Land reform: Difference between revisions
mNo edit summary |
m update to add note about underdeveloped countries being unstable |
||
(663 intermediate revisions by more than 100 users not shown) | |||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
{{short description|Changing of laws, regulations, or customs regarding land ownership}} |
|||
'''Land reform''' (also '''[[agrarian reform]]''', though that can have a broader meaning) is an often-[[Land_reform#Arguments_for_and_against_land_reform|controversial]] type of government-initiated or government-backed [[real estate]] [[property redistribution]], generally of [[agriculture|agricultural]] land. The term most often refers to transfer from ownership by a relatively small number of wealthy (or [[nobility|noble]]) owners with extensive land holdings (e.g. [[plantation]]s, large [[ranch]]es, or [[agribusiness]] plots) to individual or collective ownership by those who work the land. Such transfer of ownership may be with or without consent or compensation; compensation may vary from token amounts to the full value of the land. The [[land value tax]] advocated by [[Georgism|Georgists]] is a moderate, market-based version of land reform. |
|||
{{redirect|Land Question|the "land question" in Ireland|Land Acts (Ireland)}} |
|||
{{see also|Land reforms by country}} |
|||
[[File:Jakarta farmers protest23.jpg|300px|thumb|Farmers protesting for land reform in [[Indonesia]], 2004]] |
|||
'''Land reform''' is a form of [[agrarian reform]] involving the changing of laws, regulations, or customs regarding [[land ownership]].<ref>Batty, Fodei Joseph. "Pressures from Above, Below and Both Directions: The Politics of Land Reform in South Africa, Brazil and Zimbabwe". Western Michigan University. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, Illinois. April 7–10, 2005. p. 3. [http://www.allacademic.com//meta/p_mla_apa_research_citation/0/8/6/8/8/pages86884/p86884-1.php]</ref> Land reform may consist of a government-initiated or government-backed [[property redistribution]], generally of agricultural land. Land reform can, therefore, refer to transfer of ownership from the more powerful to the less powerful, such as from a relatively small number of wealthy or noble owners with extensive land holdings (e.g., plantations, large ranches, or [[agribusiness]] plots) to individual ownership by those who work the land.<ref>Borras, Saturnino M. Jr. "The Philippine Land form in Comparative Perspective: Some conceptual and Methodological Implications". ''Journal of Agrarian Change''. 6,1 (January 2006): 69–101.</ref> Such transfers of ownership may be with or without compensation; compensation may vary from token amounts to the full value of the land.<ref>Adams, Martin and J. Howell. "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa". Overseas Development Institute. DFID. Natural Resources Perspectives No. 64. January 2001. [http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/2078.pdf] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091205024136/http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/2078.pdf |date=2009-12-05 }}</ref> |
|||
Land reform may also entail the transfer of land from individual ownership—even [[peasant]] ownership in [[smallholding]]s—to government-owned collective farms; it has also, in other times and places, referred to the exact opposite: division of government-owned collective farms into smallholdings.<ref>Adams, Martin and J. Howell. [http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/2078.pdf "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa"]. {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20091205024136/http://www.odi.org.uk/resources/download/2078.pdf |date=2009-12-05 }} Overseas Development Institute. DFID. ''Natural Resources Perspectives'' No. 64. January 2001.</ref> The common characteristic of all land reforms is modification or replacement of existing institutional arrangements governing possession and use of land. Thus, while land reform may be radical in nature, such as through large-scale transfers of land from one group to another, it can also be less dramatic, such as regulatory reforms aimed at improving land administration.<ref>[http://www.ghanalap.gov.gh/index1.php?linkid=47&sublinkid=94 Ghana's Land Administration Project] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110721030833/http://www.ghanalap.gov.gh/index1.php?linkid=47&sublinkid=94 |date=2011-07-21 }}</ref> |
|||
This definition is somewhat complicated by the issue of state-owned [[collective farming|collective farms]]. In various times and places, ''land reform'' has encompassed the transfer of land from ownership — even [[peasant]] ownership in smallholdings — to government-owned collective farms; it has also, in other times and places, referred to the exact opposite, division of government-owned collective farms into smallholdings. |
|||
Nonetheless, any revision or reform of a country's land laws can still be an intensely political process, as reforming land policies serves to change relationships within and between communities, as well as between communities and the state. Thus even small-scale land reforms and legal modifications may be subject to intense debate or conflict.<ref>Lund, Christian. ''Local Politics and the Dynamics of Property in Africa''. Cambridge University Press: New York. 2008.</ref> |
|||
==Land ownership and tenure== |
|||
''See main article [[Land ownership and tenure]].'' |
|||
==Land usage and tenure == |
|||
The variety of land reform derives from the variety of land ownership and tenure. Among the possibilities are: |
|||
{{main|Land ownership and tenure}} |
|||
* Traditional land tenure, as in the indigenous nations or tribes of [[North America]] in the [[Pre-Columbian]] era. |
|||
{{Social democracy sidebar}} |
|||
Land ownership and tenure can be perceived as controversial in part because ideas defining what it means to access or control land, such as through "land ownership" or "land tenure", can vary considerably across regions and even within countries.<ref>La Croix, Sumner. [http://www.economics.hawaii.edu/research/workingpapers/WP_02-13.pdf "Land Tenure: An Introduction"]. Working Paper no. 02-13. May 2002. University of Hawaii.</ref> Land reforms, which change what it means to control land, therefore create tensions and conflicts between those who lose and those who gain from these redefinitions (see next section).<ref name="Boone, Catherine 2007">Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." ''African Affairs''. 2007. 106: 557–586.</ref> |
|||
Western conceptions of land have evolved over the past several centuries to place greater emphasis on individual land ownership, formalized through documents such as land titles.<ref>Locke, John. ''Two Treatises of Government''. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [1689] 1991. and Smith, Adam. ''The Wealth of Nations''. Books 1—III. London: Penguin Books. 1999.</ref> Control over land may also be perceived less in terms of individual ownership and more in terms of [[land use]], or through what is known as land tenure.<ref>[http://www.fao.org/docrep/005/y4307e/y4307e05.htm "What is land tenure?"] Food and Agriculture Organization.</ref> Historically, in many parts of Africa for example, land was not owned by an individual, but rather used by an extended family or a village community. Different people in a family or community had different rights to access this land for different purposes and at different times. Such rights were often conveyed through oral history and not formally documented.<ref>Dekker, Henri A.L. [https://books.google.com/books?id=_9AuGJ5oXpYC&q=Dekker,+Henri+A.L.+The+Invisible+Line: ''The Invisible Line: Land Reform, Land Tenure Security and Land Registration'']. Ashgate: Burlington, 2003. p. 2.</ref> |
|||
These different ideas of land ownership and tenure are sometimes referred to using different terminology. For example, "formal" or "statutory" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with individual land ownership. "Informal" or "customary" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with land tenure.<ref>"Land Law." Law and Development. The [[World Bank]]. February 23, 2007. [http://web.worldbank.org/WBSITE/EXTERNAL/TOPICS/EXTLAWJUSTICE/0,,contentMDK:20372383~menuPK:1696138~pagePK:148956~piPK:216618~theSitePK:445634,00.html],</ref> |
|||
Terms dictating control over and use of land can therefore take many forms. Some specific examples of present-day or historic forms of formal and informal land ownership include: |
|||
* Traditional land tenure, as practiced by the indigenous tribes of [[Pre-Columbian era|Pre-Columbian]] North America. |
|||
* [[Feudalism|Feudal]] land ownership, through [[fiefdom]]s |
* [[Feudalism|Feudal]] land ownership, through [[fiefdom]]s |
||
* [[Life estate]], interest in real property that ends at death. |
* [[Life estate]], interest in real property that ends at death. |
||
* [[Fee tail]], hereditary, non-transferable ownership of real property. |
* [[Fee tail]], hereditary, non-transferable ownership of real property. |
||
* [[Fee simple]]. Under [[common law]], this is the most complete ownership interest one can have in [[real property]]. |
* [[Fee simple]]. Under [[common law]], this is the most complete ownership interest one can have in [[real property]]. |
||
* [[Leasehold]] or [[renting|rental]] |
* [[Leasehold]] or [[renting|rental]] |
||
* Rights to use a [[ |
* Rights to use a [[common land|common]] |
||
* [[Sharecropping]] |
* [[Sharecropping]] |
||
*[[Run rig]] and [[rundale]] |
|||
*[[Well-field system|Well-Field System]] |
|||
* [[Easement]]s |
* [[Easement]]s |
||
*[[Kibbutz]] and [[moshav]] |
|||
*[[Satoyama]] |
|||
