Jump to content

Full employment: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Jdevine (talk | contribs)
The NAIRU: clarification, correction.
Employment-to-population ratio
 
(154 intermediate revisions by 92 users not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
{{short description|Economic situation in which there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment}}
[[Image:Circulation in macroeconomics.svg|thumb|350px|Diagram of macroeconomic circulation. ''L''<sub>S</sub> ≤ ''L''<sub>D</sub> is the full employment situation, one in which the rate of unemployment is zero or negative (corresponding to a labor shortfall).]]
'''Full employment''' is an [[Economy|economic]] situation in which there is no [[Cyclical unemployment|cyclical]] or [[unemployment#Cyclical unemployment|deficient-demand unemployment]].<ref>{{Citation | last1 = O'Sullivan | first1 = Arthur | author-link = Arthur O'Sullivan (economist) | first2 = Steven M. | last2 = Sheffrin | author-link2 = Steven M. Sheffrin | title = Economics: Principles in Action | publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall | year = 2003 | location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey | page = 335 | isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref> Full employment does not entail the disappearance of all unemployment, as other kinds of unemployment, namely [[Structural unemployment|structural]] and [[Frictional unemployment|frictional]], may remain. Full employment does not entail 100% [[employment-to-population ratio]]. For instance, workers who are "between jobs" for short periods of time as they search for better employment are not counted against full employment, as such unemployment is frictional rather than cyclical. An economy with full employment might also have unemployment or [[underemployment]] where [[Part-time job|part-time]] workers cannot find jobs appropriate to their skill level,<ref>E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3044448 SSRN, part 2, charts at 6, 10 and 22]</ref> as such unemployment is considered structural rather than cyclical. Full employment marks the point past which expansionary fiscal and/or [[monetary policy]] cannot reduce unemployment any further without causing [[inflation]].


Some economists define full employment somewhat differently, as the unemployment rate at which inflation does not continuously increase. Advocacy of avoiding accelerating inflation is based on a theory centered on the concept of the [[Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment|Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU)]] and those who hold it usually mean NAIRU when speaking of full employment.<ref>{{Citation | last = Coe | first = David T | title = Nominal Wages. The NAIRU and Wage Flexibility. | publisher = Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development | url = http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/59/19/33917832.pdf }}</ref><ref>{{Cite web | url=https://www.vox.com/2014/11/14/7027823/nairu-natural-rate-unemployment | title=The NAIRU, explained: Why economists don't want unemployment to drop too low | date=14 November 2014 }}</ref> The NAIRU has also been described by [[Milton Friedman]], among others, as the "natural" rate of unemployment. Such views tend to emphasize [[Sustainability#Economic sustainability|sustainability]], noting that a government cannot sustain unemployment rates below the NAIRU forever: inflation will continue to grow so long as unemployment lies below the NAIRU.
'''Full employment''', in [[macroeconomics]], is the level of employment rates when there is no cyclical or [[unemployment#Cyclical unemployment|deficient-demand unemployment]].<ref>{{Citation
| last = Sullivan
| first = Arthur
| authorlink = Arthur O' Sullivan
| coauthors = Steven M. Sheffrin
| title = Economics: Principles in action
| publisher = Pearson Prentice Hall
| year = 2003
| location = Upper Saddle River, New Jersey 07458
| pages = 335
| url = http://www.pearsonschool.com/index.cfm?locator=PSZ3R9&PMDbSiteId=2781&PMDbSolutionId=6724&PMDbCategoryId=&PMDbProgramId=12881&level=4
| doi =
| id =
| isbn = 0-13-063085-3}}</ref> It is defined by the majority of [[mainstream economics|mainstream]] [[economists]] as being an acceptable level of unemployment somewhere above 0%. The discrepancy from 0% arises due to non-cyclical [[types of unemployment]]. Unemployment above 0% is seen as necessary to control [[inflation]], to keep inflation from ''accelerating'', i.e., from rising from year to year. This view is based on a theory centering on the concept of the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment ([[NAIRU]]); in the current era, the majority of mainstream economists mean NAIRU when speaking of "full" employment. The NAIRU has also been described by [[Milton Friedman]], among others, as the "natural" rate of unemployment.


For the United States, economist [[William T. Dickens]] found that full-employment unemployment rate varied a lot over time but equaled about 5.5 percent of the civilian labor force during the 2000s.<ref>{{cite web|url=http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/papers/2009/7/unemployment%20dickens/07_unemployment_dickens.pdf |title= Unemployment Dickens |access-date=2013-06-28 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20150416005807/http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/papers/2009/7/unemployment%20dickens/07_unemployment_dickens.pdf |archive-date=2015-04-16 }}</ref> Recently, economists have emphasized the idea that full employment represents a "range" of possible unemployment rates. For example, in 1999, in the United States, the [[Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development]] (OECD) gives an estimate of the "full-employment unemployment rate" of 4 to 6.4%. This is the estimated unemployment rate at full employment, plus or minus the [[standard error]] of the estimate.<ref>{{Cite journal |date=December 2000 |title=V. Revised OECD measures of structural unemployment |url=http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/50/2086120.pdf |journal=OECD Economic Outlook |issue=68 |pages=155-168 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20050219121855/http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/50/2086120.pdf |archive-date=19 February 2005}}</ref>
The 20th century British economist [[William Beveridge]] stated that an [[Unemployment_rate#Measurement|unemployment rate]] of 3% was full employment. Other economists have provided estimates between 2% and 13%, depending on the country, time period, and their political biases. For the United States, economist [[William T. Dickens]] found that full-employment unemployment rate varied a lot over time but equaled about 5.5 percent of the civilian labor force during the 2000s.<ref> http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/papers/2009/7/unemployment%20dickens/07_unemployment_dickens.pdf </ref>


The concept of full employment of labor corresponds to the concept of [[potential output]] or potential real GDP and the long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve. In [[neoclassical economics| neoclassical]] macroeconomics, the highest sustainable level of aggregate real GDP or "potential" is seen as corresponding to a vertical LRAS curve: any increase in the demand for real GDP can only lead to rising prices in the long run, while any increase in output is temporary.
The concept of full employment of labor corresponds to the concept of [[potential output]] or potential [[Real gross domestic product|real GDP]] and the [[Aggregate supply#Different scopes|long run aggregate supply (LRAS)]] curve. In [[neoclassical economics|neoclassical]] macroeconomics, the highest sustainable level of aggregate real GDP or "potential" is seen as corresponding to a vertical LRAS curve: any increase in the demand for real GDP can only lead to rising prices in the long run, while any increase in output is temporary.


== Economic concept ==
== Economic concept ==
What most [[neoclassical economics|neoclassical economists]] mean by "full" employment is a rate somewhat less than 100% employment. Others, such as the late [[James Tobin]], have been accused of disagreeing, considering full employment as 0% unemployment.<ref>"As a young professor I did a paper where I analyzed the optimal unemployment rate," said [[Joseph Stiglitz]], a professor at [[Columbia University]] in New York, who knew Tobin at [[Yale university|Yale]]. "Tobin went livid over the idea. To him the optimal unemployment rate was zero."
What most [[neoclassical economics|neoclassical economists]] mean by "full" employment is a rate somewhat less than 100% employment. Others, such as the late [[James Tobin]], have been accused of disagreeing, considering full employment as 0% unemployment.<ref>"As a young professor I did a paper where I analyzed the optimal unemployment rate," said [[Joseph Stiglitz]], a professor at [[Columbia University]] in New York, who knew Tobin at [[Yale University|Yale]]. "Tobin went livid over the idea. To him the optimal unemployment rate was zero."
[http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601109&sid=ajz1hV_afuSQ Yale’s Tobin Guides Obama From Grave as Friedman Is Eclipsed]</ref> However, this was not Tobin's perspective in his later work.<ref> See, for example, "Inflation and Unemployment" by James Tobin, ''The American Economic Review'', Vol. 62, No. 1/2 (Mar. 1, 1972), pp. 1-18.</ref>
[https://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601109&sid=ajz1hV_afuSQ Yale's Tobin Guides Obama From Grave as Friedman Is Eclipsed]</ref> However, this was not Tobin's perspective in his later work.<ref>See, for example, "Inflation and Unemployment" by James Tobin, ''The American Economic Review'', Vol. 62, No. 1/2 (Mar. 1, 1972), pp. 1-18.</ref>


Some see [[John Maynard Keynes]] as attacking the existence of rates of unemployment substantially above 0%:
Some see [[John Maynard Keynes]] as attacking the existence of rates of unemployment substantially above 0%:
:"The Conservative belief that there is some law of nature which prevents men from being employed, that it is 'rash' to employ men, and that it is financially 'sound' to maintain a tenth of the population in idleness for an indefinite period, is crazily improbable - the sort of thing which no man could believe who had not had his head fuddled with nonsense for years and years. The objections which are raised are mostly not the objections of experience or of practical men. They are based on highly abstract theories – venerable, academic inventions, half misunderstood by those who are applying them today, and based on assumptions which are contrary to the facts… Our main task, therefore, will be to confirm the reader’s instinct that what seems sensible is sensible, and what seems nonsense is nonsense."
:"The Conservative belief that there is some law of nature which prevents men from being employed, that it is 'rash' to employ men, and that it is financially 'sound' to maintain a tenth of the population in idleness for an indefinite period, is crazily improbable - the sort of thing which no man could believe who had not had his head fuddled with nonsense for years and years. The objections which are raised are mostly not the objections of experience or of practical men. They are based on highly abstract theories – venerable, academic inventions, half misunderstood by those who are applying them today, and based on assumptions which are contrary to the facts… Our main task, therefore, will be to confirm the reader's instinct that what seems sensible is sensible, and what seems nonsense is nonsense." – J. M. Keynes and [[H. D. Henderson]] in a pamphlet to support [[Lloyd George]] in the 1929 election.<ref>{{cite book|last1=Keynes|first1=J. M.|author-link1=John Maynard Keynes|last2=Henderson|first2=H. D.|author-link2=Hubert Henderson|title=Can Lloyd George Do It? The Pledge Examined|year=1929|publisher=The Nation and Athenæum|location=London|pages=10–11|chapter=II: The Common Sense of the Problem}}</ref>
:– J.M. Keynes in a pamphlet to support [[Lloyd George]] in the 1929 election.


