Jump to content

Law of demand: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Overview: no need for this either, just get to the point
 
(522 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Fundamental principle in microeconomics}}
{{Expand|article with examples|date=February 2009}}
[[File:Illustration of law of demand.jpg|thumb|The demand curve, shown in blue, is sloping downwards from left to right because price and quantity demanded are inversely related. This relationship is contingent on certain conditions remaining constant. The supply curve, shown in orange, intersects with the demand curve at price (Pe) = 80 and quantity (Qe)= 120. Pe = 80 is the equilibrium price at which quantity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied. Similarly, Qe = 120 is the equilibrium quantity at which the quantity demanded and supplied are at the equilibrium price. Therefore, the intersection of the demand and supply curves provide us with the efficient allocation of goods in an economy.|365x365px]]
{{Refimprove|date=February 2009}}
In [[microeconomics]], the '''law of demand''' is a fundamental principle which states that there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. In other words, "conditional on [[ceteris paribus|all else being equal]], as the price of a [[Goods|good]] increases '''(↑)''', quantity demanded will decrease '''(↓)'''; conversely, as the price of a good decreases '''(↓)''', quantity demanded will increase '''(↑)'''".<ref name=":0">{{Cite book|title=Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions|last1=Nicholson|first1=Walter|last2=Snyder|first2=Christopher|publisher=South-Western|year=2012|isbn=978-111-1-52553-8|edition=11|location=Mason, OH|pages=27,154}}</ref> [[Alfred Marshall]] worded this as: "When we say that a person's demand for anything increases, we mean that he will buy more of it than he would before at the same price, and that he will buy as much of it as before at a higher price".<ref name=":1">{{Cite book|last=Marshall Abhishek|first=Alfred|title=Elements of economics of industry|publisher=Macmillan|year=1892|location=London|pages=77, 79}}</ref> The law of demand, however, only makes a qualitative statement in the sense that it describes the direction of change in the amount of quantity demanded but not the magnitude of change.
{{Economics sidebar}}
In economics, the '''law of demand''' is an economic law that states that consumers buy more of a good when its price decreases and less when its price increases (ceteris paribus).


The law of demand is represented by a graph called the [[demand curve]], with quantity demanded on the x-axis and price on the y-axis. Demand curves are downward sloping by definition of the law of demand. The law of demand also works together with the [[law of supply]] to determine the efficient allocation of resources in an economy through the [[Economic equilibrium|equilibrium price and quantity]].
The greater the amount to be sold, the smaller the price at which it is offered must be in order for it to find purchasers.


The relationship between price and quantity demanded holds true so long as it is complied with the ''ceteris paribus'' condition "all else remain equal" quantity demanded varies inversely with price when income and the prices of other goods remain constant.<ref name="mundanopedia.com">{{Cite web|date=2021-12-31|title=Law of Demand: What it is, Definition, Examples|url=https://mundanopedia.com/economics/law-of-demand/|access-date=2022-01-01|website=Mundanopedia|language=en-US}}</ref> If all else are not held equal, the law of demand may not necessarily hold.<ref>{{Cite web|title=The Law of Demand {{!}} Introduction to Business [Deprecated]|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-introbusiness/chapter/the-law-of-demand/|access-date=2021-04-20|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref> In the real world, there are many determinants of demand other than price, such as the prices of other goods, the consumer's income, preferences etc.<ref>http://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/lawofdemand.asp; Investopedia, Retrieved 9 September 2013</ref> There are also exceptions to the law of demand such as [[Giffen good]]s and perfectly inelastic goods.
Law of demand states that the amount demanded of a commodity and its price are inversely related, other things remaining constant. That is, if the income of the consumer, prices of the related goods, and tastes and preferences of the consumer remain unchanged, the consumer’s demand for the good will move opposite to the movement in the price of the good.


== Overview ==
"If the price of the good increases, the quantity demanded decreases, while if price of the good decreases, its quantity demanded increases."
Economist Alfred Marshall provided the graphical illustration of the law of demand.<ref name=":1" /> This graphical illustration is still used today to define and explain a variety of other concepts and theories in economics. A simple explanation of the law of demand is that all else equal, at a higher price, consumer will demand less quantity of a good and vice versa. The law of demand applies to a variety of organisational and business situations. Price determination, government policy formation etc are examples.<ref name=":2">{{Cite web|date=2019-03-04|title=Law of demand: Statement, explanation and exceptions|url=https://thefactfactor.com/facts/social_sciences/economics/law-of-demand/327/|access-date=2021-04-24|website=The Fact Factor|language=en-US}}</ref> Together with the law of supply, the law of demand provides to us the equilibrium price and quantity. Moreover, the law of demand and supply explains why goods are priced at the level that they are. They also help us identify opportunities to buy what are perceived to be underpriced (or sell overpriced) goods or assets.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Hayes|first=Adam|title=Law of Demand Definition|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/lawofdemand.asp|access-date=2021-04-21|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref>


Law of Demand is relied heavily upon by managerial economics, which is a branch of economics that applies microeconomic analysis to managerial decision-making, to make informed decisions on pricing, production, and marketing strategies. In this context, understanding the alternative factors that influence the Law of Demand becomes crucial for managers and decision-makers.<ref>{{Cite web |title=What Is the Law of Demand in Economics, and How Does It Work? |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/lawofdemand.asp |access-date=2023-04-18 |website=Investopedia |language=en}}</ref>
== Mathematical expression ==
The negative relation (i.e., higher price attracts lower demand & lower prices encourages high quantity to be bought by the consumers) is based on logic and experience. Mathematically, the inverse relation may be stated with causal relation as:<br />
<center><math>Qx = f (Px)</math></center>
Where, Q is the quantity demanded of x goods<br />
f is the function, and<br />
Px is the price of x goods.<br />


# [[Income effect]]: The income effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good or service as a result of changes in consumers' purchasing power. When prices increase, the purchasing power of consumers decreases, leading to a decline in the quantity demanded. Conversely, a decrease in prices will increase purchasing power and lead to an increase in the quantity demanded.
Hence, in the above model, the function (f) is a varying one i.e., the law of demand postulates Px as the causal factor (independent variable) and Qx is the dependent variable.
# [[Substitution effect]]: The substitution effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good or service due to a change in the relative prices of substitute goods. When the price of a good increases, consumers may shift their consumption to relatively cheaper substitute goods, causing the demand for the original good to decrease.
# Price expectations: Consumer expectations about future prices can influence their current demand for goods or services. If consumers expect prices to rise in the future, they may increase their current consumption to avoid higher prices later. Conversely, if they expect prices to fall, they may delay consumption, causing a decline in the quantity demanded.
# [[Market demographics|Market size and demographics]]: The size of the market and its demographics can also influence the Law of Demand. Changes in population size, age distribution, and income levels can affect the overall demand for goods or services, thus impacting the relationship between price and quantity demanded.