* Agricultural labor – under which someone works the land in exchange for money, payment in kind, or some combination of the two |
|||
* Collective ownership |
|||
* Access to land through a membership in a [[cooperative]], or shares in a corporation, which owns the land (typically by fee simple or its equivalent, but possibly under other arrangements). |
|||
* Government [[collectives]], such as those that might be found in communist states, whereby government ownership of most agricultural land is combined in various ways with tenure for farming collectives. |
|||
==Motivation== |
|||
In addition, there is paid agricultural labor — under which someone works the land in exchange for money, payment in kind, or some combination of the two — and various forms of collective ownership. The latter typically takes the form of membership in a [[cooperative]], or shares in a [[corporation]], which owns the land (typically by fee simple or its equivalent, but possibly under other arrangements). There are also various hybrids: in many [[communist state]]s, government ownership of most agricultural land has combined in various ways with tenure for farming collectives. |
|||
{{see also|Property redistribution}} |
|||
Land reform is a deeply political process<ref>: Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." ''African Affairs''. 2007. 106: 557–86. and Manji, Ambreena. ''The Politics of Land Reform in Ghana: From Communal Tenure to Free Markets''. Zed Books: New York. 2006.</ref> and therefore many arguments for and against it have emerged. These arguments vary tremendously over time and place. In the twentieth century, many land reforms emerged from a particular political ideology, such as communism or socialism. In the 19th century in colonized states, a colonial government may have changed the laws dictating land ownership to better consolidate political power or to support its colonial economy.<ref>Berry, Sata. "Debating the land question in Africa." Johns Hopkins University. N.d. {{cite web |url=http://www.unc.edu/~wwolford/Geography160/saraberry.pdf |title=Archived copy |access-date=2010-12-02 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120113212159/http://www.unc.edu/~wwolford/Geography160/saraberry.pdf |archive-date=2012-01-13 }}</ref> In more recent times, electoral mobilization and the use of land as a patronage resource have been proposed as possible motivations for land reform efforts, such as the extensive redistributive land reforms of Robert Mugabe in Zimbabwe.<ref>Boone, Catherine and N. Kriger. "Multiparty elections and land patronage: Zimbabwe and Cote d'Ivoire." ''Commonwealth and Comparative Politics''. 48,1 (April 2010): 173–202.</ref> |
|||
===Arguments for=== |
|||
Additionally there are, and have been, well-defined systems where neither land nor the houses people live in are their personal property (''[[Statare]]'', as defined in [[Scandinavia]]). |
|||
Arguments in support of land reform focus on its potential social and economic benefits, particularly in [[developing countries]], that may emerge from reforms focused on greater land formalization. Such benefits may include eradicating food insecurity and alleviating rural poverty.<ref>Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, Markelova, Helen and Moore, Kelsey. "The Role of Collective Action and Property Rights in Climate Change Strategies." International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), 2010. and Economic Commission for Africa. "Land Tenure Systems and their Impacts on [[Food security]] and Sustainable Development in Africa." 2009.</ref> |
|||
{{rquote|right|And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed.| ''[[The Grapes of Wrath]]''<ref>''[[The Grapes of Wrath]]'', by [[John Steinbeck]], Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, pg 238</ref>}} |
|||
The peasants or rural agricultural workers who are usually the intended primary beneficiaries of a land reform may be, prior to the reform, members of failing collectives, owners of inadequate small plots of land, paid laborers, sharecroppers, [[serf]]s, even [[slavery|slave]]s or effectively enslaved by [[debt bondage]]. |
|||
Arguments in support of such reforms gained particular momentum after the publication of ''The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else'' by Peruvian economist [[Hernando de Soto (economist)|Hernando de Soto]] in 2000. The poor, he argues, are often unable to secure formal property rights, such as land titles, to the land on which they live or farm because of poor governance, corruption and/or overly complex bureaucracies. Without land titles or other formal documentation of their land assets, they are less able to access formal credit. Political and legal reforms within countries, according to de Soto, will help to include the poor in formal legal and economic systems, increase the poor's ability to access credit and contribute to economic growth and poverty reduction.<ref>De Soto, Hernando. ''The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else''. New York: Basic Books. 2000.</ref> |
|||
==Arguments for and against land reform== |
|||
Many international development organizations and bilateral and multilateral donors, such as the World Bank, have embraced de Soto's ideas, or similar ideas, about the benefits of greater formalized land rights.<ref>Deininger, Klaus W. ''Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction''. The World Bank. 2003. [https://books.google.com/books?id=-3HWZigoZDMC]</ref> This has translated into a number of development programs that work with governments and civil society organizations to initiate and implement land reforms.<ref>World Bank. "Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets, and Collateralized Lending." 2003. [http://siteresources.worldbank.org/INTEAPREGTOPRURDEV/Resources/573691-1141228934263/2280904-1153493824735/RegionalStudyonLand+Administration.pdf]</ref> Evidence to support the economic and pro-poor benefits of increased formalized land rights are still inconclusive according to some critics (see "Arguments against land reform" below). |
|||
Land reform policies are generally advocated as an effort to eradicate [[food security|food insecurity]] and rural [[poverty]],<ref>http://www.fao.org/documents/show_cdr.asp?url_file=/docrep/006/j0415T/j0415T00.htm</ref> often with ''[[Utilitarianism|Utilitarian]]'' (eg., "the greatest good for the greatest number"), [[philosophy|philosophical]] or [[religion|religious]] arguments (see [[Jubilee (Biblical)|Jubilee]]), a right to [[dignity]], or a simple belief that justice requires a policy of "land to the tiller". However, many of these arguments conflict with prevailing notions of property rights in most societies and states. Implementations of land reform generally raise questions about how the members of the society view the individual's rights and the role of government. |
|||
Other arguments in support of land reform point to the need to alleviate conflicting land laws, particularly in former colonies, where formal and informal land systems may exist in tension with each other.<ref>Moore, Jina. "Africa's continental divide: land disputes." ''Christian Science Monitor''. January 30, 2010. [http://www.csmonitor.com/World/Africa/2010/0130/Africa-s-continental-divide-land-disputes]</ref> Such conflicts can make marginalized groups vulnerable to further exploitation.<ref>Kafmbe, Anthony Luyirika. "Access to Justice: Widows and the Institutions Regulating Succession to Property in Uganda." ''Human Rights Review''; Jul2006, Vol. 7 Issue 4, pp. 100–113.</ref> For example, in many countries in Africa with conflicting land laws, AIDS stigmatization has led to an increasing number of AIDS widows being kicked off marital land by in-laws.<ref>Ambasa-Shisanya, Constance. "Widowhood in the Era of HIV/AIDS: A Case Study of the Slaya District, Kenya." ''Journal of Social Aspects of HIV/AIDS''. August 2007. 2:2, 606–615.</ref> While the woman may have both customary and statutory rights to the land, confusion over which set of laws has primacy, or even a lack of knowledge of relevant laws, leave many AIDS widows at a significant disadvantage. Also, conflicting formal and informal land laws can also clog a country's legal system, making it prone to corruption.<ref>Tettey, Wisdom, B. Gebe and K. Ansah-Koi. "The Politics of Land and Land-related Conflicts in Ghana: A Summary." Land Policy Reform Project. Institute for Statistical, Social and Economic Research at the University of Ghana. 2008. [http://www.isser.org/images/stories/landproject/Summary%20POLITICS_OF_LAND_AND_LAND-RELATED_CONFLICTS%20-%20summary.pdf] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200307003730/http://www.isser.org/images/stories/landproject/Summary%20POLITICS_OF_LAND_AND_LAND-RELATED_CONFLICTS%20-%20summary.pdf |date=2020-03-07 }}</ref> |
|||
These questions include: |
|||
* Is private property of any sort legitimate? |
|||
* If so, is land ownership legitimate? |
|||
* If so, are historic property rights in this particular state and society legitimate? |
|||
* Even if property rights are legitimate, do they protect absolutely against expropriation, or do they merely entitle the property owner to partial or complete compensation? |
|||
* How should property rights be weighed against rights to life and liberty? |
|||
* Who should adjudicate land ownership disputes? |
|||
* At what level of government is common land owned? |
|||
* What constitutes fair land reform? |
|||
* What are the internal and external political effets of the land reform? |
|||