Most readers would interpret this statement as referring to only cyclical, [[cyclical unemployment | deficient-demand]], or "involuntary" unemployment (discussed below) but not to unemployment existing as "full employment" (mismatch and frictional unemployment). This is because, writing in 1929, Keynes was discussing a period in which the unemployment rate had been persistently above most conceptions of what corresponds to full employment. That is, a situation where a tenth of the population (and thus a larger percentage of the [[labor force]]) is unemployed involves a disaster.
Most readers would interpret this statement as referring to only cyclical, [[cyclical unemployment|deficient-demand]], or "involuntary unemployment" (discussed below) but not to unemployment existing as "full employment" (mismatch and frictional unemployment). This is because, writing in 1929, Keynes was discussing a period in which the unemployment rate had been persistently above most conceptions of what corresponds to full employment. That is, a situation where a tenth of the population (and thus a larger percentage of the [[labor force]]) is unemployed involves a disaster.


One major difference between Keynes and the [[Classical economics | Classical economists]] was that while the latter saw "full employment" as the normal state of affairs with a free-market economy (except for short periods of adjustment), Keynes saw the possibility of persistent aggregate-demand failure causing unemployment rates to exceed those corresponding to full employment. Put differently, while Classical economists saw all unemployment as "voluntary," Keynes saw the possibility that involuntary unemployment can exist when the demand for final products is low compared to potential output.
One major difference between Keynes and the [[Classical economics|Classical economists]] was that while the latter saw "full employment" as the normal state of affairs with a free-market economy (except for short periods of adjustment), Keynes saw the possibility of persistent aggregate-demand failure causing unemployment rates to exceed those corresponding to full employment. Put differently, while Classical economists saw all unemployment as "voluntary", Keynes saw the possibility that [[involuntary unemployment]] can exist when the demand for final products is low compared to potential output.
This can be seen in his later and more serious work. In his ''General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money,''<ref>See http://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/keynes/general-theory/index.htm </ref> In chapter 2, he used a definition that should be familiar to modern macroeconomics:
This can be seen in his later and more serious work. In his ''General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money'', chapter 2, he used a definition that should be familiar to modern macroeconomics:
:This state of affairs we shall describe as ‘full’ employment, both ‘frictional’ and ‘voluntary’ unemployment being consistent with ‘full’ employment thus defined.<ref> See http://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/keynes/general-theory/ch02.htm </ref>
:This state of affairs we shall describe as "full" employment, both "frictional" and "voluntary" unemployment being consistent with "full" employment thus defined.<ref name="johnmaynardkeynes">{{cite web |url=http://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/keynes/general-theory/ |title=The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money |author=John Maynard Keynes}}</ref>
The only difference from the usual definitions is that, as discussed below, most economists would add skill/location mismatch or [[structural unemployment]] as existing at full employment. More theoretically,Keynes had two main definitions of full employment, which he saw as equivalent. His first main definition of full employment involves the absence of "involuntary" unemployment.
The only difference from the usual definitions is that, as discussed below, most economists would add skill/location mismatch or [[structural unemployment]] as existing at full employment. More theoretically, Keynes had two main definitions of full employment, which he saw as equivalent. His first main definition of full employment involves the absence of "involuntary" unemployment:


: the equality of the real wage to the marginal disutility of employment ... realistically interpreted, corresponds to the absence of ‘involuntary’ unemployment. <ref> See http://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/keynes/general-theory/ch02.htm </ref>
: the equality of the real wage to the marginal disutility of employment ... realistically interpreted, corresponds to the absence of "involuntary" unemployment.<ref name="johnmaynardkeynes"/>


Put another way, the full employment and the absence of involuntary unemployment correspond to the case where the real wage equals the marginal cost to workers of supplying labor for hire on the market (the "marginal disutility of employment"). That is, the real wage rate and the amount of employment correspond to a point on the aggregate supply curve of labor that is assumed to exist. In contrast, a situation with less than full employment and thus involuntary unemployment would have the real wage above the supply price of labor. That is, the employment situation corresponds to a point above and to the left of the aggregate supply curve of labor: the real wage would be above the point on the aggregate supply curve of labor at the current level of employment; alternatively, the level of employment would be below the point on that supply curve at the current real wage.
Put another way, the full employment and the absence of involuntary unemployment correspond to the case where the real wage equals the marginal cost to workers of supplying labor for hire on the market (the "marginal disutility of employment"). That is, the real wage rate and the amount of employment correspond to a point on the aggregate supply curve of labor that is assumed to exist. In contrast, a situation with less than full employment and thus involuntary unemployment would have the real wage above the supply price of labor. That is, the employment situation corresponds to a point above and to the left of the aggregate supply curve of labor: the real wage would be above the point on the aggregate supply curve of labor at the current level of employment; alternatively, the level of employment would be below the point on that supply curve at the current real wage.


Second, in chapter 3, Keynes saw full employment as a situation where "a further increase in the value of the effective demand will no longer be accompanied by any increase in output."
Second, in chapter 3, Keynes saw full employment as a situation where "a further increase in the value of the effective demand will no longer be accompanied by any increase in output."
: In the previous chapter we have given a definition of full employment in terms of the behavior of labor. An alternative, though equivalent, criterion is that at which we have now arrived, namely a situation, in which aggregate employment is inelastic in response to an increase in the effective demand for its output.<ref> See http://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/keynes/general-theory/ch03.htm </ref>
: In the previous chapter we have given a definition of full employment in terms of the behavior of labor. An alternative, though equivalent, criterion is that at which we have now arrived, namely a situation, in which aggregate employment is inelastic in response to an increase in the effective demand for its output.<ref name="johnmaynardkeynes"/>


This means that at and above full employment, any increase in aggregate demand and employment corresponds primarily to increases in prices rather than output. Thus, full employment of labor corresponds to potential output.
This means that at and above full employment, any increase in aggregate demand and employment corresponds primarily to increases in prices rather than output. Thus, full employment of labor corresponds to potential output.

Before [[Milton Friedman]] and [[Edmund Phelps]], [[Abba Lerner]] {{Harv|Lerner|1951|loc=Chapter 15}} developed a version of the NAIRU. Unlike the current view, Lerner saw a range of "full employment" unemployment rates. He distinguished between "high" full employment (the lowest sustainable unemployment under [[incomes policies]]) and "low" full employment (the lowest sustainable unemployment rate without these policies).


Whilst full employment is often an aim for an economy, most economists see it as more beneficial to have some level of unemployment, especially of the frictional sort. In theory, this keeps the labor market flexible, allowing room for new innovations and investment. As in the NAIRU theory, the existence of some unemployment is required to avoid accelerating inflation.
Whilst full employment is often an aim for an economy, most economists see it as more beneficial to have some level of unemployment, especially of the frictional sort. In theory, this keeps the labor market flexible, allowing room for new innovations and investment. As in the NAIRU theory, the existence of some unemployment is required to avoid accelerating inflation.


==Historical measurement and discussion==
== Technical terms ==
For the United Kingdom, the [[OECD]] estimated the NAIRU (or structural unemployment) rate as being equal to 8.5% on average between 1988 and 1997, 5.9% between 1998 and 2007, 6.2%, 6.6%, and 6.7 in 2008, 2009, and 2010, then staying at 6.9% in 2011–2013. For the United States, they estimate it as being 5.8% on average between 1988 and 1997, 5.5% between 1998 and 2007, 5.8% in 2008, 6.0% in 2009, and then staying at 6.1% from 2010 to 2013. They also estimate the NAIRU for other countries.<ref>http://www.oecd.org/eco/outlook/economicoutlookannextables.htm table 22. These estimates are done using the commonly-used definition of unemployment rather than using the measures based on efforts to standardize the measure of unemployment across countries.</ref> These calculations have been criticised as lacking any foundation in evidence.<ref>E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3044448 SSRN, part 2(1)]</ref>


The era after the 2007-2009 [[Great Recession]] shows the relevance of this concept, for example as seen in the United States. On the one hand, in 2013 [[Keynesian]] economists such as [[Paul Krugman]] of [[Princeton University]] see unemployment rates as too high relative to full employment and the NAIRU and thus favor increasing the aggregate demand for goods and services and thus labor in order to reduce unemployment. On the other hand, pointing to shortages of some skilled workers, some businesspeople and [[Classical economists]] suggest that the U.S. economy is already at full employment, so that any demand stimulus will lead to nothing but rising inflation rates. One example was [[Narayana Kocherlakota]], President of the Minneapolis [[Federal Reserve Bank]], who has since changed his mind.<ref>{{cite web|url=https://www.chicagotribune.com/2012/10/09/how-a-fed-inflation-hawk-changed-his-mind/|title=How a Fed inflation hawk changed his mind|newspaper=Chicago Tribune|date=9 October 2012 }}</ref>
=== "Ideal" unemployment ===


== Unemployment and inflation ==
An alternative, more normative, definition (used by some labor economists) would see "full employment" as the attainment of the ''ideal'' unemployment rate, where the types of unemployment that reflect labor-market inefficiency (such as mismatch or [[unemployment types#Structural unemployment|structural unemployment]]) do not exist. That is, only some ''frictional'' or voluntary unemployment would exist, where workers are temporarily searching for new jobs and are thus voluntarily unemployed. This type of unemployment involves workers "shopping" for the best jobs at the same time that employers "shop" for the best possible employees to serve their needs. Its existence can allow the best possible correspondence between workers and jobs from the points of view of both employees and employers and thus promotes the economy's [[efficiency]].
{{Tone|section|date=September 2020}}


=== Unemployment at Beveridge Full Employment ===
=== Unemployment at Beveridge Full Employment ===
{{More citations needed section|date=September 2020}}
{{Main|Unemployment#Definitions, types, and theories}}
[[William Beveridge]] defined "full employment" as where the number of unemployed workers equaled the number of job vacancies available (while preferring that the economy be kept above that full employment level in order to allow maximum economic production).