Demand refers to the [[demand curve]]. A change in demand is indicated by a shift in the demand curve. Quantity demanded, on the other hand refers to a specific point on the demand curve which corresponds to a specific price. A change in quantity demanded therefore refers to a movement along the existing demand curve. However, there are some exceptions to the law of demand. For instance, if the price of cigarettes goes up, its demand does not decrease. The exceptions to the law of demand typically suit the Giffen commodities and Veblen goods which is further explained below.
The two variables move in the opposite direction. When Px falls Qx rises and the reverse. In regard to the question "by how much will quantity demanded rise?", the law is silent. For example, when Px for a one-way rail ticket on the Acela Express from Boston's South Station to New York City's Penn Station falls from $111 to $105, ridership may rise from 1625 daily riders to 1825 daily riders or even to just 1626 daily riders. Thus the law of demand merely states the direction in which quantity demanded changes for a given change in price. Moreover, what the law states is hypothetical and not actual.


The four main types of elasticity of demand are price elasticity of demand, cross elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand, and advertising elasticity of demand.<ref name="mundanopedia.com"/>
== Assumptions ==
Every law will have limitation or exceptions. While expressing the law of demand, the assumptions that other conditions of demand were unchanged. If remain constant, the inverse relation may not hold well. In other words, it is assumed that the income and tastes of consumers and the prices of other commodities are constant. This law operates when the commodity’s price changes and all other prices and conditions do not change. The main assumptions are
* Habits, tastes and fashions remain constant
* Money, income of the consumer does not change.
* Prices of other goods remain constant
* The commodity in question has no substitute
* The commodity is a normal good and has no prestige or status value.
* People do not expect changes in the prices.


== History ==
== Exceptions to the law of demand ==
The famous law of demand was first '''stated''' by Charles Davenant (1656-1714) in his essay, "Probable Methods of Making People Gainers in the Balance of Trade (1699)".<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Creedy|first=John|date=1986|title=On the King-Davenant "Law" of Demand1|url=https://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/abs/10.1111/j.1467-9485.1986.tb00826.x|journal=Scottish Journal of Political Economy|language=en|volume=33|issue=3|pages=193–212|doi=10.1111/j.1467-9485.1986.tb00826.x|issn=1467-9485}}</ref> However, there were instances of its understanding and use much earlier when Gregory King (1648-1712) made a demonstration of the law of demand. He represented a relationship between the price of wheat and the harvest where the results suggested that if the harvest falls by 50%, the price would rise by 500%. This demonstration illustrated the law of demand as well as its elasticity.<ref name=":4">{{Cite web|title=A Very Brief History of Demand and Supply|url=https://worthwhile.typepad.com/worthwhile_canadian_initi/2015/03/a-very-brief-history-of-demand-and-supply.html|access-date=2021-04-21|website=Worthwhile Canadian Initiative}}</ref>
Generally, the amount demanded of good increases with a decrease in price of the good and vice versa. In some cases, however, this may not be true. Such situations are explained.


Skipping forward to 1890, economist [[Alfred Marshall]] documented the '''graphical illustration''' of the law of demand.<ref name=":1" /> In ''Principles of Economics'' (1890), Alfred Marshall reconciled the demand and supply into a single analytical framework. The formulation of the demand curve was provided by the utility theory while supply curve was determined by the cost. This idea of demand and supply curve is what we still use today to develop the market equilibrium and to support a variety of other economic theories and concepts. Due to general agreement with the observation, economists have come to accept the validity of the law under most situations. Economist also see Alfred Marshall as the pioneer of the standard demand and supply diagrams and their use in economic analysis including welfare applications and consumer surplus.<ref name=":4" />[[File:Change in demand.png|thumb|Anything that affects the buying decision other than the product price will shift the demand curve. Considering our example of mortgage rates; with a higher mortgage rate, demand curve will shift to the left from D0 to D1. This means that there is less demand for the housing market at every price. On the other hand, with lower mortgage rate demand curve shifts to the right from D0 to D2, meaning there is more demand for the housing market at every price.]]
=== Giffen goods ===
As noted earlier, if there is an inferior good of which the negative income effect is greater than the negative substitution effect, the law of demand would not hold. For example, when the price of potatoes (which is the staple food of some poor families) decreases significantly, then a particular household may like to buy superior goods out of the savings which they can have now due to superior goods like cereals, fruits etc., not only from these savings but also by reducing the consumption of potatoes. Thus, a decrease in price of potatoes results in decrease in consumption of potatoes. Such basic good items (like bajra, barlery, grain etc.) consumed in bulk by the poor families, generally fall in the category of Giffen goods.


== Mathematical description ==
=== Commodities which are used as status symbols ===
Consider the function <math>\ Q_x = f(P_x ; \mathbf Y)</math>, where <math>Q_x</math> is the quantity demanded of good ''<math>x</math>'', <math>f</math> is the [[demand function]], <math>P_x</math> is the price of the good and <math>\mathbf Y</math> is the list of parameters other than the price.
Some expensive commodities like diamonds, air conditioned cars, etc., are used as status symbols to display one’s wealth. The more expensive these commodities become, the higher their value as a status symbol and hence, the greater the demand for them. The amount demanded of these commodities increase with an increase in their price and decrease with a decrease in their price. Also known as a [[Veblen good]].


The law of demand states that <math>\frac{\partial f}{\partial P_x} < 0</math>. Here <math>\partial/\partial P_x</math> is the [[partial derivative]] operator.<ref name=":0" />
=== Expectation of change in the price of commodity ===
If a household expects the price of a commodity to increase, it may start purchasing greater amount of the commodity even at the presently increased price. Similarly, if the house hold expects the price of the commodity to decrease, it may postpone its purchases. Thus, law of demand is violated in such cases.


The above equation, when plotted with quantity demanded (<math>Q_x</math>) on the ''<math>x</math>''-axis and price (<math>P_x</math>) on the <math>y</math>-axis, gives the [[demand curve]], which is also known as the demand schedule. The demand curve is downward sloping illustrating the inverse relationship between quantity demanded and price. Therefore, a downward sloping demand curve embeds the law of demand.
In the above circumstances, the demand curve does not slope down from left to right instead it presents a backward sloping from top right to down left as shown in diagram. This curve is known as exceptional demand curve.


In a more specific manner:<ref name="mundanopedia.com"/>
Why demand curve is downward sloping?
law of demand explain the inverse relation b/w price of commodity and its demand, assuming other things remain constant. this negative relation itself implies downward movement of demand curve from left to right. But basically it happens due to main three effects or laws:
1. Law of Diminishing marginal utility. (Please connect it to the concept)
2. Income effect, which simply talk about change in real income (Purchasing Power) of consumer. whenever there fall in price of good exist, the purchasing power of consumer gets increase and thus she wants to purchase more.
3. Substitution effect: for most of the goods substitutes or similar commodity are available. when there is change in price of one and it become cheaper as compare to its substitute, some buyer transform from present consumption towards those goods whose prices falls.