Additional arguments for land reform focus on the potential [[environmental quality|environmental benefits]] of reform. For example, if reform leads to greater security of [[land owner]]ship, through either formal or informal means, then those that use the land will be better stewards of it.<ref>World Resources Institute. "The Wealth of the Poor: Managing Ecosystems to Fight Poverty." 2005. {{cite web |url=http://archive.wri.org/publication_detail.cfm?pubid=4073 |title=World Resources 2005 -- the Wealth of the Poor: Managing ecosystems to fight poverty | World Resources Institute |access-date=2010-12-02 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20110807172600/http://archive.wri.org/publication_detail.cfm?pubid=4073 |archive-date=2011-08-07 }} and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). "Land Tenure and Rural Development." FAO Land Tenure Studies No. 3. 2002. Accessed August 21, 2010. Available: [http://ftp.fao.org/docrep/fao/005/y4307E/y4307E00.pdf]{{dead link|date=December 2017 |bot=InternetArchiveBot |fix-attempted=yes }}</ref> |
|||
Concern over the value of land reform is based upon the following: |
|||
*Lack of track record to support land reform outcome; for example, in Zimbabwe, an aggressive land reform plan has led to a collapse of the economy and 45 percent malnutrition. |
|||
*Question of experience and competence of those recieving land to be productive. |
|||
*Equity issues of displacing persons who have sometimes worked hard in previous farming of the land |
|||
*Question of competence of governmental entities to make decisions regarding agricultural productivity |
|||
*Question of enmiring a country in vast legal disputes from arbitrary property distribution |
|||
*Demotivation of any property owners to invest in land, which ultimately can be seized |
|||
Land reforms carried out in Japan, Taiwan and South Korea are credited with contributing to the industrial development. The equitable distribution of land led to increasing agricultural outputs, high rural purchasing power and social mobility.<ref>{{cite book |title=How Asia Works: Success and Failure in the World's Most Dynamic Region |date=2014 |publisher=Grove Press |isbn=9780802121325 |chapter=Land: The Triumph of Gardening}}</ref> |
|||
Opposing [[libertarianism|"royal libertarian"]] (but not [[geolibertarian]]) [[ethics|ethical]] arguments to government-directed "land reform" maintain it is just a [[euphemism]] for [[theft]], and argue that stealing is still stealing regardless of what any group of non-[[Ownership|owners]] (of the property in question) may succeed in obtaining via government intermediary, and that such policies consequently cannot ever be [[justice|just]].<ref>[http://www.anthonyflood.com/redist4.htm "Redistribution" as Euphemism or, Who Owns What?]'' Philosophy Pathways,'' Number 65, 24 August 2003, by Anthony Flood</ref> They state that alleged "willing seller, willing buyer" programs also invariably involve governments buying land with tax-money (which may be disproportionately collected from the land-owners the land of whom are concerned in the planned reform), and sometimes laws granting government first right to buy land for sale (diminishing the market-value of the land by eliminating competing buyers), and so an element of [[coercion]] exists despite the "willing" label. |
|||
===Arguments against=== |
|||
The opposition for a land reform may also be based on other ideologies than modern-day liberalism. In countries where there has traditionally been no private land ownership (e.g. [[Russia]] in 19th century) the opposition for reforms enabling the creation of private farms may use nationalistic arguments, proposing that the private farms are inconsistent with the national culture. In countries where the established church was an important land owner, theological arguments have been used in the debate on privatization or nationalization of that land (e.g. 16th century [[Sweden]]). The right to ownership of the land, and sometimes, the persons residing on that land, has also been argued on the theory of ''right of conquest'', implying that the original ownership was transferred to the land-owning class's ancestors in a [[just war]]. The ownership can also be argued on the ground of god-given right, implying that it is some deity that has given the land to its owners. |
|||
Many of the arguments in support of land reform speak to its potentially positive social and economic outcomes. Yet, as mentioned previously, land reform is an intensely political process.<ref name="Boone, Catherine 2007" /> Thus, many of those opposed to land reform are nervous as to the underlying motivations of those initiating the reform. For example, some may fear that they will be disadvantaged or victimized as a result of the reforms. Others may fear that they will lose out in the economic and political power struggles (especially in under developed countries) that underlie many land reforms.<ref>[http://www.economist.com/node/16703331 "A chance to improve how Kenya is run." ''The Economist''. July 29, 2010]</ref> |
|||
Other groups and individuals express concerns about land reforms focused on formalization of property rights. While the economic and social benefits of formalized land rights are often touted, some research suggests that such reforms are either ineffective or may cause further hardship or conflict.<ref>Bourbeau, Heather, "Property Wrongs." ''Foreign Policy''. Nov/Dec 2001. Issue 127, pp. 78–79 and Nyamu Musembi, Celestine. "De Soto and Land Relations in rural Africa: breathing life into dead theories about property rights." ''Third World Quarterly''. 2007. 28:8, 1457–1478.</ref> |
|||
For the proponents of the reform, the rights of the individuals for whose good the reform is supposed to work, overcome the property rights of the land owners. Usually their philosophical background differs significantly from the viewpoints outlined above, spanning from Marxism to religious ideologies. What is common for them, is that they see the rights or duties advocated as more important than right to own real estate. |
|||
Additional arguments against land reform focus on concerns over equity issues and potential [[elite capture]] of land, particularly in regards to reforms focused on greater land formalization. If improperly or inadequately implemented, critics worry that such reforms may further disadvantage marginalized groups such as indigenous communities or women.<ref>Drimie, Scott. "The Impact of HIV/AIDS on Land: Case Studies from Kenya, Lesotho and South Africa." ''Food and Agriculture Organization''. August 2002. and Varley, Ann. "Gender and Property Formalization: Conventional and Alternative Approaches." ''World Development''. October 2007. 35:10, 1739–1753.</ref> These concerns also lead to questions about the institutional capacity of governments to implement land reforms as they are designed. Even if a country does have this capacity, critics worry that corruption and patrimonialism will lead to further [[elite capture]].<ref>''Gender in Agriculture Source Book''. The World Bank, FAO and IFAD. 2009.[https://books.google.com/books?id=XxBrq6hTs_UC]</ref> |
|||
''See also [[property redistribution]].'' |
|||
In looking at more radical reforms, such as large-scale land redistribution, arguments against reform include concerns that redistributed land will not be used productively and that owners of expropriated land will not be compensated adequately or compensated at all. Zimbabwe, again, is a commonly cited example of the perils of such large-scale reforms, whereby land redistribution contributed to economic decline and increased food insecurity in the country.<ref>[http://www.economist.com/node/1201137?story_id=1201137 "From breadbasket to basket case." ''The Economist''. June 27, 2002]</ref> In cases where land reform has been enacted as part of [[socialism|socialist]] [[collectivization]], many of the arguments against collectivization more generally apply. |
|||
==Land reform efforts== |
|||
==National efforts== |
|||
Agrarian land reform has been a recurring theme of enormous consequence in world history — see, for example, the history of the Semproninan Law or ''Lex Sempronia agraria'' proposed by [[Tiberius Sempronius Gracchus]] and passed by the [[Roman Senate]] (133 BC), which led to the social and political wars that ended the [[Roman Republic]]. |
|||
{{main|Land reforms by country}} |
|||
An early example of land reform was the [[Land Acts (Ireland)|Irish Land Acts]] of 1870–1909. Most all newly independent countries of Eastern and Central Europe implemented land reforms in the aftermath of [[World War I]]. In most countries, the land in excess of certain limits ({{Convert|20|-|500|ha|acre|abbr=on}}, depending on the region and type of land) was expropriated; in [[Finland]], it was redeemed and placed into a special fund.<ref>Gediminas Vaskela. [http://gevask.dtiltas.lt/GeVask/html/agreforma01e.htm The Land Reform of 1919–1940: Lithuania and the Countries of East and Central Europe] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20120322093409/http://gevask.dtiltas.lt/GeVask/html/agreforma01e.htm |date=2012-03-22 }}</ref> |
|||
A historically important source of pressure for land reform has been the accumulation of significant properties by tax-exempt individuals or entities. In the [[Christian]] world, this has frequently been true of churches and monastaries. In the Moslem world, land reforms such as that organized in [[Spain]] by al-Hurr in 718 have transferred property from [[Muslim|Muslims]] to Christians, who were taxable. |
|||