Lord [[William Beveridge]] defined "full employment" as where the number of unemployed workers equaled the number of job vacancies available (while preferring that the economy be kept above that full employment level in order to allow maximum economic production). But the point is that this definition allows for ''some'' unemployment. To see this, assume that frictional and mismatch unemployment can be separated. At Beveridge full employment, in the case of ''frictional'' unemployment the number of job-seekers corresponds to an equal number of job openings: as discussed above, the unemployed are "shopping" for the best possible jobs (as long as the cost of job-search is less than the expected benefit) at the same time that employers are "shopping" for the best possible employees to fill the vacancies. Similarly,at Beveridge full employment, the number of people suffering from mismatch or [[unemployment types#Structural unemployment|structural unemployment]] equals the number of vacancies. The problem here is that the the skills and geographical locations of the unemployed workers does not correspond to the skill requirements and locations of the vacancies. In theory, Beveridge's concept full employment corresponds to that of Keynes (discussed above).
This definition allows for certain kinds of unemployment, where the number of unemployed workers equals the number of vacancies. Unemployment of this kind can take two forms: [[unemployment types#Frictional unemployment|frictional]] and [[unemployment types#Structural unemployment|structural]]. Frictional unemployment is where the unemployed are searching for the best possible jobs whilst employers are also searching for the best possible employees to fulfil those jobs. Structural unemployment exists when the skills and geographical locations of the unemployed workers do not correspond to the skill requirements and locations of the vacancies. In either case, there exists a job for every worker, and a worker for every job.


The situation with less that full employment in Beveridge's sense results either from [[unemployment types#Classical unemployment|"Classical" unemployment]] or "neoclassical" unemployment or from Keynesian deficient-demand unemployment. In terms of supply and demand, Classical or neoclassical unemployment results from the actual real wage exceeding the equilibrium real wage, so that the quantity of labor demanded (and the number of vacancies) is less than the quantity of labor supplied (and the number of unemployed workers). In the ''Classical'' theory, the problem is that real wages are rigid, i.e., do not fall due to an excess supply of labor. In theory, this might happen because of minimum wage laws and other interference with "free markets" that prevent the attainment of market perfection. Classical economists favor making labor markets more like the ideal competitive market -- and so making real wages more flexible -- in order to deal with this kind of unemployment.
An economy with less than full employment in Beveridge's sense will have either [[unemployment types#Real wage unemployment|classical unemployment]], [[unemployment types#Cyclical unemployment|cyclical unemployment]], or both. Classical unemployment results from the actual real wage rising above the equilibrium real wage, so that the quantity of labor demanded (and the number of vacancies) is less than the quantity of labor supplied (and the number of unemployed workers). This might occur because of [[Pareto-efficiency|inefficient]] interference in the market; for example, a minimum wage set above the equilibrium wage; but also because of [[market failure]], such as that caused by [[cartel]]s.


Under classical unemployment, the ways by which a return to Beveridge full employment can occur depend on the nature of the rise in wages- if it is only "nominal" wages that are rigid (failing to return to equilibrium), then real wages can decrease if prices rise relative to the rigid nominal wages. If nominal wages track price levels, however, then changes to prices will not affect the real wage- and thus employment will remain below Beveridge full employment.
The neoclassical theory, in contrast, follows [[John Maynard Keynes]] and more importantly, [[Milton Friedman]] to blame inflexible ''money'' or ''nominal'' wages for low employment relative to full employment. If the money wage is fixed, the real wage is fixed for any given average price level, so that rigid money wages have the same effect as rigid real wages when the price level is given. In this case, however, real wages can be depressed (and Beveridge full employment restored) if prices rise relative to nominal wages. Alternatively, people could wait for the persistence of high unemployment to eventually cause money wages to fall. This would have the same effect, reducing real wages and increasing the quantity of labor demanded. One of the big debates in macroeconomics is whether it is better to deal with neoclassical unemployment using a small amount of inflation or by waiting for markets to adjust.


Cyclical, deficient-demand, or Keynesian unemployment occurs when there is not enough aggregate demand in the economy to provide jobs for everyone who wants to work. If demand for most goods and services falls, less production is needed and consequently fewer workers are needed: if wages are [[sticky prices|sticky]] and do not fall to meet the new equilibrium level, unemployment results, because (as with classical unemployment) there are more prospective workers than there are vacancies.<ref name="Keynes 2007">{{cite book|title=The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money |last=Keynes |first=John Maynard |year=2007 |orig-year=1936 |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan |location=Basingstoke, Hampshire |isbn=978-0-230-00476-4 |url=http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/keynescont.htm |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090316094655/http://cepa.newschool.edu/het/essays/keynes/keynescont.htm |archive-date=16 March 2009}}</ref>
In contrast, Keynesian deficient-demand unemployment (as explained by [[Don Patinkin]]) sees a situation with less than full employment (following Beveridge's definition) as possibly prevailing ''even if'' the actual real wage is equal to the equilibrium real wage at full employment. The problem is that the demand for final products is limited by [[aggregate demand]] failure. Low demand for products (below potential output) implies that there is a sales constraint on the labor market to the left of equilibrium so that the quantity of labor demanded is below the amount that would be demanded if the aggregate demand for products was sufficient (what [[Robert Clower]] called the ''notional'' demand for labor). In terms of neoclassical theory, the prevailing real wage is less than the marginal physical product of labor in this situation. In the absence of the sales constraint, profit-maximizing employers would hire unemployed workers as long as this inequality is true, moving the labor markets toward full employment. However, the sales constraint means that the extra product of these workers ''could not be sold''. Thus, employers would not hire the unemployed until aggregate demand role, which would shift the sales constraint to the right, allowing more employment of labor. In this situation, Keynesians recommend policies that raise the aggregate demand for final products and thus the aggregate demand for workers.

=== The Phillips curve ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=September 2020}}
The theories behind the [[Phillips curve]] pointed to the inflationary costs of lowering the unemployment rate. That is, as unemployment rates fell and the economy approached full employment, the [[inflation]] rate would rise. But this theory also says that there is no single unemployment number that one can point to as the "full employment" rate. Instead, there is a [[trade-off]] between unemployment and inflation: a government might choose to attain a lower unemployment rate but would pay for it with higher inflation rates. In essence, in this view, the meaning of “full employment” is really nothing but a matter of opinion based on how the benefits of lowering the unemployment rate compare to the costs of raising the inflation rate.

Though their theory had been proposed by the Keynesian economist [[Abba Lerner]] several years before,<ref>{{Harv|Lerner|1951|loc=Chapter 15}}</ref> it was the work of [[Milton Friedman]], leader of the [[monetarist]] school of economics, and [[Edmund Phelps]] that ended the popularity of this concept of full employment. In 1968, Friedman posited the theory that full employment rate of unemployment was '''''unique''''' at any given time. He called it the "natural" rate of unemployment. Instead of being a matter of opinion and normative judgment, it is something we are stuck with, even if it is unknown. As discussed further, below, inflation/unemployment trade-offs cannot be relied upon. Further, rather than trying to attain full employment, Friedman argues that policy-makers should try to keep prices stable (meaning a low or even a zero inflation rate). If this policy is sustained, he suggests that a free-market economy will gravitate to the "natural" rate of unemployment automatically.


=== The NAIRU ===
=== The NAIRU ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=September 2020}}
{{main|NAIRU}}
{{main|NAIRU}}


[[Image:NAIRU-SR-and-LR.svg|thumb|right|200px|[[Phillips Curve]] before and after Expansionary Policy, with Long-Run Phillips Curve ([[NAIRU]])]]
[[Image:NAIRU-SR-and-LR.svg|thumb|right|200px|[[Phillips Curve]] before and after Expansionary Policy, with Long-Run Phillips Curve ([[NAIRU]])]]


James Tobin (following the lead of Franco Modigliani), introduced the term the “'''N'''on-'''A'''ccelerating '''I'''nflation '''R'''ate of '''U'''nemployment” (NAIRU), which corresponds to the situation where the real gross domestic product equals potential output. It has been called the "inflation threshold" unemployment rate or the inflation barrier. This concept is identical to [[Milton Friedman| Milton Friedman’s]] concept of the "natural" rate but reflects the fact that there is nothing "natural" about an economy. The level of the NAIRU depends on the degree of "supply side" unemployment, i.e., joblessness that can't be abolished by high demand. This includes frictional, mismatch, and Classical unemployment. When the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU, there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment. That is, Keynes’ involuntary unemployment does not exist.
In an effort to avoid the normative connotations of the word "natural," James Tobin (following the lead of Franco Modigliani), introduced the term the “'''N'''on-'''A'''ccelerating '''I'''nflation '''R'''ate of '''U'''nemployment” (NAIRU), which corresponds to the situation where the real gross domestic product equals potential output. It has been called the "inflation threshold" unemployment rate or the inflation barrier. This concept is identical to [[Milton Friedman]]’s concept of the "natural" rate but reflects the fact that there is nothing "natural" about an economy. The level of the NAIRU depends on the degree of "supply side" unemployment, i.e., joblessness that can't be abolished by high demand. This includes frictional, mismatch, and Classical unemployment. When the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU, there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment. That is, Keynes’ involuntary unemployment does not exist.