:<math>Qdx = f(P_x, I, P_y, T)</math>
== Law of demand and changes in demand ==


Which is a functional relationship where the quantity demanded by the consumer <math>Qdx</math> depends on the price of the good <math>P_x</math>, the monetary income of the consumer <math>I</math>, the prices of other goods <math>P_y</math>, and the taste of the consumer <math>T</math>.
The law of demand states that, other things remaining same, the quantity demanded of a good increases when its price falls and vice-versa. Note that demand for goods changes as a consequence of changes in income, tastes etc. Hence, the demand may sometime expand or contract and increase or decrease. In this context, let us make a distinction between two different types of changes that affect quantity demanded, viz., expansion and contraction; and increase and decrease.


Another common way to express the law of demand [[Revealed preference|without imposing a functional form]] is the following:<ref>{{Cite book |last=Mas-Colell |first=Andreu |url=https://www.worldcat.org/oclc/32430901 |title=Microeconomic theory |date=1995 |others=Michael Dennis Whinston, Jerry R. Green |isbn=0-19-507340-1 |location=New York |oclc=32430901}}</ref>
While stating the law of demand i.e., while treating price as the causative factor, the relevant terms are Expansion and Contraction in demand. When demand is changing due to aprice change alone, we should not say increase or decrease but expansion or contraction. If one of the nonprice determinants of demand, such as the prices of other goods, income, etc. change & thereby demand changes, the relevant terms are increase and decrease in demand. The expansion and contraction in demand are shown in the diagram. You may observe that expansion and contraction are shown on a single DD curve. The changes (movements) take place along the given curve.


:<math>(p'-p)(x'-x)\leq 0</math>
== Determinants of demand ==


This formula states that, for all possible prices p' and p, and corresponding demands x' and x, prices and demand must move in opposite directions, i.e. as price increases, demand must decrease and vice versa. Note that demands are demand ''bundles'', not individual demands. Demand for a single good can still increase even though its price also increased, if there is another good whose price increased and which is sufficiently substituted away from. If good i is a Giffen good whose price increases while other goods' prices are held fixed (so that <math display="inline">p_j'-p_j=0 \; \forall j\neq i</math>), the law of demand is clearly violated, as we have both <math display="inline">p_i'-p_i>0</math> (as price increased) and <math display="inline">q_i'-q_i>0</math> (as we consider a Giffen good), so that <math display="inline">(p'-p)(x'-x)=(p_i'-p_i)(x_i'-x_i)>0</math>.
After having understood the nature of demand and law of demand, it is easy to ascertain the determinants of demand. We have mentioned above that an individual demand for a commodity depends on desire for the commodity and his capability to purchase it. The desire to purchase is revealed by tastes and preferences of the individuals. The capability to purchase depends upon his purchasing power, which in turn depends upon his income and price of the commodity. Since an individual purchases a number of commodities, how much quantity of a particular commodity he chooses to purchase depends upon the price of that particular commodity and prices of the other commodities, beside his income?


== Demand versus supply ==
So, the amount demanded (per unit of time) of a commodity depends upon


On the one hand, demand refers to the [[demand curve]]. Changes in supply are depicted graphically by a shift in the supply curve to the left or right.<ref name=":0" /> Changes in the demand curve are usually caused by 5 major factors, namely: number of buyers, consumer income, tastes or preferences, price of related goods and future expectations. [[File:Quantity demanded.jpg|thumb|A change in quantity demanded is shown by a movement along the existing demand curve. By starting out at P1, the associated willingness to purchase or quantity demanded is Q1. Now, if price goes up to P2, there is a lower willingness to purchase i.e., quantity demanded is Q2. The demand curve itself did not change since both the combination of P1Q1 and P2Q2 were already a part of the existing demand curve.]]
=== Prices of related commodities ===
On the other hand, quantity demanded refers to a specific point located on the demand curve which corresponds to a specific price. Therefore, quantity demanded represents the exact quantity of a good or service demanded by a consumer at a particular price, conditional on the other determinants. A change in quantity demanded can be indicated by a movement along the existing demand curve that is caused only by a change in price.
When a change in price of the other commodity leaves the amount demanded of the commodity under consideration unchanged, we say that the two commodities are unrelated, otherwise these are related. The related commodities are of two types’ substitutes and complements. When the price of one commodity and the quantity demanded of the other commodity move in the same direction (i.e., both increase together and decrease together).


For instance, let's take the example of a housing market. An increase or decrease in price of housing will not shift the demand curve rather it will cause a movement along the demand curve for housing i.e. change in quantity demanded. But if we look at mortgage rates (a factor other than price), even if housing prices remain unchanged, an increased mortgage rate leads to a lower willingness to buy at all prices, shifting the demand curve to the left. Consumers will buy less, even though the price is the same.<ref name=":5">{{Cite web|title=Changes in Supply and Demand {{!}} Microeconomics|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmopen-microeconomics/chapter/changes-in-supply-and-demand/|access-date=2021-04-25|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref> On the other hand, lower mortgage rate leads to a higher willingness to buy at all prices, and eventually shifting the demand curve to the right.<ref>{{Cite web|title=Video: Change in Demand vs. Change in Quantity Demanded {{!}} Introduction to Business|url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/wmintrobusiness/chapter/video-change-in-demand-vs-change-in-quantity-demanded/|access-date=2021-04-24|website=courses.lumenlearning.com}}</ref> Consumers will now buy more, even though the price has not changed at all.<ref name=":5" /> Such variation in demand can be explained by demand elasticity.
=== Income of the individual ===
The '''amount demanded of a commodity''' also depends upon the income of an individual. With an increase in income, increased amount of most of the commodities in his consumption bundle, though the extent of the increase may differ between commodities.


== Demand elasticity ==
=== Tastes and preferences ===
The elasticity of demand refers to the sensitivity of a goods demand as compared to the fluctuation of other economic factors, such as price, income, etc. The law of demand explains that the relationship between Demand and Price is directly inverse. However, the demand for some goods are more receptive to a change in price than others. There are four major elasticities of demand, these being the price elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand, cross elasticity of demand, and advertising elasticity of demand.<ref name="mundanopedia.com"/>
It is quite well that the change in tastes and preferences of consumers in favor of a commodity results in smaller demand for the commodity. Modern business firms, which sell product with different brand names, rely a great deal on influencing tastes and preferences of households in favor of their products (with the help of advertisements, etc.) in order to bring about increase in demand of their products.


