTOR 1174128.
  • Moser, Nat. Oil and the Economy of Russia: From the Late-Tsarist to the Post-Soviet Period (Routledge, 2017).
  • Nove, Alec. An Economic History of the USSR, 1917–1991. (3rd ed. 1993) online free to borrow
  • Ofer, Gur. "Soviet Economic Growth: 1928-1985," Journal of Economic Literature (1987) 25#4: 1767–1833. online
  • Pravda, Alex (2010). "The collapse of the Soviet Union, 1990–1991". In Leffler, Melvyn P.; Westad, Odd Arne (eds.). The Cambridge History of the Cold War, Volume 3: Findings. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. pp. 356–377.
  • Rutland, Robert (1985). The Myth of the Plan: Lessons of Soviet Planning Experience. London: Hutchinson.
  • Zhuravskaya, Ekaterina, Sergei Guriev, and Andrei Markevich. 2024. "New Russian Economic History." Journal of Economic Literature, 62 (1): 47–114.

In Russian

[edit]
  • Kara-Murza, Sergey (2004). Soviet Civilization: From 1917 to the Great Victory (in Russian) Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От начала до Великой Победы. ISBN 5-699-07590-9.
  • Kara-Murza, Sergey (2004). Soviet Civilization: From the Great Victory Till Our Time (in Russian). Сергей Кара-Мурза. Советская цивилизация. От Великой Победы до наших дней. ISBN 5-699-07591-7.
[edit]