To understand this concept, start with the actual unemployment equal to the NAIRU. Then, assume that a country’s government and its [[central bank]] use demand-side policy to reduce the unemployment rate and then attempt to keep the rate at a specific low level: rising budget deficits or falling interest rates increase aggregate demand and raise employment of labor. Thus, the actual unemployment rate falls, as going from point '''A''' to '''B''' in the near-by graph. Unemployment then stays below the NAIRU for years or more, as at point '''B'''. In this situation, the theory behind the NAIRU posits that inflation will accelerate, i.e. get worse and worse (in the absence of wage and price controls). As the short-run [[Phillips Curve]] theory indicates, higher inflation rate results from low unemployment. That is, in terms of the "trade-off" theory, low unemployment can be "bought," paid for by suffering from higher inflation. But the NAIRU theory says that this is not the whole story, so that the trade-off breaks down: a persistently higher inflation rate is eventually incorporated as higher ''inflationary expectations''. Then, if workers and employers expect higher inflation, it results in higher inflation, as higher money wages are passed on to consumers as higher prices. This causes the short run [[Phillips Curve]] to shift to the right and upward, worsening the [[trade-off]] between inflation and unemployment. At a given unemployment rate, inflation accelerates. But if the unemployment rate rises to equal the NAIRU, we see higher inflation than before the expansionary policies, as at point '''C''' in the near-by diagram. The fall of the unemployment rate was temporary because it could not be sustained. In sum, the trade-off between inflation and unemployment cannot be relied upon to be stable: taking advantage of it causes it to disappear. This story fits the experience of the United States during the late 1960s, during which unemployment rates stayed low (below 4% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates rose significantly.
To understand this concept, start with the actual unemployment equal to the NAIRU. Then, assume that a country's government and its [[central bank]] use demand-side policy to reduce the unemployment rate and then attempt to keep the rate at a specific low level: rising budget deficits or falling interest rates increase aggregate demand and raise employment of labor. Thus, the actual unemployment rate falls, as going from point '''A''' to '''B''' in the nearby graph. Unemployment then stays below the NAIRU for years or more, as at point '''B'''. In this situation, the theory behind the NAIRU posits that inflation will accelerate, i.e. get worse and worse (in the absence of wage and price controls). As the short-run [[Phillips curve]] theory indicates, higher inflation rate results from low unemployment. That is, in terms of the "trade-off" theory, low unemployment can be "bought," paid for by suffering from higher inflation. But the NAIRU theory says that this is not the whole story, so that the trade-off breaks down: a persistently higher inflation rate is eventually incorporated as higher ''inflationary expectations''. Then, if workers and employers expect higher inflation, it results in higher inflation, as higher money wages are passed on to consumers as higher prices. This causes the short run Phillips curve to shift to the right and upward, worsening the [[trade-off]] between inflation and unemployment. At a given unemployment rate, inflation accelerates. But if the unemployment rate rises to equal the NAIRU, we see higher inflation than before the expansionary policies, as at point '''C''' in the nearby diagram. The fall of the unemployment rate was temporary because it could not be sustained. In sum, the trade-off between inflation and unemployment cannot be relied upon to be stable: taking advantage of it causes it to disappear. This story fits the experience of the United States during the late 1960s, during which unemployment rates stayed low (below 4% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates rose significantly.


Second, examine the other main case. Again start with the unemployment rate equal to the NAIRU. Then, either shrinking government budget deficits (or rising government surpluses) or rising real interest rates encourage higher unemployment. In this situation, the NAIRU theory says that inflation will get better (decelerate) if unemployment rates exceed the NAIRU for a long time. High unemployment leads to lower inflation, which in turn causes lower inflationary expectations and a further round of lower inflation. High unemployment causes the short-run inflation/unemployment trade-off to improve. This story fits the experience of the United States during the early 1980s ([[Paul Volcker]]'s war against inflation), during which unemployment rates stayed high (at about 10% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates fell significantly.
Second, examine the other main case. Again start with the unemployment rate equal to the NAIRU. Then, either shrinking government budget deficits (or rising government surpluses) or rising real interest rates encourage higher unemployment. In this situation, the NAIRU theory says that inflation will get better (decelerate) if unemployment rates exceed the NAIRU for a long time. High unemployment leads to lower inflation, which in turn causes lower inflationary expectations and a further round of lower inflation. High unemployment causes the short-run inflation/unemployment trade-off to improve. This story fits the experience of the United States during the early 1980s ([[Paul Volcker]]'s war against inflation), during which unemployment rates stayed high (at about 10% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates fell significantly.


Finally, the NAIRU theory says that the inflation rate does not rise or fall when the unemployment equals the "natural" rate. This is where the term NAIRU is derived. In macroeconomics, the case where the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU is seen as the long-run [[equilibrium]] because there are no forces inside the normal workings of the economy that cause the inflation rate to rise or fall. The NAIRU corresponds to the '''long-run Phillips curve'''. While the short-run Phillips curve is based on a constant rate of inflationary expectations, the long-run Phillips curve reflects full adjustment of inflationary expectations to the actual experience of inflation in the economy.
Finally, the NAIRU theory says that the inflation rate does not rise or fall when the unemployment equals the "natural" rate. This is where the term NAIRU is derived. In macroeconomics, the case where the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU is seen as the long-run [[Economic equilibrium|equilibrium]] because there are no forces inside the normal workings of the economy that cause the inflation rate to rise or fall. The NAIRU corresponds to the ''long-run Phillips curve''. While the short-run Phillips curve is based on a constant rate of inflationary expectations, the long-run Phillips curve reflects full adjustment of inflationary expectations to the actual experience of inflation in the economy.


As mentioned above, [[Abba Lerner]] had developed a version of the NAIRU before the modern "natural" rate or NAIRU theories were developed. Unlike the currently dominant view, Lerner saw a range of "full employment" unemployment rates. Crucially, the unemployment rate depended on the economy's institution. Lerner distinguished between "high" full employment, which was the lowest sustainable unemployment under [[incomes policies]], and "low" full employment, i.e., the lowest sustainable unemployment rate without these policies.
=== Phillips curve ===


Further, it is possible that the value of the NAIRU depends on government policy, rather than being "natural" and unvarying. A government can attempt to make people "employable" by both positive means (e.g. using training courses) and negative means (e.g. cuts in unemployment insurance benefits). These policies do not necessarily create full employment. Instead, the point is to reduces the amount of mismatch unemployment by facilitating the linking of unemployed workers with the available jobs by training them and or subsidizing their moving to the geographic location of the jobs.
Ideas associated with the [[Phillips curve]] questioned the possibility and value of full employment in a society: this theory suggests that full employment—especially as defined normatively—will be associated with positive [[inflation]]. The Phillips curve tells us also that there is no single unemployment number that one can single out as the "full employment" rate. Instead, there is a [[trade-off]] between unemployment and inflation: a government might choose to attain a lower unemployment rate but would pay for it with higher inflation rates.
In 1968, [[Milton Friedman]], leader of the [[monetarist]] school of economics, and [[Edmund Phelps]] posited a unique full employment rate of unemployment, what they called the "natural" rate of unemployment. But this is seen not as a normative choice as much as something we are stuck with, even if it is unknown. Rather than trying to attain full employment, Friedman argues that policy-makers should try to keep prices stable (a low or even a zero inflation rate). If this policy is sustained, he suggests that the economy will gravitate to the "natural" rate of unemployment automatically.


In addition, the [[hysteresis (economics)|hysteresis hypothesis]] says that the NAIRU does not stay the same over time—and can change due to economic policy.<ref>Hargreaves Heap, Shawn P. (1980). Choosing the Wrong “Natural” Rate: Accelerating Inflation or Decelerating Employment and Growth? ''Economic Journal''. vol. 90 (September): 611-620.</ref> A persistently low unemployment rate makes it easier for those workers who are unemployed for "mismatch" reasons to move to where the jobs are and/or to attain the training necessary for the available vacancies (often by getting those jobs and receiving on-the-job training). On the other hand, high unemployment makes it more difficult for those workers to adjust, while hurting their morale, job-seeking skills, and the value of their work skills. Thus, some economists argue that British Prime Minister [[Margaret Thatcher]]'s anti-inflation policies using persistently high unemployment led to higher mismatch or structural unemployment and a higher NAIRU.
=== Structural unemployment ===
{{main|Structural unemployment}}
Some Economists estimate a "range" of possible unemployment rates. For example, in 1999, in the United States, the [[Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development]] (OECD) gives an estimate of the "full-employment unemployment rate" of 4 to 6.4%. This is the estimated [[structural unemployment|"structural" unemployment]] rate, (the unemployment when there is full employment), plus & minus, the [[standard error]] of the estimate. (Estimates for other countries are also available from the OECD.) [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/44/50/2086120.pdf]

===Full employability===
Full employability indicates an attempt by government to make people "employable" by both positive means (e.g. training courses) and negative means (e.g. cuts in benefits). It does not necessarily create full employment.

== Technical issues ==


=== Uncertainty ===
{{Unreferenced section|date=September 2020}}
Whatever the definition of full employment, it is difficult to discover exactly what unemployment rate it corresponds to. In the United States, for example, the economy saw stable inflation ''despite'' low unemployment during the late 1990s, contradicting most economists' estimates of the NAIRU.
Whatever the definition of full employment, it is difficult to discover exactly what unemployment rate it corresponds to. In the United States, for example, the economy saw stable inflation ''despite'' low unemployment during the late 1990s, contradicting most economists' estimates of the NAIRU.