In the modern world and in the aftermath of [[colonialism]] and the [[Industrial Revolution]], land reform has occurred around the world, from the [[Mexican Revolution]] (1917; the revolution began in 1910) to [[People's Republic of China|Communist China]] to [[Bolivia]] (1952, 2006) to [[Zimbabwe]] and [[Namibia]]. Land reform has been especially popular as part of [[decolonization]] struggles in [[Africa]] and the [[Arab world]], where it was part of the program for [[African socialism]] and [[Arab socialism]]. [[Cuba]] has seen one of the most complete agrarian reforms in Latin America. Land reform was an important step in achieving economic development in many [[Third World]] countries since the post-[[World War II]] period, especially in the [[East Asian Tigers]] and "Tiger Cubs" nations such as [[Republic of China|Taiwan]], [[South Korea]], and [[Malaysia]]. |
|||
Since [[mainland China]]'s economic reforms led by [[Deng Xiaoping]] land reforms have also played a key role in the development of the [[People's Republic of China]], with the re-emergence of big landowners as well as landless peasants. |
|||
===Latin America=== |
|||
*[[Mexico]]: a certain degree of land reform was introduced, albeit unevenly, as part of the [[Mexican Revolution]]. [[Emiliano Zapata]] was strongly identified with land reform, as are the present-day (as of 2006) [[Zapatista Army of National Liberation]]. See [[Mexican Agrarian Land Reform]]. |
|||
*[[Brazil]]: In the 1930s, [[Getúlio Vargas]] reneged on a promised land reform. Strong campaign including [[direct action]] by the [[Landless Workers' Movement]] throughout the 1990s. Current efforts under [[Lula da Silva]], Brazil's first elected leftwing president, inaugurated [[January 1]], [[2003]] |
|||
*[[Guatemala]]: land reform occurred during the [[History of Guatemala#The "Ten Years of Spring"|"Ten Years of Spring"]], 1944–1954 under the governments of [[Juan José Arévalo]] and [[Jacobo Arbenz]]. |
|||
*[[Bolivia]]: The revolution of 1952 was followed by a land reform law, but in 1970 only 45% of peasant families had received title to land, although more land reform projects continued in the 1970s and 1980s. Bolivian president [[Evo Morales]] restarted land reform when he took office in 2006.<ref>James Read, [http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/americas/5045424.stm Bolivia head starts land handout], BBC News, 4 June 2006. Accessed 20 July 2006.</ref> |
|||
*[[Peru]]: land reform in the 1950s largely eliminated a centuries-old system of [[debt bondage|debt peonage]]. Further land reform occurred after the 1968 coup by [[left-wing politics|left-wing]] colonel Juan Velasco Alvarado, and again as part of a [[counterterrorism]] effort against the [[Shining Path]] roughly 1988–1995, led by [[Hernando de Soto (economist)|Hernando de Soto]] and the [[Institute for Liberty and Democracy]] during the early years of the government of [[Alberto Fujimori]], before the latter's ''auto-[[coup]]''. |
|||
*[[Cuba]]: Land reform was among the chief planks of the revolutionary platform of 1959. Almost all large holdings were seized by the [[National Institute for Agrarian Reform]] (INRA), which dealt with all areas of agricultural policy. A ceiling of 166 acres (67 hectares) was established, and tenants were given full ownership rights. |
|||
*[[Chile]]: Attempts at land reform began under the government of [[Jorge Alessandri]] in 1960, were accelerated during the government of [[Eduardo Frei Montalva]] (1964-1970), and reached its climax during the 1970-1973 presidency of [[Salvador Allende]]. Farms of more than 198 acres (80 hectares) were expropriated. After the [[Chilean coup of 1973|1973 coup]] the process was halted, and up to a point reversed by the market forces. |
|||
*[[Colombia]]: [[Alfonso López Pumarejo]] (1934-1938) passed the Law 200 of 1936, which allowed for the expropriation of private properties, in order to promote "social interest". Later attempts declined, until the [[History of Colombia#The National Front|National Front]] presidencies of [[Alberto Lleras Camargo]] ([[1958]]-[[1962]]) and [[Carlos Lleras Restrepo]] (1966-1970), which respectively created the Colombian Institute for Agrarian Reform (INCORA) and further developed land entitlement. In 1968 and 1969 alone, the INCORA issued more than 60,000 land titles to farmers and workers. Despite this, the process was then halted and the situation began to reverse itself, as the subsequent violent actions of drug lords, paramilitaries, guerrillas and opportunistic large landowners severely contributed to a renewed concentration of land and to the displacement of small landowners. In the early 21st century, tentative government plans to use the land legally expropriated from drug lords and/or the properties given back by demobilized paramilitary groups have not caused much practical improvement yet. |
|||
*[[Venezuela]]: [[Hugo Chávez]]'s government enacted [[Plan Zamora]] to redistribute government and unused private land to ''campesinos'' in need. |
|||
===Middle East and North Africa === |
|||
''Land reform is discussed in the article on [[Arab Socialism]]'' |
|||
*[[Egypt]]: Initially, [[Egyptian land reform]] essentially abolished the political influence of major land owners. However, land reform only resulted in the redistribution of about 15% of Egypt's land under cultivation, and by the early 1980s, the effects of land reform in Egypt drew to a halt as the population of Egypt moved away from agriculture. The Egyptian land reform laws were greatly curtailed under [[Anwar Sadat]] and eventually abolished. |
|||
* [[Syria]] (1963, largely reversed since) <!--mentioned in [[Arab Socialism]] --> |
|||
* [[Iran]]: a significant land reform was part of [[Muhammad Reza Shah]]'s so-called [[White Revolution]] of [[1963]]. Almost 90% of Iranian [[sharecropping|share-croppers]] became land owners. |
|||
* [[Iraq]] (1970) <!--mentioned in [[Arab Socialism]] --> |
|||
=== Europe === |
|||
*[[Finland]]: In 1918, Finland fought a [[Finnish Civil War|civil war]] resulting in a series of land reforms. These included the compensated transfer of lease-holdings (''torppa'') to the leasers and prohibition of forestry companies to acquire land. After the [[Second World War]], [[Carelia]]ns evacuated from areas ceded to Russia were given land in remaining Finnish areas, taken from public and private holdings. Also the veterans of war benefited from these allotments. |
|||
*[[France]]: a major and lasting land reform took place under the [[French Directory|Directory]] during the latter phases of the [[French Revolution]]. |
|||
*[[Estonia]] and [[Latvia]]: at their founding as states in 1918–1919, they expropriate the large estates of [[Baltic German]] landowners, much of which became smallholdings. |
|||
*[[Hungary]]: In 1945 every estate bigger than 142 acres was expropriated without compensation and distributed among the peasants. In the 1950s collective ownership was introduced according to the Soviet model, but after 1990 co-ops were dissolved and the land was redistributed among private smallholders. |
|||
*[[Ireland]]: after the [[Irish Famine]], land reform became the dominant issue in Ireland, where almost all of the land was owned by the [[England|English]] aristocracy. The [[Irish Parliamentary Party]] campaigned for this in a largely indifferent [[British House of Commons]]. Reform began tentatively in 1870 and continued for fifty years (''see also'' [[Land War]]). |
|||
*[[Poland]]: there have been several land reforms in Poland. The most important include [[Land reforms in the Second Polish Republic|Land reforms]] in the [[Second Polish Republic]] (1919, 1921, 1923, 1925 and 1928) and [[Land reform in the People's Republic of Poland|Land reform]] (1944) in the [[People's Republic of Poland]]. |
|||
*[[Romania]]: After failed attempts at land reform by [[Mihail Kogălniceanu]] in the years immediately after Romanian unification in 1863, a major land reform finally occurred in 1921. |
|||
*[[Russia]] |
|||
**[[Imperial Russia]]: [[Stolypin reform]] |
|||
**[[Bolshevist Russia]]: [[Decree on Land]] |
|||
*[[Scotland]] the [[Land Reform (Scotland) Act 2003]] ends the historic legacy of [[feudal law]] and creates a framework for rural or [[Croft (land)|croft]] communities right to buy land in their area. |
|||
*[[Sweden]], almost non-violently, arrived at regulating the length minimum of [[tenant farming]] contracts at 25 years. |
|||
=== Sub-Saharan Africa === |
|||
*[[Kenya]]: [[Kenyatta]] launched a "willing buyer-willing seller" based land reform program in the 1960s, funded by Britain, the former colonial power. In 2006 president [[Mwai Kibaki]] said it will repossess all land owned by "absentee landlords" in the coastal strip and redistribute it to squatters. <ref>[http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/low/africa/5275670.stm Pledge to redistribute Kenya land]</ref>. Outcome of land reform is a [[malnutrition|malnourshed]] percentage of the population of 32%. |
|||
*[[Namibia]]: A limited land reform has been a hallmark of the regime of [[Sam Nujoma]]; legislation passed in September 1994, with a compulsory, compensated approach.<ref>[http://allafrica.com/stories/200608170017.html Namibia: Land Reform to Cost Billions]</ref> |
|||
*[[South Africa]]: "Land restitution" was one of the promises made by the [[African National Congress]] when it came to power in South Africa in 1994. Initially, land was bought from its owners (willing seller) by the government (willing buyer) and redistributed. However, as of early 2006, the [[African National Congress|ANC]] government announced that it will start [[expropriation|expropriating]] the land, although according to the country's chief land-claims commissioner, Tozi Gwanya, unlike Zimbabwe there will be compensation to those whose land is expropriated, "but it must be a just amount, not inflated sums."<ref>http://www.irinnews.org/report.asp?ReportID=55132&SelectRegion=Southern_Africa&SelectCountry=SOUTH_AFRICA </ref><ref>http://www.mg.co.za/articlePage.aspx?articleid=263484&area=/breaking_news/breaking_news__national/</ref> |
|||