=== Tastes of the consumers ===
===Price elasticity of demand===
The variation in demand with regards to a change in price is known as the [[price elasticity of demand]]. The formula to solve for the coefficient of price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in Price.
The amount demanded also depends on consumer’s taste. Tastes include fashion, habit, customs, etc. A consumer’s taste is also affected by advertisement. If the taste for a commodity goes up, its amount demanded is more even at the same price and vice-versa.


:<math>E_{\langle p \rangle} = \frac{\Delta Q/Q}{\Delta P/P}</math>
=== Wealth ===
The amount demanded of a commodity is also affected by the amount of wealth as well as its distribution. The wealthier are the people, higher is the demand for normal commodities. If wealth is more equally distributed, the demand for necessaries and comforts is more. On the other hand, if some people are rich, while the majority is poor, the demand for luxuries is generally less.


Price elasticity of demand can be classified as elastic, inelastic, or unitary. An elastic demand occurs when the percentage change in the quantity demanded is greater than the percentage change in price, meaning that a small change in price results in a large change in quantity demanded. Inelastic demand occurs when the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in price. Unitary elasticity occurs when the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price.
=== Expectations regarding the future ===
If consumers expect changes in price of a commodity in future, they will change the demand at present even when the present price remains the same. Similarly, if consumers expect their incomes to rise in the near future, they may increase the demand for a commodity just now.


Factors affecting price elasticity of demand include the availability of substitute goods, the proportion of income spent on the good, the nature of the good (whether it's a necessity or a luxury), and the time horizon under consideration.<ref>{{Cite web |title=Price Elasticity of Demand Meaning, Types, and Factors That Impact It |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/p/priceelasticity.asp |access-date=2023-04-18 |website=Investopedia |language=en}}</ref>
=== Climate and weather ===
The climate of an area and the weather prevailing there has a decisive effect on consumer’s demand. In cold areas, woolen cloth is demanded. During hot summer days, ice is very much in demand. On a rainy day, ice-cream is not so much demanded.


=== State of business ===
===Cross elasticity of demand===
The [[cross elasticity of demand]] is an economic concept that measures the relative change in demand of a good when another good varies in price. The formula to solve for the coefficient of cross elasticity of demand is calculated by dividing the percentage change in quantity demanded of good A by the percentage change in price of good B.
The level of demand for different commodities also depends upon the business conditions in the country. If the country is passing through boom conditions, there will be a marked increase in demand. On the other hand, the level of demand goes down during depression.


:<math>\text{Cross-price Elasticity Of Demand}
==Aggregate consumer demand or market demand==
= \frac{\%\text{ change in quantity demanded of good A}}{\%\text{ change in price of good B}}</math>


The Cross elasticity of demand, also commonly referred to as the Cross-price elasticity of demand, allows companies to establish competitive prices against [[substitute good]]s and [[complementary good]]s. The metric figure produced by the equation thus determines the strength of both the relationship and competition between the two goods.<ref name="Hayes.A, 2021">{{cite web |last1=Hayes |first1=Adam |title=Cross Elasticity of Demand |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/cross-elasticity-demand.asp#:~:text=our%20editorial%20policies-,What%20Is%20Cross%20Elasticity%20of%20Demand%3F,price%20for%20another%20good%20changes. |website=Investopedia |access-date=28 April 2022}}</ref>
The market (also aggregate consumer) demand function is derived by adding all individual consumer demand functions. Aggregation adds three other non price determinants of demand - (1) the number of consumers (2) "the distribution of tastes among consumers" and (3) "the distribution of income among consumers of different tastes."<ref> Binger & Hoffman, Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. (Addison-Wesley 1998) at 154-55.</ref> Thus if the population of consumers increases all other things being held constant the market demand curve will shift out. Likewise, if the income distribution were to change in favor of a group of consumers with strong taste for same good "there would be an increase in demand for that good relative to other goods."<ref> Binger & Hoffman, Microeconomics with Calculus, 2nd ed. (Addison-Wesley 1998) at 155.</ref>


===Income elasticity of demand===
The factors that affect individual demand also affect market demand although the net effect can be ambiguous.
[[Income elasticity of demand]] is an economic measurement tool developed to measure the sensitivity of a goods quantity demanded when there is a change in the real income of a consumer. To calculate the income elasticity of demand, the percentage change in quantity demanded is divided by the percentage change in the consumers income.


:<math>\epsilon_d = \frac{\%\ \mbox{change in quantity demanded}}{\%\ \mbox{change in income}}</math>
== Macro concepts of demand ==
Individual demand, firms demand and industry demand are the micro concepts of demand. This is useful to manager in decision making as to determination of size of supplies etc. However, a manger has to know the macro concepts of demand as he operates within the macroeconomic environment. As such he much understands a few macro concepts of demand. As a matter of fact, national demand may influence the industry demand which in its turn may influence the firms demand.
Some of the important macro-concepts of demand are illustrated below.


The Income elasticity of demand allows businesses to analyse and further predict the impact of business cycles on total sales.<ref name="Hayes.Alex,21">{{cite web |last1=Hayes |first1=A |title=Income Elasticity of Demand |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/i/incomeelasticityofdemand.asp |website=Investopedia |access-date=29 April 2022}}</ref> The Income elastitcty of demand thus allows goods to be broadly categorised as [[Normal good]]s and [[Inferior good]]s. A positive measurement suggests that the good is a normal good, and a negative measurement suggests an inferior good. The Income elasticity of demand effectively represents a consumers idea as to whether a good is a luxury or a necessity.
=== Effective demand ===
This refers to the aggregate volume of demand in an economy, (size of the market), which induces the manufacturers to adjust that demand by supply. Thus if demand is ‘effective’, it should create employment, induce output and generate income in the economy.


=== Consumption demand ===
===Advertising elasticity of demand===
[[Advertising elasticity of demand]] measures the effectiveness of an advertising campaign as to generate new sales. To calculate the Advertising elasticity of demand, the percentage change in quantity demanded is divided by the percentage change in advertising expenditures.<ref name="Kenton, W. AED">{{cite web |last1=Kenton |first1=Will |title=Advertising Elasticity of Demand (AED) |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/advertising-elasticity-of-demand.asp |website=Investopedia |access-date=28 April 2022}}</ref>
It is a component of the effective demand. It is concerned with the demand for consumer goods i.e., consumption expenditure of a nation which depends on national income.


:<math>AED = \frac{\%\ \mbox{change in quantity demanded}}{\%\ \mbox{change in spending on advertising}} = \frac{\Delta Q_d/Q_d}{\Delta A/A} </math>
=== Investment demand ===
It is another component of effective demand. It has reference to the demand for investment goods i.e., investment expenditure in the national economy which is dependent on the net return on investment.