The idea that the full-employment unemployment rate (NAIRU) is not a unique number has been seen in recent empirical research. Staiger, Stock, and Watson found that the range of possible values of the NAIRU (from 4.3 to 7.3% unemployment) was too large to be useful to macroeconomic policy-makers. [[Robert Eisner]] suggested that for 1956-95 there was a zone from about 5% to about 10% unemployment between the low-unemployment realm of accelerating inflation and the high-unemployment realm of [[disinflation]]. In between, he found that inflation falls with falling unemployment.
The idea that the full-employment unemployment rate (NAIRU) is not a unique number has been seen in recent empirical research. Staiger, Stock, and Watson found that the range of possible values of the NAIRU (from 4.3 to 7.3% unemployment) was too large to be useful to macroeconomic policy-makers. [[Robert Eisner]] suggested that for 1956-95 there was a zone from about 5% to about 10% unemployment between the low-unemployment realm of accelerating inflation and the high-unemployment realm of [[disinflation]]. In between, he found that inflation falls with falling unemployment.

Worse, the NAIRU doesn't stay the same over time—and can change due to economic policy. For example, some economists argue that British Prime Minister [[Margaret Thatcher]]'s anti-inflation policies using persistently high unemployment led to higher structural unemployment and a higher NAIRU.


== Policy ==
== Policy ==
The active pursuit of national full [[employment]] through interventionist government policies is associated with [[Keynesian economics]] and marked the postwar agenda of many Western nations, until the [[stagflation]] of the 1970s.
The active pursuit of national full [[employment]] through interventionist government policies is associated with [[Keynesian economics]] and marked the postwar agenda of many Western nations, until the [[stagflation]] of the 1970s. [[Active labour market policies|Interventionist full employment policies]], targeted especially at young people, remain in place in the [[Nordic countries]].<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Hummeluhr |first1=Niels |title=Youth guarantees in the Nordic countries |date=November 1997 |url=https://www.oecd.org/norway/1925599.pdf}}</ref> A commitment to full employment was also restored in the [[United Kingdom]] under [[New Labour]] (1997–2010), which manifested in the [[New Deal (United Kingdom)|New Deal]] which lasted from 1998 until 2010.


=== Australia ===
=== Australia ===
In 1945, the government of [[Australian Labor Party]] [[Prime Minister of Australia|Prime Minister]] [[John Curtin]]<ref name="Hutchens">{{Cite web |last=Hutchens |first=Gareth |date=July 17, 2021 |title=Australia once wanted its allies to commit to full employment — what happened? |url=https://www.abc.net.au/news/2021-07-18/australia-tried-to-convince-its-allies-to-pursue-full-employment/100293040 |url-status=live |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20230428160608/https://www.abc.net.au/news/2021-07-18/australia-tried-to-convince-its-allies-to-pursue-full-employment/100293040 |archive-date=April 28, 2023 |access-date=April 29, 2023 |website=[[ABC News (Australia)]]}}</ref> submitted to the [[Parliament of Australia]] the [[white paper]] ''[[White Paper on Full Employment in Australia|Full Employment in Australia]]'';<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Black |first=Laurel |date=1984 |title=Social Democracy and Full Employment: The Australian White Paper, 1945 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/27508644 |journal=Labour History |issue=46 |pages=34–51 |doi=10.2307/27508644 |jstor=27508644 |issn=0023-6942}}</ref> full employment remained the government's policy until 1975.<ref name="Hutchens"/>
[[Australia]] was the first country in the world in which full employment in a capitalist society was made official policy by its [[government]]. On May 30, 1945, The [[Australian Labor Party]] [[Prime Minister of Australia|Prime Minister]] [[John Curtin]] and his Employment Minister [[John Dedman]] proposed a [[white paper]] in the [[Australian House of Representatives]] titled [[White Paper on Full Employment|''Full Employment In Australia'']], the first time any government apart from [[totalitarianism|totalitarian]] regimes had unequivocally committed itself to providing work for any person who was willing and able to work. Conditions of full employment lasted in Australia from 1941 to 1975. This had been preceded by the [[Harvester Judgment]] (1907), establishing the [[basic wage]] (a [[living wage]]); while this earlier case was overturned, it remained influential.


=== United States ===
=== United States ===
The United States is, as a statutory matter, committed to full employment (defined as 3% unemployment for persons 20 and older, 4% for persons aged 16 and over); the government is empowered to effect this goal.<ref>"A bill to establish and translate into practical reality the right of all adult Americans able, willing, and seeking to work to full opportunity for useful paid employment at fair rates of compensation;" [[Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act]] (1978)</ref> The relevant legislation is the [[Employment Act]] (1946), initially the "Full Employment Act," later amended in the [[Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act]] (1978). The 1946 act was passed in the aftermath of [[World War II]], when it was feared that demobilization would result in a depression, as it had following [[World War I]] in the [[Depression of 1920–21]], while the 1978 act was passed following the [[1973–75 recession]] and in the midst of continuing high inflation.
The United States is, as a statutory matter, committed to full employment; the government is empowered to effect this goal.<ref>"A bill to establish and translate into practical reality the right of all adult Americans able, willing, and seeking to work to full opportunity for useful paid employment at fair rates of compensation;" [[Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act]] (1978)</ref> The relevant legislation is the [[Employment Act]] (1946), initially the "Full Employment Act," later amended in the [[Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act]] (1978). The 1946 act was passed in the aftermath of [[World War II]], when it was feared that demobilization would result in a depression, as it had following [[World War I]] in the [[Depression of 1920–21]], while the 1978 act was passed following the [[1973–75 recession]] and in the midst of continuing high inflation.


The law states that full employment is one of four economic goals, in concert with growth in production, [[price stability]], [[balance of trade]], and [[balanced budget|budget]], and that the US shall rely primarily on private enterprise to achieve these goals. Specifically, the Act is committed to an unemployment rate of no more than 3% for persons aged 20 or over and not more than 4% for persons aged 16 or over (from 1983 onwards), and the Act expressly ''allows'' (but does not ''require'') the government to create a "reservoir of public employment" to effect this level of employment. These jobs are required to be in the lower ranges of skill and pay so as to not draw the workforce away from the private sector.
The law states that full employment is one of four economic goals, in concert with growth in production, [[price stability]], [[balance of trade]], and [[balanced budget|budget]], and that the US shall rely primarily on private enterprise to achieve these goals. Specifically, the Act is committed to an unemployment rate of no more than 3% for persons aged 20 or over, and not more than 4% for persons aged 16 or over (from 1983 onwards), and the Act expressly ''allows'' (but does not ''require'') the government to create a "reservoir of public employment" to affect this level of employment. These jobs are required to be in the lower ranges of skill and pay so as to not draw the workforce away from the private sector.


However, since the passage of this Act in 1978, the US has, {{as of|2017|lc=yes}}, only briefly achieved this level of employment on the national level in the late 1990s,<ref>{{cite web|title=Bureau of Labor Statistics Data|url=https://www.bls.gov/opub/mlr/2018/article/great-recession-great-recovery.htm|website=Bureau of Labor Statistics|publisher=United States Department of Labor|access-date=15 October 2020|date=15 October 2020}}</ref> though some states have neared it or met it, nor has such a reservoir of public employment been created.
However, since the passage of this Act in 1978, the US has, {{as of|2012|lc=yes}} never achieved this level of employment on the national level, though some states have neared it or met it,<ref>[http://gretawire.foxnewsinsider.com/2012/02/01/does-47th-in-job-creation-about-gov-romney-sting-or-not-is-there-another-way-to-look-at-this] - (See the graphics from the BLS.)</ref><ref>[http://2012.talkingpointsmemo.com/2012/06/romney-jobs-record-double-standard.php] - Healey told CNN’s John King. “Using one number, this odd average of four years, to come up with 47th in the nation, doesn’t really show what happened, which is a progression toward '''a very positive downward spiral, toward full employment'''.”</ref><ref>[http://americaneedsmitt.com/2012/05/did-massachusetts-really-rank-47th-in-jobs/] - Most people may not be aware of this, but the United States Congress passed a law in 1946 called the Full Employment Act, which was later amended as part of the [[Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act]] of 1978. As part of this law, which is still on the books, the statutory definition of “full employment” was set as 4% unemployment for persons aged 16 or older. In 1999, the U.S. Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) updated and issued their definition of the “full-employment unemployment rate” as being between 4 to 6.4%. In other words, according to congressional statute and the OECD, '''the state of Massachusetts was at or very near full employment during Governor Romney’s four years in office''' – a goal that the federal government has never even come close to accomplishing in the 65 years since the [[Full Employment Act|Full Employment Act of 1946]] was made law.</ref> nor has such a reservoir of public employment been created.