*[[Zimbabwe]]: Very controversial efforts at [[land reform in Zimbabwe]] under [[Robert Mugabe]] has moved steadily from a "willing seller, willing buyer" approach toward outright expropriation, often for the benefit of people close to the government. Outcome to date is 45 percent of the population [[malnutrition|malnourished]]. |
|||
=== North America === |
|||
*[[Canada]]: A land reform was carried out as part of [[Prince Edward Island]]'s agreement to join the [[Canadian confederation]] in the 1870s. Most of the land was owned by [[absentee landlords]] in England, and as part of the deal Canada was to buy all the land and give it to the farmers. |
|||
*[[United States of America]]: Native Americans living in several [[Indian reservation]]s across the country are working to reclaim or recover their lands that were lost from [[Forced Fee Patenting]] and other Federal programs that alienated them from their legally allotted lands. |
|||
**Native Americans living on several [[Indian reservation]]s across the country are working to reclaim their lands from the Federal [[Bureau of Indian Affairs]] leasing program, which leases these lands to mostly non-tribal farmers and ranchers. Many of these lands were put into the program against the will of their legal allottees and/or legal heirs who were declared "incompetent" to manage their own affairs. There exists very few records on how the classification of "competency" or "non-competency" was determined by the [[Competency Commissions]] that existed on Native American Reservations prior to the 1934 [[Indian Reorganization Act]]. |
|||
**[[Minnesota]]:"The mission of the [[White Earth Land Recovery Project]] is to facilitate recovery of the original land base of the White Earth Indian Reservation, while preserving and restoring traditional practices of sound land stewardship, language fluency, community development, and strengthening our spiritual and cultural heritage (WELRP)." |
|||
**Following the [[American Civil War|Civil War]], the [[Radical Republicans]] attempted to put a land reform through Congress, promising "forty acres and a mule" to newly-freed blacks in the South, which was ultimately rejected by moderate elements as "socialistic". This failure left blacks without an economic base, and was one of the key contributing factors to the development of [[sharecropping]] and [[segregation]]. |
|||
**The [[Dawes Act]] of 1887 split the [[Native Americans in the United States|Indian]] tribal lands into allotments held by individual Indians. Most tribal land was recollectivized in 1934. |
|||
=== Asia === |
|||
*[[China]] has been through a series of land reforms: |
|||
** The thorough land reform launched by the [[Communist Party of China]] in 1946, three years before the foundation of the [[People's Republic of China]] (PRC), won the party millions of supporters among the poor and middle peasantry. The land and other property of landlords were expropriated and redistributed so that each household in a rural village would have a comparable holding. This agrarian revolution was made famous in the West by William Hinton's book ''Fanshen''. |
|||
**In the mid-[[1950s]], a second land reform compelled individual farmers to join collectives, which, in turn, were grouped into People's Communes with centrally controlled property rights and an egalitarian principle of distribution. This policy was generally a failure in terms of production. [http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0031.htm] There is evidence that the PRC began to reverse this policy even in the [[1960s]]. |
|||
** A third land reform beginning in the late 1970s re-introduced family-based contract system called the [[Household Responsibility System]], which had enormous initial success, followed by a period of relative stagnation. Chen, Wang, and Davis [1998] suggest that the later stagnation was due, in part, to a system of periodic redistribution that encouraged over-exploitation rather than capital investment in future productivity. [http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0031.htm] |
|||
*[[India]]: Due the taxation and regulation under the [[British Raj]], at the time of [[Indian independence|independence]], India inherited a semi-feudal agrarian system, with ownership of land concentrated with a few individual landlords ([[Zamindar]]s, Zamindari System). Since independence, there has been voluntary and state initiated/mediated land reforms in several states. The most notable and successful example of land reforms is in the state of [[West Bengal]]. After promising land reforms and elected to power, the [[Communist Party of India]] kept their word and initiated gradual land reforms. The result was a more equitable distribution of land among the landless farmers. This has ensured an almost life long loyalty from the farmers and the communists have been in power ever since. Another successful land reform program was launched in [[Jammu and Kashmir]] after 1947. |
|||
**However, this success was not replicated in other areas like [[Kerala]] - the only other state where communists came to power - and the states of [[Andhra Pradesh|Andhra]] and [[Madhya Pradesh]], where the more radical wing of the CPI, the PWG (People's War Group) or [[Naxalite]]s resorted to violence as it failed to secure power. Even in [[West Bengal]], the economy suffered for a long time as a result of the communist economic policies that did little to encourage heavy industries. In the state of [[Bihar]], tensions between land owners militia, villagers and [[Maoist]]s have resulted in numerous massacres. |
|||
**All in all, land reforms have been successful only in pockets of the country, as people have often found loopholes in the laws setting limits on the maximum area of land held by any one person. |
|||
*[[Japan]]: After [[World War II]], the U.S. occupying forces conducted a land reform in Japan. |
|||
*[[Taiwan]]: In the years after [[World War II]], [[Chiang Kai-shek]] conducted land reform at the insistence of the U.S. This course of action was made possible, in part, by the fact that many of the large landowners were Japanese who had fled and also by the fact that the [[Kuomintang]] were mostly from the mainland and had few ties to the remaining indigenous landowners. |
|||
*[[Vietnam]]: In the years after World War II, even before the formal division of Vietnam, land reform was initiated in [[North Vietnam]]. This land reform redistributed land to more than 2 million poor peasants, but at a cost of from tens <ref>Communist Party of Vietnam, ''Kinh nghiệm giải quyết vấn đề ruộng đất trong cách mạng Việt Nam'' (Experience in land reform in the Vietnamese Revolution), available online: http://dangcongsan.vn/details.asp?topic=2&subtopic=5&leader_topic=79&id=BT1060374012</ref> to hundreds of thousands of lives<ref>''The Viet Minh Regime, Government and Administration in the Democratic Republic of Vietnam'', Bernard Fall, Greenwood Press, Connecticut, 1975.</ref> and was one of the main reason for the mass exodus of 1 million people from the North to the South in 1954. South Vietnam made several further attempts in the post-Diem years, the most ambitious being the [[Land to the Tiller (South Vietnam)|Land to the Tiller]] program instituted in 1970 by President [[Nguyen Van Thieu]]. This limited individuals to 15 hectares, compensated the owners of expropriated tracts, and extended legal title to peasants who in areas under control of the South Vietnamese government to whom had land had previously been distributed by the [[Viet Cong]]. Mark Moyar [1996] asserts that while it was effectively implemented only in some parts of the country, "In the Mekong Delta and the provinces around Saigon, the program worked extremely well... It reduced the percentage of total cropland cultivated by tenants from sixty percent to ten percent in three years." [http://www.vietnam.ttu.edu/vietnamcenter/events/1996_Symposium/96papers/moyar.htm] |
|||
*[[South Korea]]: In 1945–1950, United States and South Korean authorities carried out a land reform that retained the institution of private property. They confiscated and redistributed all land held by the Japanese colonial government, Japanese companies, and individual Japanese colonists. The Korean government carried out a reform whereby Koreans with large landholdings were obliged to divest most of their land. A new class of independent, family proprietors was created. [http://countrystudies.us/south-korea/36.htm] |
|||
==See also== |
==See also== |
||
{{div col|colwidth=12em}} |
|||
*[[Agrarian reform]] |
|||
* [[Adverse possession]] |
|||
*[[Anti-globalization movement]] |
|||
* ''[[Agrarian Justice]]'' |
|||
*[[Communism]] |
|||
*[[ |
* [[Agrarian reform]] |
||
* [[Certificate of occupancy (land tenure)|Certificate of occupancy]] |
|||
*[[Homestead principle]] |
|||
* [[Chinese Land Reform]] |
|||
*[[Georgism]] |
|||
*[[ |
* [[Citizen's Dividend]] |
||
* [[Concentration of land ownership]] |
|||
*[[Restitution]] |
|||
* [[Economic rent#Classical rent (land rent)|Classical rent]] |
|||
*[[Squatter]] |
|||
* [[Collectivization in the Soviet Union]] |
|||
* [[Common land]] |
|||
Contrast: |
|||
* [[ |
* [[Dekulakization]] |
||
* [[Differential and absolute ground rent]] |
|||
* [[Eminent domain]] |
|||
* [[Enclosure]] |
|||
* {{lang|de|[[Fachhochschule]]}} |
|||
* [[Frente Unido de Reforma Agraria]] |
|||
* [[Gentrification]] |
|||
* [[Georgism]] |
|||
* [[Homestead principle]] |
|||
* [[Land (economics)]] |
|||
* [[Land Acts (Ireland)]] |
|||
* [[Land banking]] |
|||
* [[Land claim]] |
|||
* [[Land consumption]] |
|||
* [[Land grabbing]] |
|||
* [[Land law]] |
|||
* [[Landlessness]] |
|||
* [[Land consolidation]] |
|||
* ''[[Land Reform in Developing Countries]]'' |
|||