A business utilises the advertising elasticity of demand to measure the effectiveness of advertising on generating new sales. A positive elasticity indicates success for the advertisement as demand for the goods has increased. However, this measurement is also subject to the availability of substitutes, [[consumer behaviour]]s and price points of the good being advertised.<ref name="Kenton, W. AED"/>
=== Demand for money ===
This refers to desire to hold money (liquidity) in hand. In any of the three motives i.e., transaction, precaution or speculation. Accordingly, we may speak of transaction demand for money to meet day-to-day exchange transactions. The precautionary demand for moneys to meet contingency requirements. The speculative demand for money has got long-term business use; it is mostly influenced by the market rate of interest. In fact, the rate of interest is the opportunity costs of holding money in hand for speculative purposes.


=== Demand for bonds ===
== Exceptions to the law of demand ==
The elasticity of demand follows the law of demand and its definition. However, there are goods and specific situations that defy the law of demand. Generally, the amount demanded of a good increases with a decrease in price of the good and vice versa. In some cases this may not be true. There are certain goods which do not follow the law of demand. These include [[Giffen goods]], [[Veblen good]]s, basic or necessary goods and expectations of future price changes. Further exception and details are given in the sections below:
Since money and bonds are substitutes, the demand for bonds is related to the demand for money.


== Limitation ==
===Giffen goods===
* Change in taste or fashion.
* Change in income
* Change in other prices.
* Discovery of substitution.
* Anticipatory change in prices.
* Rare or distinction goods.<ref>{{cite book
| last = Sullivan
| first = Arthur
| authorlink = Arthur O' Sullivan
| coauthors = Steven M. Sheffrin
| title = Economics: Principles in action
| publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall
| date = 2003
| location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey
| pages = 552
| url = http://www.pearsonschool.com/index.cfm?locator=PSZ3R9&PMDbSiteId=2781&PMDbSolutionId=6724&PMDbCategoryId=&PMDbProgramId=12881&level=4
| doi =
| id =
| isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref>


Initially proposed by [[Sir Robert Giffen]], economists disagree on the existence of [[Giffen good]]s in the market. A Giffen good describes an inferior good that, as the price increases, demand for the product increases. As an example, during the [[Great Famine (Ireland)|Great Famine of Ireland]] of the 19th century, potatoes were considered a Giffen good. Potatoes were the largest staple in the Irish diet, so as the price rose it had a large impact on income. People responded by cutting out on [[luxury good]]s such as meat and vegetables, and instead bought more potatoes. Therefore, as the price of potatoes increased, so did the quantity demanded.<ref>{{cite book|last=Mankiw|first=Gregory|title=Principles of Economics|year=2007|publisher=South-Western Cengage Learning|isbn=978-0-324-22472-6|pages=470}}</ref> This results in an upward sloping demand curve contrary to the fundamental law of demand.<ref>{{Cite web|last=Andrew Bloomenthal|title=Getting Familiar with Giffen Goods|url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/g/giffen-good.asp|access-date=2021-04-22|website=Investopedia|language=en}}</ref>
There are certain goods which do not follow this law. These include [[Veblen goods]] and [[Giffen goods]and Etc.]


Giffen goods violate the law of demand due to the [[income effect]] dominating the [[substitution effect]]. This can be illustrated with the [[Slutsky equation]] for a change in a good's own price:
==See also==
{{portal|Business and economics|EUR 1 (2007 issue).png}}
*[[Supply and Demand]]


:<math>
==References==

\frac{\partial x_i}{\partial p_i} = \frac{\partial h_i}{\partial p_i} - \frac{\partial x_i}{\partial m}x_i

</math>

The first term on the right-hand side is the substitution effect, which is always negative. The second term on the right side is the income effect, which can be positive or negative. For inferior goods, this is negative, so subtracting this means adding its positive absolute value. The non-derivative component of the income effect is a measure of a consumer's existing demand for the good, meaning that if a consumer spends a large amount of his income on an inferior good, then a price increase could cause the income effect to dominate the substitution effect. This leads to a positive partial derivative of the good's demand with regards to its price, which violates the law of demand.

===Expectation of change in the price of commodity===
If an increase in the price of a commodity causes households to expect the price of a commodity to increase further, they may start purchasing a greater amount of the commodity even at the presently increased price.<ref name=":2" /> Similarly, if the household expects the price of the commodity to decrease, it may postpone its purchases. Thus, some argue that the law of demand is violated in such cases. In this case, the demand curve does not slope down from left to right; instead, it presents a backward slope from the top right to down left. This curve is known as an exceptional demand curve.

===Basic or necessary goods===
The goods which people need no matter how high the price is are basic or necessary goods. Medicines covered by insurance are a good example. An increase or decrease in the price of such a good does not affect its quantity demanded.

===Certain scenarios in stock trading===
Stock buyers acting in accord with the [[Hot hand|hot-hand fallacy]] will increase buying when stock prices are trending upward.<ref name="Johnson2005">{{cite journal|last=Johnson|first=Joseph|author2=Tellis, G.J. |author3=Macinnis, D.J. |title=Losers, Winners, and Biased Trades|journal=Journal of Consumer Research|year=2005|volume=2|issue=32|pages=324–329|doi=10.1086/432241|s2cid=145211986}}</ref> Other rationales for buying a high-priced stock are that previous buyers who bid up the price are proof of the issue's quality, or conversely, that an issue's low price may be evidence of viability problems. Likewise, demand among short traders during a [[short squeeze]] can increase as price increases.

=== Veblen goods ===

[[File:SC06 2006 Rolls-Royce Phantom.jpg|thumb|Named after the American economist [[Thorstein Veblen]], Veblen goods are luxury items. They are perceived as status symbols and include diamonds and luxury cars.<ref>{{Cite web|last=IsEqualTo|title=IsEqualTo - A complete Education App for students|url=https://isequalto.com/|access-date=2021-04-24|website=isequalto.com|language=en}}</ref>]]
Unlike [[Giffen good]]s, which are inferior items, [[Veblen goods]] are generally high quality goods. The demand for Veblen goods increases with the increase in price. Examples of Veblen goods are mostly luxurious items such as diamond, gold, precious stones, world-famous paintings, antiques etc.<ref name=":2" /> Veblen goods appear to go against the law of demand because of their exclusivity appeal, in the sense that if a price of a luxurious and expensive product is increased, it may attract the status-conscious group more, since it will be further out of reach for an average consumer. [[Thorstein Veblen]] referred to this sort of consumption as the purchase of goods that do not exhibit additional utility or functionality but offer status and reveal socioeconomic position.<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal|last1=Currid‐Halkett|first1=Elizabeth|last2=Lee|first2=Hyojung|last3=Painter|first3=Gary D.|date=2019|title=Veblen goods and urban distinction: The economic geography of conspicuous consumption|journal=Journal of Regional Science|language=en|volume=59|issue=1|pages=83–117|doi=10.1111/jors.12399|s2cid=158494416 |issn=1467-9787|doi-access=free}}</ref> In simple words, these goods are not bought for their satisfaction but for their "snob appeal" or "ostentation".<ref name=":3" /> Accordingly, all these factors also lead to an upward sloping demand curve for Veblen goods along a certain price range.