=== Job guarantee ===
=== Job guarantee ===
{{Fringe section|needs to note the issues mainstream economists take issue with this policy|date=October 2020}}
{{main|Job guarantee}}
Some, particularly [[Post-Keynesian economists]]<ref>Notably at the [http://www.cfeps.org/ Center for Full Employment and Price Stability], as per references.</ref><ref>{{citation
{{main|Job guarantee}}[[Post-Keynesian economists]]<ref>Notably at the [http://www.cfeps.org/ Center for Full Employment and Price Stability], as per references.</ref><ref>{{citation
|title=The Endogenous Money Approach
|title=The Endogenous Money Approach
|last=Wray
|last=Wray
|first=L. Randall
|first=L. Randall
|issue=Working Paper No. 17
|issue=Working Paper No. 17
|month=Aug
|date=Aug 2001
|year=2001
|url=http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp/wp17.html
|url=http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp/wp17.html
|publisher=[http://www.cfeps.org/ Center for Full Employment and Price Stability]
|publisher=enter for Full Employment and Price Stability
|access-date=2009-10-05
|archive-date=2017-03-15
|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20170315203457/http://www.cfeps.org/pubs/wp/wp17.html
|url-status=dead
}}</ref> have suggested ensuring full employment via a [[job guarantee]] program, where those who are unable to find work in the private sector are employed by the government, the stock of thus employed public sector workers fulfilling the same function as the unemployed do in controlling inflation, without the human costs of unemployment.
}}</ref> have suggested ensuring full employment via a [[job guarantee]] program, where those who are unable to find work in the private sector are employed by the government, the stock of thus employed public sector workers fulfilling the same function as the unemployed do in controlling inflation, without the human costs of unemployment.


==See also==
==See also==
{{div col|colwidth=30em}}
*[[Career]]
*[[Chapter IX of the United Nations Charter]]
*[[Corporatism]]
*[[Deflation]]
*[[Employment]]
*[[Employment]]
*[[Employment Policy Convention, 1964]]
*[[False Consciousness]]
*[[International labour standard]]
*[[Job guarantee]]
*[[Labour (economics)]]
*[[Labour (economics)]]
*[[List of sovereign states by employment rate]]
*[[Marxism]]
*[[Profession]]
*[[Unemployment]]
*[[NAIBER]]
*[[Reserve army of labour]]
{{div col end}}
*[[Say's law]]
*[[Wage slavery]]


==Notes==
==Notes==
{{Reflist}}
{{Reflist|30em}}

==References==
*[[A. A. Berle]], ‘A New look at management responsibility’ (1962) 2 Human Resource Management 3
*[[William Beveridge|W. Beveridge]], ''Full Employment in a Free Society'' (1944)
* {{cite book |last=Farmer |first=Roger E. A. |chapter=Unemployment |title=Macroeconomics |location=Cincinnati |publisher=South-Western |year=1999 |edition=Second |isbn=0-324-12058-3 |pages=173–192 }}
*M. S. Eccles, ''Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections'' (1951)
*[[Michał Kalecki]], ‘Political aspects of full employment’ (1943) [http://pluto.mscc.huji.ac.il/~mshalev/ppe/Kalecki_FullEmployment.pdf 14(4) Political Quarterly 322]
* {{cite book |last1=Lerner |first1=Abba Ptachya |title=Economics of Employment |date=1951 |publisher=McGraw-Hill |location=New York|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=4BfRAAAAMAAJ |language=en}}
*E. McGaughey, ''A Casebook on Labour Law'' (Hart 2018) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3308954 ch 16]
*E. McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=3044448 SSRN, part 2(3)]
*[[Robert Reich]], ''Aftershock: The next economy and America's future'' (2012)
*[[Sidney Webb, 1st Baron Passfield|S. Webb]], ''How the Government Can Prevent Unemployment'' ([https://archive.org/stream/howgovernmentcan00webb#page/n3/mode/2up 1912])
*United Kingdom Government White Paper, ''Employment Policy'' (May 1944) Cmd 6527


==External sources==
==External sources==
{{Library resources box
|by=no
|onlinebooks=no
|others=no
|about=yes
|label=Full employment }}
* [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/27/46/18464874.pdf The OECD on measuring the NAIRU]
* [http://www.oecd.org/dataoecd/27/46/18464874.pdf The OECD on measuring the NAIRU]
* Devine, James. 2004. The "Natural" Rate of Unemployment. In Edward Fullbrook, ed., ''A Guide to What's Wrong with Economics'', London, UK: Anthem Press, 126-32.
* Devine, James. 2004. The "Natural" Rate of Unemployment. In Edward Fullbrook, ed., ''A Guide to What's Wrong with Economics'', London, UK: Anthem Press, 126–32.
* [[Robert Eisner|Eisner, Robert]]. 1997. A New View of the NAIRU. In Paul Davidson and Jan A. Kregel, eds. ''Improving the Global Economy''. Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar, 1997.
* [[Robert Eisner|Eisner, Robert]]. 1997. A New View of the NAIRU. In Paul Davidson and Jan A. Kregel, eds. ''Improving the Global Economy''. Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar, 1997.
* Friedman, Milton. 1968. The Role of Monetary Policy. ''American Economic Review''. 58(1) March: 1-21.
* Friedman, Milton. 1968. The Role of Monetary Policy. ''American Economic Review''. 58(1) March: 1-21.
* Lerner, Abba. 1951. ''Economics of Employment'', New York: McGraw-Hill.
* McConnell, Brue, and Flynn. Microeconomics 19th edition. 2012.
* McConnell, Brue, and Flynn. Microeconomics 19th edition. 2012.
* Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 1997. The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary Policy. ''Journal of Economic Perspectives''. 11(1) Winter: 33-49.
* Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 1997. The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary Policy. ''Journal of Economic Perspectives''. 11(1) Winter: 33–49.

{{employment}}

{{Authority control}}


{{DEFAULTSORT:Full Employment}}
{{DEFAULTSORT:Full Employment}}
[[Category:Macroeconomics]]
[[Category:Full employment| ]]
[[Category:Labor economics| ]]
[[Category:Macroeconomic policy]]

Latest revision as of 01:22, 30 November 2024

Full employment is an economic situation in which there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment.[1] Full employment does not entail the disappearance of all unemployment, as other kinds of unemployment, namely structural and frictional, may remain. Full employment does not entail 100% employment-to-population ratio. For instance, workers who are "between jobs" for short periods of time as they search for better employment are not counted against full employment, as such unemployment is frictional rather than cyclical. An economy with full employment might also have unemployment or underemployment where part-time workers cannot find jobs appropriate to their skill level,[2] as such unemployment is considered structural rather than cyclical. Full employment marks the point past which expansionary fiscal and/or monetary policy cannot reduce unemployment any further without causing inflation.

Some economists define full employment somewhat differently, as the unemployment rate at which inflation does not continuously increase. Advocacy of avoiding accelerating inflation is based on a theory centered on the concept of the Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment (NAIRU) and those who hold it usually mean NAIRU when speaking of full employment.[3][4] The NAIRU has also been described by Milton Friedman, among others, as the "natural" rate of unemployment. Such views tend to emphasize sustainability, noting that a government cannot sustain unemployment rates below the NAIRU forever: inflation will continue to grow so long as unemployment lies below the NAIRU.

For the United States, economist William T. Dickens found that full-employment unemployment rate varied a lot over time but equaled about 5.5 percent of the civilian labor force during the 2000s.[5] Recently, economists have emphasized the idea that full employment represents a "range" of possible unemployment rates. For example, in 1999, in the United States, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) gives an estimate of the "full-employment unemployment rate" of 4 to 6.4%. This is the estimated unemployment rate at full employment, plus or minus the standard error of the estimate.[6]

The concept of full employment of labor corresponds to the concept of potential output or potential real GDP and the long run aggregate supply (LRAS) curve. In neoclassical macroeconomics, the highest sustainable level of aggregate real GDP or "potential" is seen as corresponding to a vertical LRAS curve: any increase in the demand for real GDP can only lead to rising prices in the long run, while any increase in output is temporary.

Economic concept

[edit]

What most neoclassical economists mean by "full" employment is a rate somewhat less than 100% employment. Others, such as the late James Tobin, have been accused of disagreeing, considering full employment as 0% unemployment.[7] However, this was not Tobin's perspective in his later work.[8]

Some see John Maynard Keynes as attacking the existence of rates of unemployment substantially above 0%:

"The Conservative belief that there is some law of nature which prevents men from being employed, that it is 'rash' to employ men, and that it is financially 'sound' to maintain a tenth of the population in idleness for an indefinite period, is crazily improbable - the sort of thing which no man could believe who had not had his head fuddled with nonsense for years and years. The objections which are raised are mostly not the objections of experience or of practical men. They are based on highly abstract theories – venerable, academic inventions, half misunderstood by those who are applying them today, and based on assumptions which are contrary to the facts… Our main task, therefore, will be to confirm the reader's instinct that what seems sensible is sensible, and what seems nonsense is nonsense." – J. M. Keynes and H. D. Henderson in a pamphlet to support Lloyd George in the 1929 election.[9]

Most readers would interpret this statement as referring to only cyclical, deficient-demand, or "involuntary unemployment" (discussed below) but not to unemployment existing as "full employment" (mismatch and frictional unemployment). This is because, writing in 1929, Keynes was discussing a period in which the unemployment rate had been persistently above most conceptions of what corresponds to full employment. That is, a situation where a tenth of the population (and thus a larger percentage of the labor force) is unemployed involves a disaster.

One major difference between Keynes and the Classical economists was that while the latter saw "full employment" as the normal state of affairs with a free-market economy (except for short periods of adjustment), Keynes saw the possibility of persistent aggregate-demand failure causing unemployment rates to exceed those corresponding to full employment. Put differently, while Classical economists saw all unemployment as "voluntary", Keynes saw the possibility that involuntary unemployment can exist when the demand for final products is low compared to potential output. This can be seen in his later and more serious work. In his General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money, chapter 2, he used a definition that should be familiar to modern macroeconomics:

This state of affairs we shall describe as "full" employment, both "frictional" and "voluntary" unemployment being consistent with "full" employment thus defined.[10]

The only difference from the usual definitions is that, as discussed below, most economists would add skill/location mismatch or structural unemployment as existing at full employment. More theoretically, Keynes had two main definitions of full employment, which he saw as equivalent. His first main definition of full employment involves the absence of "involuntary" unemployment:

the equality of the real wage to the marginal disutility of employment ... realistically interpreted, corresponds to the absence of "involuntary" unemployment.[10]

Put another way, the full employment and the absence of involuntary unemployment correspond to the case where the real wage equals the marginal cost to workers of supplying labor for hire on the market (the "marginal disutility of employment"). That is, the real wage rate and the amount of employment correspond to a point on the aggregate supply curve of labor that is assumed to exist. In contrast, a situation with less than full employment and thus involuntary unemployment would have the real wage above the supply price of labor. That is, the employment situation corresponds to a point above and to the left of the aggregate supply curve of labor: the real wage would be above the point on the aggregate supply curve of labor at the current level of employment; alternatively, the level of employment would be below the point on that supply curve at the current real wage.