* [[Land reforms by country]] |
|||
* [[Land tenure]] |
|||
* [[Land titling]] |
|||
* [[Land value tax]] |
|||
* [[Manorialism]] |
|||
* [[México Indígena]] |
|||
* [[Mutualism (economic theory)|Mutualism]] |
|||
* [[Natural capital]] |
|||
* [[Nonpossessory interest in land]] |
|||
* [[Profit (real property)]] |
|||
* [[Real estate appraisal]] |
|||
* [[Restitution]] |
|||
* [[Serfdom]] |
|||
* [[Settler]] |
|||
* [[Speculation]] |
|||
* [[Squatting]] |
|||
* [[Stolypin reform]] |
|||
* [[Usufruct]] |
|||
* [[Water scarcity]] |
|||
* [[Zapatismo]] |
|||
{{div col end}} |
|||
==References== |
==References== |
||
{{reflist}} |
|||
<references/> |
|||
== Further reading == |
|||
* {{Cite journal |doi=10.1111/1471-0366.00042 |title=Land Reform: Taking a Long(er) View |journal=Journal of Agrarian Change |volume=2 |issue=4 |pages=433–463 |year=2002 |last1=Bernstein |first1=H.|bibcode=2002JAgrC...2..433B }} |
|||
* Caralee McLiesh and Richard E. Messick, Moderators. (2004). [https://web.archive.org/web/20070609143810/http://rru.worldbank.org/Discussions/Topics/Topic45.aspx "Can Formal Property Titling Programs Ensure Increased Business Investments and Growth?"]. [[World Bank]]. |
|||
* Ciparisse, Gérard. (2003). [https://web.archive.org/web/20050729153028/http://www.fao.org/documents/show_cdr.asp?url_file=%2FDOCREP%2F005%2FX2038E%2FX2038E00.HTM Multilingual Thesaurus on Land Tenure]. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the UN. {{ISBN|9251042837}}. |
|||
* Cahill, Kevin. "Who Owns The World: The Hidden Facts Behind Landownership", Mainstream Publishing, 2006, {{ISBN|9781845961589}}. {{OCLC|746882317}}. |
|||
** Cahill, Kevin. "Who Owns Britain: The Hidden Facts Behind Landownership in the UK and Ireland", Canongate Books, 2002. {{ISBN|9781841953106}}. {{OCLC|1015469648}}. |
|||
* [[Michael Lipton]], [[Land Reform in Developing Countries: Property rights and property wrongs]], Routledge, 2009 |
|||
* R. H. Tawney, ''Land and Labour in China'' New York, Harcourt Brace & Company (1979). 3rd Edition. {{ISBN|9780374977719}}. {{OCLC|709358069}}. |
|||
* Fu Chen, Liming Wang and John Davis, [https://web.archive.org/web/20101223213916/http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0031.htm "Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s"], [https://web.archive.org/web/20041209060121/http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LR98_2/landrf.htm Land Reform 1998/2], a publication of the Sustainable Development Department of the United Nations' [[Food and Agriculture Organization]] (FAO). |
|||
* [[William H. Hinton]]. ''[[Fanshen: A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village]]''. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966. {{ISBN|9780520210400}}. {{OCLC|258568918}}. |
|||
* Ho, Peter. (2001, June). [https://web.archive.org/web/20080222190523/http://www.rug.nl/cds/medewerkers/peterho/iSI ''Who Owns China's Land? Policies, Property Rights and Deliberate Institutional Ambiguity''], The China Quarterly, Vol. 166, June 2001, pp. 387–414 |
|||
** Ho, Peter. (2006). "Institutions In Transition: Land Ownership, Property Rights and Social Conflict in China''. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. {{ISBN|9780199280698}}. {{OCLC|1292686440}}. |
|||
* Mark Moyar. [https://archive.today/20090311004735/http://www.vietnam.ttu.edu/vietnamcenter/events/1996_Symposium/96papers/moyar.htm "Villager attitudes during the final decade of the Vietnam War"]. Presented at 1996 Vietnam Symposium [https://archive.today/20090309174927/http://www.vietnam.ttu.edu/vietnamcenter/events/1996_Symposium/96papers/papers.htm "After the Cold War: Reassessing Vietnam"]. |
|||
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20070927103758/http://www.tts.fi/uk/publication/teho-magazine/teho04_5.htm#Paakirjoitus Summary of "Efficiency and wellbeing for 80 years" by Tarmo Luoma] on site of ''TEHO'' magazine. |
|||
* Rudzani Albert Makhado and Kgabo Lawrance Masehela. (2012). Perspectives on South Africa's Land Reform Debate. Lambert Academic Publishing, Germany. {{ISBN|9783845416076}}. {{OCLC|935209055}}. |
|||
* Henry George, "[[Progress and Poverty]]: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depressions and of increase of want with increase of wealth: the remedy", 1879. |
|||
* Groppo, Paolo. (1998). [https://web.archive.org/web/20041209060121/http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LR98_2/landrf.htm Land Reform: Land Settlement and Cooperatives Bulletin]. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the UN. |
|||
* Krogh, Peter Frederic. (1986). [http://hdl.handle.net/10822/552663 U.S. and Third World Land Reform]. American Interests. [https://repository.library.georgetown.edu/handle/10822/552494 Dean Peter Krogh Foreign Affairs Digital Archives]. School of Foreign Service, Georgetown University. |
|||
* Goodman, Amy. (2010). [http://www.democracynow.org/2010/8/24/report_global_food_security_and_sovereignty Global Food Security and Sovereignty Threatened by Corporate and Government “Land Grabs” in Poor Countries]. ''[[Democracy Now!]]''. |
|||
* [[Alfred Russel Wallace|Wallace, Alfred Russel]]. (1882). [https://archive.org/details/landnationalisat00walluoft Land Nationalisation: Its necessity and its aims: Being a comparison of the system of landlord and tenant with that of occupying ownership in their influence on the well-being of the people]. |
|||
==External links== |
==External links== |
||
{{commons category|Land reform}} |
|||
*[http://www.landaction.org Land Research Action Network:News, Analysis, and Research on Land Reform] |
|||
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20161130121504/http://www.landaction.org/ Land Research Action Network: News, Analysis, and Research on Land Reform]. |
|||
*[http://www.scotland.gov.uk/Topics/Rural/Land Land Reform in Scotland] |
|||
* [https://web.archive.org/web/20071225190436/http://www.tierraydignidad.org/ Land, Territory and Dignity Forum] |
|||
*[http://www.hrw.org/reports/2002/zimbabwe/ Fast Track Land Reform in Zimbabwe] |
|||
* [https://www.landesa.org/ Landesa] - Securing land rights for the world's poorest. |
|||
*[http://gevask.dtiltas.lt/GeVask/html/agreforma01e.htm The Land Reform of 1919–1940: Lithuania and the Countries of East and Central Europe] |
|||
*[http://www.fao.org/documents/show_cdr.asp?url_file=/DOCREP/005/X2038E/X2038E00.HTM FAO Multilingual Thesaurus on Land Tenure] |
|||
*[http://www.icarrd.org/index.html FAO International Conference on Agrarian Reform and Rural Development (ICARRD), March 2006] |
|||
*[http://www.tierraydignidad.org Civil Society conference "Land, Territory and Dignity", March 2006] |
|||
*William Rees-Mogg, [http://www.timesonline.co.uk/article/0,,1052-2352011,00.html South Africa's bitter harvest], ''The Times'', 11 September 2006 |
|||
<!-- |
|||
These appear to be dead links on the World Bank site: |
|||
* Policy note on [http://rru.worldbank.org/PublicPolicyJournal/Summary.aspx?id=300 "Land Markets: Promoting the Private Sector by Improving Access to Land"] |
|||
* Paper on [http://rru.worldbank.org/PapersLinks/Open.aspx?id=3507 Property Rights and Finance] |
|||
--> |
|||
* World Bank archived online discussion: [http://rru.worldbank.org/Discussions/Topics/Topic45.aspx "Can Formal Property Titling Programs Ensure Increased Business Investments and Growth?"] |
|||
==References== |
|||
* Fu Chen, Liming Wang and John Davis, [http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LTan0031.htm "Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s"], [http://www.fao.org/sd/LTdirect/LR98_2/landrf.htm Land Reform 1998/2], a publication of the Sustainable Development Department of the [[United Nations]]' [[Food and Agriculture Organization]] (FAO). |
|||
* [[William H. Hinton]]. ''Fanshen: A documentary of revolution in a Chinese village''. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966. ISBN 0-520-21040-9. |
|||
*Mark Moyar, [http://www.vietnam.ttu.edu/vietnamcenter/events/1996_Symposium/96papers/moyar.htm "Villager attitudes during the final decade of the Vietnam War"]. Presented at 1996 Vietnam Symposium [http://www.vietnam.ttu.edu/vietnamcenter/events/1996_Symposium/96papers/papers.htm "After the Cold War: Reassessing Vietnam"]. |
|||
* [http://www.tts.fi/uk/publication/teho-magazine/teho04_5.htm#Paakirjoitus Summary of "Efficiency and wellbeing for 80 years" by Tarmo Luoma] on site of ''TEHO'' magazine. |
|||
{{Property navbox}} |
|||
[[Category:Economic history]] |
|||
{{Social democracy}} |
|||
[[Category:Land management]] |
|||
{{Authority control}} |
|||
[[Category:Land reform| ]] |
|||
[[de:Landreform]] |
|||
[[Category:Land administration]] |
|||
[[es:Reforma agraria]] |
|||
[[ |
[[Category:Marxist theory]] |
||
[[Category:Agricultural policy]] |
|||
[[fr:Réforme agraire]] |
|||
[[Category:Decolonization]] |
|||
[[he:רפורמה אגררית]] |
|||
[[Category:Wealth concentration]] |
|||
[[pt:Reforma agrária]] |
|||
[[Category:Plantations]] |
|||
[[sl:Agrarna reforma]] |
|||
[[Category:Social democratic concepts]] |
|||
[[sv:Jordreform]] |
|||
[[vi:Cải cách ruộng đất]] |
|||
[[tr:Toprak reformu]] |
Latest revision as of 17:06, 25 November 2024
Land reform is a form of agrarian reform involving the changing of laws, regulations, or customs regarding land ownership.[1] Land reform may consist of a government-initiated or government-backed property redistribution, generally of agricultural land. Land reform can, therefore, refer to transfer of ownership from the more powerful to the less powerful, such as from a relatively small number of wealthy or noble owners with extensive land holdings (e.g., plantations, large ranches, or agribusiness plots) to individual ownership by those who work the land.[2] Such transfers of ownership may be with or without compensation; compensation may vary from token amounts to the full value of the land.[3]