[[Gary S. Becker]] and [[Kevin M. Murphy]] analysed Veblen goods. Their analysis of the demand for paintings by masters and for other objects proves Veblen by relying heavily on the allocative role of prices in markets with social interactions.<ref>Becker, G. S. & Murphy, K. M. (2000). {{Citation|date=2000-01-08|pages=8–15|publisher=Harvard University Press|isbn=978-0-674-00337-8|title=Social Economics: market behavior in a social environment}}</ref>

== See also ==
{{Portal|Business and economics}}
* [[Revealed preference]]
* [[Aggregation problem]]
* [[Representative agent]]
* [[Methodological individualism]]
* [[Demand (economics)]]
* [[Price–performance ratio]]
* Second law of demand ([[price elasticity]] over time)
* Third Law of Demand ([[Alchian–Allen effect]])
* [[Supply and demand]]
* [[Law of supply]]
* [[Tragedy of the commons]]

== References ==
{{Reflist}}
{{Reflist}}


{{Microeconomics}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Law Of Demand}}
{{Population}}
[[Category:Economics terminology]]
{{Authority control}}
[[Category:Economic term stubs]]

[[Category:Microeconomics]]
[[Category:Economics laws]]
[[Category:Demand]]

Latest revision as of 04:21, 11 October 2024

The demand curve, shown in blue, is sloping downwards from left to right because price and quantity demanded are inversely related. This relationship is contingent on certain conditions remaining constant. The supply curve, shown in orange, intersects with the demand curve at price (Pe) = 80 and quantity (Qe)= 120. Pe = 80 is the equilibrium price at which quantity demanded is equal to the quantity supplied. Similarly, Qe = 120 is the equilibrium quantity at which the quantity demanded and supplied are at the equilibrium price. Therefore, the intersection of the demand and supply curves provide us with the efficient allocation of goods in an economy.

In microeconomics, the law of demand is a fundamental principle which states that there is an inverse relationship between price and quantity demanded. In other words, "conditional on all else being equal, as the price of a good increases (↑), quantity demanded will decrease (↓); conversely, as the price of a good decreases (↓), quantity demanded will increase (↑)".[1] Alfred Marshall worded this as: "When we say that a person's demand for anything increases, we mean that he will buy more of it than he would before at the same price, and that he will buy as much of it as before at a higher price".[2] The law of demand, however, only makes a qualitative statement in the sense that it describes the direction of change in the amount of quantity demanded but not the magnitude of change.

The law of demand is represented by a graph called the demand curve, with quantity demanded on the x-axis and price on the y-axis. Demand curves are downward sloping by definition of the law of demand. The law of demand also works together with the law of supply to determine the efficient allocation of resources in an economy through the equilibrium price and quantity.

The relationship between price and quantity demanded holds true so long as it is complied with the ceteris paribus condition "all else remain equal" quantity demanded varies inversely with price when income and the prices of other goods remain constant.[3] If all else are not held equal, the law of demand may not necessarily hold.[4] In the real world, there are many determinants of demand other than price, such as the prices of other goods, the consumer's income, preferences etc.[5] There are also exceptions to the law of demand such as Giffen goods and perfectly inelastic goods.

Overview

[edit]

Economist Alfred Marshall provided the graphical illustration of the law of demand.[2] This graphical illustration is still used today to define and explain a variety of other concepts and theories in economics. A simple explanation of the law of demand is that all else equal, at a higher price, consumer will demand less quantity of a good and vice versa. The law of demand applies to a variety of organisational and business situations. Price determination, government policy formation etc are examples.[6] Together with the law of supply, the law of demand provides to us the equilibrium price and quantity. Moreover, the law of demand and supply explains why goods are priced at the level that they are. They also help us identify opportunities to buy what are perceived to be underpriced (or sell overpriced) goods or assets.[7]

Law of Demand is relied heavily upon by managerial economics, which is a branch of economics that applies microeconomic analysis to managerial decision-making, to make informed decisions on pricing, production, and marketing strategies. In this context, understanding the alternative factors that influence the Law of Demand becomes crucial for managers and decision-makers.[8]

  1. Income effect: The income effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good or service as a result of changes in consumers' purchasing power. When prices increase, the purchasing power of consumers decreases, leading to a decline in the quantity demanded. Conversely, a decrease in prices will increase purchasing power and lead to an increase in the quantity demanded.
  2. Substitution effect: The substitution effect is the change in the quantity demanded of a good or service due to a change in the relative prices of substitute goods. When the price of a good increases, consumers may shift their consumption to relatively cheaper substitute goods, causing the demand for the original good to decrease.
  3. Price expectations: Consumer expectations about future prices can influence their current demand for goods or services. If consumers expect prices to rise in the future, they may increase their current consumption to avoid higher prices later. Conversely, if they expect prices to fall, they may delay consumption, causing a decline in the quantity demanded.
  4. Market size and demographics: The size of the market and its demographics can also influence the Law of Demand. Changes in population size, age distribution, and income levels can affect the overall demand for goods or services, thus impacting the relationship between price and quantity demanded.

Demand refers to the demand curve. A change in demand is indicated by a shift in the demand curve. Quantity demanded, on the other hand refers to a specific point on the demand curve which corresponds to a specific price. A change in quantity demanded therefore refers to a movement along the existing demand curve. However, there are some exceptions to the law of demand. For instance, if the price of cigarettes goes up, its demand does not decrease. The exceptions to the law of demand typically suit the Giffen commodities and Veblen goods which is further explained below.

The four main types of elasticity of demand are price elasticity of demand, cross elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand, and advertising elasticity of demand.[3]

History

[edit]

The famous law of demand was first stated by Charles Davenant (1656-1714) in his essay, "Probable Methods of Making People Gainers in the Balance of Trade (1699)".[9] However, there were instances of its understanding and use much earlier when Gregory King (1648-1712) made a demonstration of the law of demand. He represented a relationship between the price of wheat and the harvest where the results suggested that if the harvest falls by 50%, the price would rise by 500%. This demonstration illustrated the law of demand as well as its elasticity.[10]

Skipping forward to 1890, economist Alfred Marshall documented the graphical illustration of the law of demand.[2] In Principles of Economics (1890), Alfred Marshall reconciled the demand and supply into a single analytical framework. The formulation of the demand curve was provided by the utility theory while supply curve was determined by the cost. This idea of demand and supply curve is what we still use today to develop the market equilibrium and to support a variety of other economic theories and concepts. Due to general agreement with the observation, economists have come to accept the validity of the law under most situations. Economist also see Alfred Marshall as the pioneer of the standard demand and supply diagrams and their use in economic analysis including welfare applications and consumer surplus.[10]

Anything that affects the buying decision other than the product price will shift the demand curve. Considering our example of mortgage rates; with a higher mortgage rate, demand curve will shift to the left from D0 to D1. This means that there is less demand for the housing market at every price. On the other hand, with lower mortgage rate demand curve shifts to the right from D0 to D2, meaning there is more demand for the housing market at every price.