Second, in chapter 3, Keynes saw full employment as a situation where "a further increase in the value of the effective demand will no longer be accompanied by any increase in output."

In the previous chapter we have given a definition of full employment in terms of the behavior of labor. An alternative, though equivalent, criterion is that at which we have now arrived, namely a situation, in which aggregate employment is inelastic in response to an increase in the effective demand for its output.[10]

This means that at and above full employment, any increase in aggregate demand and employment corresponds primarily to increases in prices rather than output. Thus, full employment of labor corresponds to potential output.

Whilst full employment is often an aim for an economy, most economists see it as more beneficial to have some level of unemployment, especially of the frictional sort. In theory, this keeps the labor market flexible, allowing room for new innovations and investment. As in the NAIRU theory, the existence of some unemployment is required to avoid accelerating inflation.

Historical measurement and discussion

[edit]

For the United Kingdom, the OECD estimated the NAIRU (or structural unemployment) rate as being equal to 8.5% on average between 1988 and 1997, 5.9% between 1998 and 2007, 6.2%, 6.6%, and 6.7 in 2008, 2009, and 2010, then staying at 6.9% in 2011–2013. For the United States, they estimate it as being 5.8% on average between 1988 and 1997, 5.5% between 1998 and 2007, 5.8% in 2008, 6.0% in 2009, and then staying at 6.1% from 2010 to 2013. They also estimate the NAIRU for other countries.[11] These calculations have been criticised as lacking any foundation in evidence.[12]

The era after the 2007-2009 Great Recession shows the relevance of this concept, for example as seen in the United States. On the one hand, in 2013 Keynesian economists such as Paul Krugman of Princeton University see unemployment rates as too high relative to full employment and the NAIRU and thus favor increasing the aggregate demand for goods and services and thus labor in order to reduce unemployment. On the other hand, pointing to shortages of some skilled workers, some businesspeople and Classical economists suggest that the U.S. economy is already at full employment, so that any demand stimulus will lead to nothing but rising inflation rates. One example was Narayana Kocherlakota, President of the Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank, who has since changed his mind.[13]

Unemployment and inflation

[edit]

Unemployment at Beveridge Full Employment

[edit]

William Beveridge defined "full employment" as where the number of unemployed workers equaled the number of job vacancies available (while preferring that the economy be kept above that full employment level in order to allow maximum economic production).

This definition allows for certain kinds of unemployment, where the number of unemployed workers equals the number of vacancies. Unemployment of this kind can take two forms: frictional and structural. Frictional unemployment is where the unemployed are searching for the best possible jobs whilst employers are also searching for the best possible employees to fulfil those jobs. Structural unemployment exists when the skills and geographical locations of the unemployed workers do not correspond to the skill requirements and locations of the vacancies. In either case, there exists a job for every worker, and a worker for every job.

An economy with less than full employment in Beveridge's sense will have either classical unemployment, cyclical unemployment, or both. Classical unemployment results from the actual real wage rising above the equilibrium real wage, so that the quantity of labor demanded (and the number of vacancies) is less than the quantity of labor supplied (and the number of unemployed workers). This might occur because of inefficient interference in the market; for example, a minimum wage set above the equilibrium wage; but also because of market failure, such as that caused by cartels.

Under classical unemployment, the ways by which a return to Beveridge full employment can occur depend on the nature of the rise in wages- if it is only "nominal" wages that are rigid (failing to return to equilibrium), then real wages can decrease if prices rise relative to the rigid nominal wages. If nominal wages track price levels, however, then changes to prices will not affect the real wage- and thus employment will remain below Beveridge full employment.

Cyclical, deficient-demand, or Keynesian unemployment occurs when there is not enough aggregate demand in the economy to provide jobs for everyone who wants to work. If demand for most goods and services falls, less production is needed and consequently fewer workers are needed: if wages are sticky and do not fall to meet the new equilibrium level, unemployment results, because (as with classical unemployment) there are more prospective workers than there are vacancies.[14]

The Phillips curve

[edit]

The theories behind the Phillips curve pointed to the inflationary costs of lowering the unemployment rate. That is, as unemployment rates fell and the economy approached full employment, the inflation rate would rise. But this theory also says that there is no single unemployment number that one can point to as the "full employment" rate. Instead, there is a trade-off between unemployment and inflation: a government might choose to attain a lower unemployment rate but would pay for it with higher inflation rates. In essence, in this view, the meaning of “full employment” is really nothing but a matter of opinion based on how the benefits of lowering the unemployment rate compare to the costs of raising the inflation rate.

Though their theory had been proposed by the Keynesian economist Abba Lerner several years before,[15] it was the work of Milton Friedman, leader of the monetarist school of economics, and Edmund Phelps that ended the popularity of this concept of full employment. In 1968, Friedman posited the theory that full employment rate of unemployment was unique at any given time. He called it the "natural" rate of unemployment. Instead of being a matter of opinion and normative judgment, it is something we are stuck with, even if it is unknown. As discussed further, below, inflation/unemployment trade-offs cannot be relied upon. Further, rather than trying to attain full employment, Friedman argues that policy-makers should try to keep prices stable (meaning a low or even a zero inflation rate). If this policy is sustained, he suggests that a free-market economy will gravitate to the "natural" rate of unemployment automatically.

The NAIRU

[edit]
Phillips Curve before and after Expansionary Policy, with Long-Run Phillips Curve (NAIRU)

In an effort to avoid the normative connotations of the word "natural," James Tobin (following the lead of Franco Modigliani), introduced the term the “Non-Accelerating Inflation Rate of Unemployment” (NAIRU), which corresponds to the situation where the real gross domestic product equals potential output. It has been called the "inflation threshold" unemployment rate or the inflation barrier. This concept is identical to Milton Friedman’s concept of the "natural" rate but reflects the fact that there is nothing "natural" about an economy. The level of the NAIRU depends on the degree of "supply side" unemployment, i.e., joblessness that can't be abolished by high demand. This includes frictional, mismatch, and Classical unemployment. When the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU, there is no cyclical or deficient-demand unemployment. That is, Keynes’ involuntary unemployment does not exist.

To understand this concept, start with the actual unemployment equal to the NAIRU. Then, assume that a country's government and its central bank use demand-side policy to reduce the unemployment rate and then attempt to keep the rate at a specific low level: rising budget deficits or falling interest rates increase aggregate demand and raise employment of labor. Thus, the actual unemployment rate falls, as going from point A to B in the nearby graph. Unemployment then stays below the NAIRU for years or more, as at point B. In this situation, the theory behind the NAIRU posits that inflation will accelerate, i.e. get worse and worse (in the absence of wage and price controls). As the short-run Phillips curve theory indicates, higher inflation rate results from low unemployment. That is, in terms of the "trade-off" theory, low unemployment can be "bought," paid for by suffering from higher inflation. But the NAIRU theory says that this is not the whole story, so that the trade-off breaks down: a persistently higher inflation rate is eventually incorporated as higher inflationary expectations. Then, if workers and employers expect higher inflation, it results in higher inflation, as higher money wages are passed on to consumers as higher prices. This causes the short run Phillips curve to shift to the right and upward, worsening the trade-off between inflation and unemployment. At a given unemployment rate, inflation accelerates. But if the unemployment rate rises to equal the NAIRU, we see higher inflation than before the expansionary policies, as at point C in the nearby diagram. The fall of the unemployment rate was temporary because it could not be sustained. In sum, the trade-off between inflation and unemployment cannot be relied upon to be stable: taking advantage of it causes it to disappear. This story fits the experience of the United States during the late 1960s, during which unemployment rates stayed low (below 4% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates rose significantly.

Second, examine the other main case. Again start with the unemployment rate equal to the NAIRU. Then, either shrinking government budget deficits (or rising government surpluses) or rising real interest rates encourage higher unemployment. In this situation, the NAIRU theory says that inflation will get better (decelerate) if unemployment rates exceed the NAIRU for a long time. High unemployment leads to lower inflation, which in turn causes lower inflationary expectations and a further round of lower inflation. High unemployment causes the short-run inflation/unemployment trade-off to improve. This story fits the experience of the United States during the early 1980s (Paul Volcker's war against inflation), during which unemployment rates stayed high (at about 10% of the civilian labor force) and inflation rates fell significantly.

Finally, the NAIRU theory says that the inflation rate does not rise or fall when the unemployment equals the "natural" rate. This is where the term NAIRU is derived. In macroeconomics, the case where the actual unemployment rate equals the NAIRU is seen as the long-run equilibrium because there are no forces inside the normal workings of the economy that cause the inflation rate to rise or fall. The NAIRU corresponds to the long-run Phillips curve. While the short-run Phillips curve is based on a constant rate of inflationary expectations, the long-run Phillips curve reflects full adjustment of inflationary expectations to the actual experience of inflation in the economy.

As mentioned above, Abba Lerner had developed a version of the NAIRU before the modern "natural" rate or NAIRU theories were developed. Unlike the currently dominant view, Lerner saw a range of "full employment" unemployment rates. Crucially, the unemployment rate depended on the economy's institution. Lerner distinguished between "high" full employment, which was the lowest sustainable unemployment under incomes policies, and "low" full employment, i.e., the lowest sustainable unemployment rate without these policies.