Land reform may also entail the transfer of land from individual ownership—even peasant ownership in smallholdings—to government-owned collective farms; it has also, in other times and places, referred to the exact opposite: division of government-owned collective farms into smallholdings.[4] The common characteristic of all land reforms is modification or replacement of existing institutional arrangements governing possession and use of land. Thus, while land reform may be radical in nature, such as through large-scale transfers of land from one group to another, it can also be less dramatic, such as regulatory reforms aimed at improving land administration.[5]
Nonetheless, any revision or reform of a country's land laws can still be an intensely political process, as reforming land policies serves to change relationships within and between communities, as well as between communities and the state. Thus even small-scale land reforms and legal modifications may be subject to intense debate or conflict.[6]
Land usage and tenure
[edit]Part of a series on |
Social democracy |
---|
Land ownership and tenure can be perceived as controversial in part because ideas defining what it means to access or control land, such as through "land ownership" or "land tenure", can vary considerably across regions and even within countries.[7] Land reforms, which change what it means to control land, therefore create tensions and conflicts between those who lose and those who gain from these redefinitions (see next section).[8]
Western conceptions of land have evolved over the past several centuries to place greater emphasis on individual land ownership, formalized through documents such as land titles.[9] Control over land may also be perceived less in terms of individual ownership and more in terms of land use, or through what is known as land tenure.[10] Historically, in many parts of Africa for example, land was not owned by an individual, but rather used by an extended family or a village community. Different people in a family or community had different rights to access this land for different purposes and at different times. Such rights were often conveyed through oral history and not formally documented.[11]
These different ideas of land ownership and tenure are sometimes referred to using different terminology. For example, "formal" or "statutory" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with individual land ownership. "Informal" or "customary" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with land tenure.[12]
Terms dictating control over and use of land can therefore take many forms. Some specific examples of present-day or historic forms of formal and informal land ownership include:
- Traditional land tenure, as practiced by the indigenous tribes of Pre-Columbian North America.
- Feudal land ownership, through fiefdoms
- Life estate, interest in real property that ends at death.
- Fee tail, hereditary, non-transferable ownership of real property.
- Fee simple. Under common law, this is the most complete ownership interest one can have in real property.
- Leasehold or rental
- Rights to use a common
- Sharecropping
- Run rig and rundale
- Well-Field System
- Easements
- Kibbutz and moshav
- Satoyama
- Agricultural labor – under which someone works the land in exchange for money, payment in kind, or some combination of the two
- Collective ownership
- Access to land through a membership in a cooperative, or shares in a corporation, which owns the land (typically by fee simple or its equivalent, but possibly under other arrangements).
- Government collectives, such as those that might be found in communist states, whereby government ownership of most agricultural land is combined in various ways with tenure for farming collectives.
Motivation
[edit]Land reform is a deeply political process[13] and therefore many arguments for and against it have emerged. These arguments vary tremendously over time and place. In the twentieth century, many land reforms emerged from a particular political ideology, such as communism or socialism. In the 19th century in colonized states, a colonial government may have changed the laws dictating land ownership to better consolidate political power or to support its colonial economy.[14] In more recent times, electoral mobilization and the use of land as a patronage resource have been proposed as possible motivations for land reform efforts, such as the extensive redistributive land reforms of Robert Mugabe in Zimbabwe.[15]
Arguments for
[edit]Arguments in support of land reform focus on its potential social and economic benefits, particularly in developing countries, that may emerge from reforms focused on greater land formalization. Such benefits may include eradicating food insecurity and alleviating rural poverty.[16]
And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed.
Arguments in support of such reforms gained particular momentum after the publication of The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else by Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto in 2000. The poor, he argues, are often unable to secure formal property rights, such as land titles, to the land on which they live or farm because of poor governance, corruption and/or overly complex bureaucracies. Without land titles or other formal documentation of their land assets, they are less able to access formal credit. Political and legal reforms within countries, according to de Soto, will help to include the poor in formal legal and economic systems, increase the poor's ability to access credit and contribute to economic growth and poverty reduction.[18]
Many international development organizations and bilateral and multilateral donors, such as the World Bank, have embraced de Soto's ideas, or similar ideas, about the benefits of greater formalized land rights.[19] This has translated into a number of development programs that work with governments and civil society organizations to initiate and implement land reforms.[20] Evidence to support the economic and pro-poor benefits of increased formalized land rights are still inconclusive according to some critics (see "Arguments against land reform" below).
Other arguments in support of land reform point to the need to alleviate conflicting land laws, particularly in former colonies, where formal and informal land systems may exist in tension with each other.[21] Such conflicts can make marginalized groups vulnerable to further exploitation.[22] For example, in many countries in Africa with conflicting land laws, AIDS stigmatization has led to an increasing number of AIDS widows being kicked off marital land by in-laws.[23] While the woman may have both customary and statutory rights to the land, confusion over which set of laws has primacy, or even a lack of knowledge of relevant laws, leave many AIDS widows at a significant disadvantage. Also, conflicting formal and informal land laws can also clog a country's legal system, making it prone to corruption.[24]
Additional arguments for land reform focus on the potential environmental benefits of reform. For example, if reform leads to greater security of land ownership, through either formal or informal means, then those that use the land will be better stewards of it.[25]
Land reforms carried out in Japan, Taiwan and South Korea are credited with contributing to the industrial development. The equitable distribution of land led to increasing agricultural outputs, high rural purchasing power and social mobility.[26]
Arguments against
[edit]Many of the arguments in support of land reform speak to its potentially positive social and economic outcomes. Yet, as mentioned previously, land reform is an intensely political process.[8] Thus, many of those opposed to land reform are nervous as to the underlying motivations of those initiating the reform. For example, some may fear that they will be disadvantaged or victimized as a result of the reforms. Others may fear that they will lose out in the economic and political power struggles (especially in under developed countries) that underlie many land reforms.[27]
Other groups and individuals express concerns about land reforms focused on formalization of property rights. While the economic and social benefits of formalized land rights are often touted, some research suggests that such reforms are either ineffective or may cause further hardship or conflict.[28]
Additional arguments against land reform focus on concerns over equity issues and potential elite capture of land, particularly in regards to reforms focused on greater land formalization. If improperly or inadequately implemented, critics worry that such reforms may further disadvantage marginalized groups such as indigenous communities or women.[29] These concerns also lead to questions about the institutional capacity of governments to implement land reforms as they are designed. Even if a country does have this capacity, critics worry that corruption and patrimonialism will lead to further elite capture.[30]
In looking at more radical reforms, such as large-scale land redistribution, arguments against reform include concerns that redistributed land will not be used productively and that owners of expropriated land will not be compensated adequately or compensated at all. Zimbabwe, again, is a commonly cited example of the perils of such large-scale reforms, whereby land redistribution contributed to economic decline and increased food insecurity in the country.[31] In cases where land reform has been enacted as part of socialist collectivization, many of the arguments against collectivization more generally apply.