Mathematical description

[edit]

Consider the function , where is the quantity demanded of good , is the demand function, is the price of the good and is the list of parameters other than the price.

The law of demand states that . Here is the partial derivative operator.[1]

The above equation, when plotted with quantity demanded () on the -axis and price () on the -axis, gives the demand curve, which is also known as the demand schedule. The demand curve is downward sloping illustrating the inverse relationship between quantity demanded and price. Therefore, a downward sloping demand curve embeds the law of demand.

In a more specific manner:[3]

Which is a functional relationship where the quantity demanded by the consumer depends on the price of the good , the monetary income of the consumer , the prices of other goods , and the taste of the consumer .

Another common way to express the law of demand without imposing a functional form is the following:[11]

This formula states that, for all possible prices p' and p, and corresponding demands x' and x, prices and demand must move in opposite directions, i.e. as price increases, demand must decrease and vice versa. Note that demands are demand bundles, not individual demands. Demand for a single good can still increase even though its price also increased, if there is another good whose price increased and which is sufficiently substituted away from. If good i is a Giffen good whose price increases while other goods' prices are held fixed (so that ), the law of demand is clearly violated, as we have both (as price increased) and (as we consider a Giffen good), so that .

Demand versus supply

[edit]

On the one hand, demand refers to the demand curve. Changes in supply are depicted graphically by a shift in the supply curve to the left or right.[1] Changes in the demand curve are usually caused by 5 major factors, namely: number of buyers, consumer income, tastes or preferences, price of related goods and future expectations.

A change in quantity demanded is shown by a movement along the existing demand curve. By starting out at P1, the associated willingness to purchase or quantity demanded is Q1. Now, if price goes up to P2, there is a lower willingness to purchase i.e., quantity demanded is Q2. The demand curve itself did not change since both the combination of P1Q1 and P2Q2 were already a part of the existing demand curve.

On the other hand, quantity demanded refers to a specific point located on the demand curve which corresponds to a specific price. Therefore, quantity demanded represents the exact quantity of a good or service demanded by a consumer at a particular price, conditional on the other determinants. A change in quantity demanded can be indicated by a movement along the existing demand curve that is caused only by a change in price.

For instance, let's take the example of a housing market. An increase or decrease in price of housing will not shift the demand curve rather it will cause a movement along the demand curve for housing i.e. change in quantity demanded. But if we look at mortgage rates (a factor other than price), even if housing prices remain unchanged, an increased mortgage rate leads to a lower willingness to buy at all prices, shifting the demand curve to the left. Consumers will buy less, even though the price is the same.[12] On the other hand, lower mortgage rate leads to a higher willingness to buy at all prices, and eventually shifting the demand curve to the right.[13] Consumers will now buy more, even though the price has not changed at all.[12] Such variation in demand can be explained by demand elasticity.

Demand elasticity

[edit]

The elasticity of demand refers to the sensitivity of a goods demand as compared to the fluctuation of other economic factors, such as price, income, etc. The law of demand explains that the relationship between Demand and Price is directly inverse. However, the demand for some goods are more receptive to a change in price than others. There are four major elasticities of demand, these being the price elasticity of demand, income elasticity of demand, cross elasticity of demand, and advertising elasticity of demand.[3]

Price elasticity of demand

[edit]

The variation in demand with regards to a change in price is known as the price elasticity of demand. The formula to solve for the coefficient of price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in quantity demanded divided by the percentage change in Price.

Price elasticity of demand can be classified as elastic, inelastic, or unitary. An elastic demand occurs when the percentage change in the quantity demanded is greater than the percentage change in price, meaning that a small change in price results in a large change in quantity demanded. Inelastic demand occurs when the percentage change in quantity demanded is smaller than the percentage change in price. Unitary elasticity occurs when the percentage change in quantity demanded is equal to the percentage change in price.

Factors affecting price elasticity of demand include the availability of substitute goods, the proportion of income spent on the good, the nature of the good (whether it's a necessity or a luxury), and the time horizon under consideration.[14]

Cross elasticity of demand

[edit]

The cross elasticity of demand is an economic concept that measures the relative change in demand of a good when another good varies in price. The formula to solve for the coefficient of cross elasticity of demand is calculated by dividing the percentage change in quantity demanded of good A by the percentage change in price of good B.

The Cross elasticity of demand, also commonly referred to as the Cross-price elasticity of demand, allows companies to establish competitive prices against substitute goods and complementary goods. The metric figure produced by the equation thus determines the strength of both the relationship and competition between the two goods.[15]

Income elasticity of demand

[edit]

Income elasticity of demand is an economic measurement tool developed to measure the sensitivity of a goods quantity demanded when there is a change in the real income of a consumer. To calculate the income elasticity of demand, the percentage change in quantity demanded is divided by the percentage change in the consumers income.

The Income elasticity of demand allows businesses to analyse and further predict the impact of business cycles on total sales.[16] The Income elastitcty of demand thus allows goods to be broadly categorised as Normal goods and Inferior goods. A positive measurement suggests that the good is a normal good, and a negative measurement suggests an inferior good. The Income elasticity of demand effectively represents a consumers idea as to whether a good is a luxury or a necessity.

Advertising elasticity of demand

[edit]

Advertising elasticity of demand measures the effectiveness of an advertising campaign as to generate new sales. To calculate the Advertising elasticity of demand, the percentage change in quantity demanded is divided by the percentage change in advertising expenditures.[17]

A business utilises the advertising elasticity of demand to measure the effectiveness of advertising on generating new sales. A positive elasticity indicates success for the advertisement as demand for the goods has increased. However, this measurement is also subject to the availability of substitutes, consumer behaviours and price points of the good being advertised.[17]

Exceptions to the law of demand

[edit]

The elasticity of demand follows the law of demand and its definition. However, there are goods and specific situations that defy the law of demand. Generally, the amount demanded of a good increases with a decrease in price of the good and vice versa. In some cases this may not be true. There are certain goods which do not follow the law of demand. These include Giffen goods, Veblen goods, basic or necessary goods and expectations of future price changes. Further exception and details are given in the sections below:

Giffen goods

[edit]

Initially proposed by Sir Robert Giffen, economists disagree on the existence of Giffen goods in the market. A Giffen good describes an inferior good that, as the price increases, demand for the product increases. As an example, during the Great Famine of Ireland of the 19th century, potatoes were considered a Giffen good. Potatoes were the largest staple in the Irish diet, so as the price rose it had a large impact on income. People responded by cutting out on luxury goods such as meat and vegetables, and instead bought more potatoes. Therefore, as the price of potatoes increased, so did the quantity demanded.[18] This results in an upward sloping demand curve contrary to the fundamental law of demand.[19]

Giffen goods violate the law of demand due to the income effect dominating the substitution effect. This can be illustrated with the Slutsky equation for a change in a good's own price:

The first term on the right-hand side is the substitution effect, which is always negative. The second term on the right side is the income effect, which can be positive or negative. For inferior goods, this is negative, so subtracting this means adding its positive absolute value. The non-derivative component of the income effect is a measure of a consumer's existing demand for the good, meaning that if a consumer spends a large amount of his income on an inferior good, then a price increase could cause the income effect to dominate the substitution effect. This leads to a positive partial derivative of the good's demand with regards to its price, which violates the law of demand.