Further, it is possible that the value of the NAIRU depends on government policy, rather than being "natural" and unvarying. A government can attempt to make people "employable" by both positive means (e.g. using training courses) and negative means (e.g. cuts in unemployment insurance benefits). These policies do not necessarily create full employment. Instead, the point is to reduces the amount of mismatch unemployment by facilitating the linking of unemployed workers with the available jobs by training them and or subsidizing their moving to the geographic location of the jobs.

In addition, the hysteresis hypothesis says that the NAIRU does not stay the same over time—and can change due to economic policy.[16] A persistently low unemployment rate makes it easier for those workers who are unemployed for "mismatch" reasons to move to where the jobs are and/or to attain the training necessary for the available vacancies (often by getting those jobs and receiving on-the-job training). On the other hand, high unemployment makes it more difficult for those workers to adjust, while hurting their morale, job-seeking skills, and the value of their work skills. Thus, some economists argue that British Prime Minister Margaret Thatcher's anti-inflation policies using persistently high unemployment led to higher mismatch or structural unemployment and a higher NAIRU.

Uncertainty

[edit]

Whatever the definition of full employment, it is difficult to discover exactly what unemployment rate it corresponds to. In the United States, for example, the economy saw stable inflation despite low unemployment during the late 1990s, contradicting most economists' estimates of the NAIRU.

The idea that the full-employment unemployment rate (NAIRU) is not a unique number has been seen in recent empirical research. Staiger, Stock, and Watson found that the range of possible values of the NAIRU (from 4.3 to 7.3% unemployment) was too large to be useful to macroeconomic policy-makers. Robert Eisner suggested that for 1956-95 there was a zone from about 5% to about 10% unemployment between the low-unemployment realm of accelerating inflation and the high-unemployment realm of disinflation. In between, he found that inflation falls with falling unemployment.

Policy

[edit]

The active pursuit of national full employment through interventionist government policies is associated with Keynesian economics and marked the postwar agenda of many Western nations, until the stagflation of the 1970s. Interventionist full employment policies, targeted especially at young people, remain in place in the Nordic countries.[17] A commitment to full employment was also restored in the United Kingdom under New Labour (1997–2010), which manifested in the New Deal which lasted from 1998 until 2010.

Australia

[edit]

In 1945, the government of Australian Labor Party Prime Minister John Curtin[18] submitted to the Parliament of Australia the white paper Full Employment in Australia;[19] full employment remained the government's policy until 1975.[18]

United States

[edit]

The United States is, as a statutory matter, committed to full employment; the government is empowered to effect this goal.[20] The relevant legislation is the Employment Act (1946), initially the "Full Employment Act," later amended in the Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act (1978). The 1946 act was passed in the aftermath of World War II, when it was feared that demobilization would result in a depression, as it had following World War I in the Depression of 1920–21, while the 1978 act was passed following the 1973–75 recession and in the midst of continuing high inflation.

The law states that full employment is one of four economic goals, in concert with growth in production, price stability, balance of trade, and budget, and that the US shall rely primarily on private enterprise to achieve these goals. Specifically, the Act is committed to an unemployment rate of no more than 3% for persons aged 20 or over, and not more than 4% for persons aged 16 or over (from 1983 onwards), and the Act expressly allows (but does not require) the government to create a "reservoir of public employment" to affect this level of employment. These jobs are required to be in the lower ranges of skill and pay so as to not draw the workforce away from the private sector.

However, since the passage of this Act in 1978, the US has, as of 2017, only briefly achieved this level of employment on the national level in the late 1990s,[21] though some states have neared it or met it, nor has such a reservoir of public employment been created.

Job guarantee

[edit]

Post-Keynesian economists[22][23] have suggested ensuring full employment via a job guarantee program, where those who are unable to find work in the private sector are employed by the government, the stock of thus employed public sector workers fulfilling the same function as the unemployed do in controlling inflation, without the human costs of unemployment.

See also

[edit]

Notes

[edit]
  1. ^ O'Sullivan, Arthur; Sheffrin, Steven M. (2003), Economics: Principles in Action, Upper Saddle River, New Jersey: Pearson Prentice Hall, p. 335, ISBN 0-13-063085-3
  2. ^ E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) SSRN, part 2, charts at 6, 10 and 22
  3. ^ Coe, David T, Nominal Wages. The NAIRU and Wage Flexibility. (PDF), Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development
  4. ^ "The NAIRU, explained: Why economists don't want unemployment to drop too low". 14 November 2014.
  5. ^ "Unemployment Dickens" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2015-04-16. Retrieved 2013-06-28.
  6. ^ "V. Revised OECD measures of structural unemployment" (PDF). OECD Economic Outlook (68): 155–168. December 2000. Archived from the original (PDF) on 19 February 2005.
  7. ^ "As a young professor I did a paper where I analyzed the optimal unemployment rate," said Joseph Stiglitz, a professor at Columbia University in New York, who knew Tobin at Yale. "Tobin went livid over the idea. To him the optimal unemployment rate was zero." Yale's Tobin Guides Obama From Grave as Friedman Is Eclipsed
  8. ^ See, for example, "Inflation and Unemployment" by James Tobin, The American Economic Review, Vol. 62, No. 1/2 (Mar. 1, 1972), pp. 1-18.
  9. ^ Keynes, J. M.; Henderson, H. D. (1929). "II: The Common Sense of the Problem". Can Lloyd George Do It? The Pledge Examined. London: The Nation and Athenæum. pp. 10–11.
  10. ^ a b c John Maynard Keynes. "The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money".
  11. ^ http://www.oecd.org/eco/outlook/economicoutlookannextables.htm table 22. These estimates are done using the commonly-used definition of unemployment rather than using the measures based on efforts to standardize the measure of unemployment across countries.
  12. ^ E McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) SSRN, part 2(1)
  13. ^ "How a Fed inflation hawk changed his mind". Chicago Tribune. 9 October 2012.
  14. ^ Keynes, John Maynard (2007) [1936]. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. Basingstoke, Hampshire: Palgrave Macmillan. ISBN 978-0-230-00476-4. Archived from the original on 16 March 2009.
  15. ^ (Lerner 1951, Chapter 15)
  16. ^ Hargreaves Heap, Shawn P. (1980). Choosing the Wrong “Natural” Rate: Accelerating Inflation or Decelerating Employment and Growth? Economic Journal. vol. 90 (September): 611-620.
  17. ^ Hummeluhr, Niels (November 1997). "Youth guarantees in the Nordic countries" (PDF). {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  18. ^ a b Hutchens, Gareth (July 17, 2021). "Australia once wanted its allies to commit to full employment — what happened?". ABC News (Australia). Archived from the original on April 28, 2023. Retrieved April 29, 2023.
  19. ^ Black, Laurel (1984). "Social Democracy and Full Employment: The Australian White Paper, 1945". Labour History (46): 34–51. doi:10.2307/27508644. ISSN 0023-6942. JSTOR 27508644.
  20. ^ "A bill to establish and translate into practical reality the right of all adult Americans able, willing, and seeking to work to full opportunity for useful paid employment at fair rates of compensation;" Full Employment and Balanced Growth Act (1978)
  21. ^ "Bureau of Labor Statistics Data". Bureau of Labor Statistics. United States Department of Labor. 15 October 2020. Retrieved 15 October 2020.
  22. ^ Notably at the Center for Full Employment and Price Stability, as per references.
  23. ^ Wray, L. Randall (Aug 2001), The Endogenous Money Approach, enter for Full Employment and Price Stability, archived from the original on 2017-03-15, retrieved 2009-10-05

References

[edit]
  • A. A. Berle, ‘A New look at management responsibility’ (1962) 2 Human Resource Management 3
  • W. Beveridge, Full Employment in a Free Society (1944)
  • Farmer, Roger E. A. (1999). "Unemployment". Macroeconomics (Second ed.). Cincinnati: South-Western. pp. 173–192. ISBN 0-324-12058-3.
  • M. S. Eccles, Beckoning Frontiers: Public and Personal Recollections (1951)
  • Michał Kalecki, ‘Political aspects of full employment’ (1943) 14(4) Political Quarterly 322
  • Lerner, Abba Ptachya (1951). Economics of Employment. New York: McGraw-Hill.
  • E. McGaughey, A Casebook on Labour Law (Hart 2018) ch 16
  • E. McGaughey, 'Will Robots Automate Your Job Away? Full Employment, Basic Income, and Economic Democracy' (2018) SSRN, part 2(3)
  • Robert Reich, Aftershock: The next economy and America's future (2012)
  • S. Webb, How the Government Can Prevent Unemployment (1912)
  • United Kingdom Government White Paper, Employment Policy (May 1944) Cmd 6527

External sources

[edit]
  • The OECD on measuring the NAIRU
  • Devine, James. 2004. The "Natural" Rate of Unemployment. In Edward Fullbrook, ed., A Guide to What's Wrong with Economics, London, UK: Anthem Press, 126–32.
  • Eisner, Robert. 1997. A New View of the NAIRU. In Paul Davidson and Jan A. Kregel, eds. Improving the Global Economy. Cheltenham, UK: Edgar Elgar, 1997.
  • Friedman, Milton. 1968. The Role of Monetary Policy. American Economic Review. 58(1) March: 1-21.
  • McConnell, Brue, and Flynn. Microeconomics 19th edition. 2012.
  • Staiger, Douglas, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 1997. The NAIRU, Unemployment and Monetary Policy. Journal of Economic Perspectives. 11(1) Winter: 33–49.