Expectation of change in the price of commodity

[edit]

If an increase in the price of a commodity causes households to expect the price of a commodity to increase further, they may start purchasing a greater amount of the commodity even at the presently increased price.[6] Similarly, if the household expects the price of the commodity to decrease, it may postpone its purchases. Thus, some argue that the law of demand is violated in such cases. In this case, the demand curve does not slope down from left to right; instead, it presents a backward slope from the top right to down left. This curve is known as an exceptional demand curve.

Basic or necessary goods

[edit]

The goods which people need no matter how high the price is are basic or necessary goods. Medicines covered by insurance are a good example. An increase or decrease in the price of such a good does not affect its quantity demanded.

Certain scenarios in stock trading

[edit]

Stock buyers acting in accord with the hot-hand fallacy will increase buying when stock prices are trending upward.[20] Other rationales for buying a high-priced stock are that previous buyers who bid up the price are proof of the issue's quality, or conversely, that an issue's low price may be evidence of viability problems. Likewise, demand among short traders during a short squeeze can increase as price increases.

Veblen goods

[edit]
Named after the American economist Thorstein Veblen, Veblen goods are luxury items. They are perceived as status symbols and include diamonds and luxury cars.[21]

Unlike Giffen goods, which are inferior items, Veblen goods are generally high quality goods. The demand for Veblen goods increases with the increase in price. Examples of Veblen goods are mostly luxurious items such as diamond, gold, precious stones, world-famous paintings, antiques etc.[6] Veblen goods appear to go against the law of demand because of their exclusivity appeal, in the sense that if a price of a luxurious and expensive product is increased, it may attract the status-conscious group more, since it will be further out of reach for an average consumer. Thorstein Veblen referred to this sort of consumption as the purchase of goods that do not exhibit additional utility or functionality but offer status and reveal socioeconomic position.[22] In simple words, these goods are not bought for their satisfaction but for their "snob appeal" or "ostentation".[22] Accordingly, all these factors also lead to an upward sloping demand curve for Veblen goods along a certain price range.

Gary S. Becker and Kevin M. Murphy analysed Veblen goods. Their analysis of the demand for paintings by masters and for other objects proves Veblen by relying heavily on the allocative role of prices in markets with social interactions.[23]

See also

[edit]

References

[edit]
  1. ^ a b c Nicholson, Walter; Snyder, Christopher (2012). Microeconomic Theory: Basic Principles and Extensions (11 ed.). Mason, OH: South-Western. pp. 27, 154. ISBN 978-111-1-52553-8.
  2. ^ a b c Marshall Abhishek, Alfred (1892). Elements of economics of industry. London: Macmillan. pp. 77, 79.
  3. ^ a b c d "Law of Demand: What it is, Definition, Examples". Mundanopedia. 2021-12-31. Retrieved 2022-01-01.
  4. ^ "The Law of Demand | Introduction to Business [Deprecated]". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-20.
  5. ^ http://www.investopedia.com/terms/l/lawofdemand.asp; Investopedia, Retrieved 9 September 2013
  6. ^ a b c "Law of demand: Statement, explanation and exceptions". The Fact Factor. 2019-03-04. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  7. ^ Hayes, Adam. "Law of Demand Definition". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-04-21.
  8. ^ "What Is the Law of Demand in Economics, and How Does It Work?". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-18.
  9. ^ Creedy, John (1986). "On the King-Davenant "Law" of Demand1". Scottish Journal of Political Economy. 33 (3): 193–212. doi:10.1111/j.1467-9485.1986.tb00826.x. ISSN 1467-9485.
  10. ^ a b "A Very Brief History of Demand and Supply". Worthwhile Canadian Initiative. Retrieved 2021-04-21.
  11. ^ Mas-Colell, Andreu (1995). Microeconomic theory. Michael Dennis Whinston, Jerry R. Green. New York. ISBN 0-19-507340-1. OCLC 32430901.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
  12. ^ a b "Changes in Supply and Demand | Microeconomics". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-25.
  13. ^ "Video: Change in Demand vs. Change in Quantity Demanded | Introduction to Business". courses.lumenlearning.com. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  14. ^ "Price Elasticity of Demand Meaning, Types, and Factors That Impact It". Investopedia. Retrieved 2023-04-18.
  15. ^ Hayes, Adam. "Cross Elasticity of Demand". Investopedia. Retrieved 28 April 2022.
  16. ^ Hayes, A. "Income Elasticity of Demand". Investopedia. Retrieved 29 April 2022.
  17. ^ a b Kenton, Will. "Advertising Elasticity of Demand (AED)". Investopedia. Retrieved 28 April 2022.
  18. ^ Mankiw, Gregory (2007). Principles of Economics. South-Western Cengage Learning. p. 470. ISBN 978-0-324-22472-6.
  19. ^ Andrew Bloomenthal. "Getting Familiar with Giffen Goods". Investopedia. Retrieved 2021-04-22.
  20. ^ Johnson, Joseph; Tellis, G.J.; Macinnis, D.J. (2005). "Losers, Winners, and Biased Trades". Journal of Consumer Research. 2 (32): 324–329. doi:10.1086/432241. S2CID 145211986.
  21. ^ IsEqualTo. "IsEqualTo - A complete Education App for students". isequalto.com. Retrieved 2021-04-24.
  22. ^ a b Currid‐Halkett, Elizabeth; Lee, Hyojung; Painter, Gary D. (2019). "Veblen goods and urban distinction: The economic geography of conspicuous consumption". Journal of Regional Science. 59 (1): 83–117. doi:10.1111/jors.12399. ISSN 1467-9787. S2CID 158494416.
  23. ^ Becker, G. S. & Murphy, K. M. (2000). Social Economics: market behavior in a social environment, Harvard University Press, 2000-01-08, pp. 8–15, ISBN 978-0-674-00337-8