National efforts
[edit]An early example of land reform was the Irish Land Acts of 1870–1909. Most all newly independent countries of Eastern and Central Europe implemented land reforms in the aftermath of World War I. In most countries, the land in excess of certain limits (20–500 ha (49–1,236 acres), depending on the region and type of land) was expropriated; in Finland, it was redeemed and placed into a special fund.[32]
See also
[edit]- Adverse possession
- Agrarian Justice
- Agrarian reform
- Certificate of occupancy
- Chinese Land Reform
- Citizen's Dividend
- Concentration of land ownership
- Classical rent
- Collectivization in the Soviet Union
- Common land
- Dekulakization
- Differential and absolute ground rent
- Eminent domain
- Enclosure
- Fachhochschule
- Frente Unido de Reforma Agraria
- Gentrification
- Georgism
- Homestead principle
- Land (economics)
- Land Acts (Ireland)
- Land banking
- Land claim
- Land consumption
- Land grabbing
- Land law
- Landlessness
- Land consolidation
- Land Reform in Developing Countries
- Land reforms by country
- Land tenure
- Land titling
- Land value tax
- Manorialism
- México Indígena
- Mutualism
- Natural capital
- Nonpossessory interest in land
- Profit (real property)
- Real estate appraisal
- Restitution
- Serfdom
- Settler
- Speculation
- Squatting
- Stolypin reform
- Usufruct
- Water scarcity
- Zapatismo
References
[edit]- ^ Batty, Fodei Joseph. "Pressures from Above, Below and Both Directions: The Politics of Land Reform in South Africa, Brazil and Zimbabwe". Western Michigan University. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, Illinois. April 7–10, 2005. p. 3. [1]
- ^ Borras, Saturnino M. Jr. "The Philippine Land form in Comparative Perspective: Some conceptual and Methodological Implications". Journal of Agrarian Change. 6,1 (January 2006): 69–101.
- ^ Adams, Martin and J. Howell. "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa". Overseas Development Institute. DFID. Natural Resources Perspectives No. 64. January 2001. [2] Archived 2009-12-05 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Adams, Martin and J. Howell. "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa". Archived 2009-12-05 at the Wayback Machine Overseas Development Institute. DFID. Natural Resources Perspectives No. 64. January 2001.
- ^ Ghana's Land Administration Project Archived 2011-07-21 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ Lund, Christian. Local Politics and the Dynamics of Property in Africa. Cambridge University Press: New York. 2008.
- ^ La Croix, Sumner. "Land Tenure: An Introduction". Working Paper no. 02-13. May 2002. University of Hawaii.
- ^ a b Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." African Affairs. 2007. 106: 557–586.
- ^ Locke, John. Two Treatises of Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [1689] 1991. and Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. Books 1—III. London: Penguin Books. 1999.
- ^ "What is land tenure?" Food and Agriculture Organization.
- ^ Dekker, Henri A.L. The Invisible Line: Land Reform, Land Tenure Security and Land Registration. Ashgate: Burlington, 2003. p. 2.
- ^ "Land Law." Law and Development. The World Bank. February 23, 2007. [3],
- ^ : Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." African Affairs. 2007. 106: 557–86. and Manji, Ambreena. The Politics of Land Reform in Ghana: From Communal Tenure to Free Markets. Zed Books: New York. 2006.
- ^ Berry, Sata. "Debating the land question in Africa." Johns Hopkins University. N.d. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-01-13. Retrieved 2010-12-02.
{{cite web}}
: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link) - ^ Boone, Catherine and N. Kriger. "Multiparty elections and land patronage: Zimbabwe and Cote d'Ivoire." Commonwealth and Comparative Politics. 48,1 (April 2010): 173–202.
- ^ Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, Markelova, Helen and Moore, Kelsey. "The Role of Collective Action and Property Rights in Climate Change Strategies." International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), 2010. and Economic Commission for Africa. "Land Tenure Systems and their Impacts on Food security and Sustainable Development in Africa." 2009.
- ^ The Grapes of Wrath, by John Steinbeck, Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, pg 238
- ^ De Soto, Hernando. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books. 2000.
- ^ Deininger, Klaus W. Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. The World Bank. 2003. [4]
- ^ World Bank. "Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets, and Collateralized Lending." 2003. [5]
- ^ Moore, Jina. "Africa's continental divide: land disputes." Christian Science Monitor. January 30, 2010. [6]
- ^ Kafmbe, Anthony Luyirika. "Access to Justice: Widows and the Institutions Regulating Succession to Property in Uganda." Human Rights Review; Jul2006, Vol. 7 Issue 4, pp. 100–113.
- ^ Ambasa-Shisanya, Constance. "Widowhood in the Era of HIV/AIDS: A Case Study of the Slaya District, Kenya." Journal of Social Aspects of HIV/AIDS. August 2007. 2:2, 606–615.
- ^ Tettey, Wisdom, B. Gebe and K. Ansah-Koi. "The Politics of Land and Land-related Conflicts in Ghana: A Summary." Land Policy Reform Project. Institute for Statistical, Social and Economic Research at the University of Ghana. 2008. [7] Archived 2020-03-07 at the Wayback Machine
- ^ World Resources Institute. "The Wealth of the Poor: Managing Ecosystems to Fight Poverty." 2005. "World Resources 2005 -- the Wealth of the Poor: Managing ecosystems to fight poverty | World Resources Institute". Archived from the original on 2011-08-07. Retrieved 2010-12-02. and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). "Land Tenure and Rural Development." FAO Land Tenure Studies No. 3. 2002. Accessed August 21, 2010. Available: [8][permanent dead link ]
- ^ "Land: The Triumph of Gardening". How Asia Works: Success and Failure in the World's Most Dynamic Region. Grove Press. 2014. ISBN 9780802121325.
- ^ "A chance to improve how Kenya is run." The Economist. July 29, 2010
- ^ Bourbeau, Heather, "Property Wrongs." Foreign Policy. Nov/Dec 2001. Issue 127, pp. 78–79 and Nyamu Musembi, Celestine. "De Soto and Land Relations in rural Africa: breathing life into dead theories about property rights." Third World Quarterly. 2007. 28:8, 1457–1478.
- ^ Drimie, Scott. "The Impact of HIV/AIDS on Land: Case Studies from Kenya, Lesotho and South Africa." Food and Agriculture Organization. August 2002. and Varley, Ann. "Gender and Property Formalization: Conventional and Alternative Approaches." World Development. October 2007. 35:10, 1739–1753.
- ^ Gender in Agriculture Source Book. The World Bank, FAO and IFAD. 2009.[9]
- ^ "From breadbasket to basket case." The Economist. June 27, 2002
- ^ Gediminas Vaskela. The Land Reform of 1919–1940: Lithuania and the Countries of East and Central Europe Archived 2012-03-22 at the Wayback Machine
Further reading
[edit]- Bernstein, H. (2002). "Land Reform: Taking a Long(er) View". Journal of Agrarian Change. 2 (4): 433–463. Bibcode:2002JAgrC...2..433B. doi:10.1111/1471-0366.00042.
- Caralee McLiesh and Richard E. Messick, Moderators. (2004). "Can Formal Property Titling Programs Ensure Increased Business Investments and Growth?". World Bank.
- Ciparisse, Gérard. (2003). Multilingual Thesaurus on Land Tenure. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the UN. ISBN 9251042837.
- Cahill, Kevin. "Who Owns The World: The Hidden Facts Behind Landownership", Mainstream Publishing, 2006, ISBN 9781845961589. OCLC 746882317.
- Cahill, Kevin. "Who Owns Britain: The Hidden Facts Behind Landownership in the UK and Ireland", Canongate Books, 2002. ISBN 9781841953106. OCLC 1015469648.
- Michael Lipton, Land Reform in Developing Countries: Property rights and property wrongs, Routledge, 2009
- R. H. Tawney, Land and Labour in China New York, Harcourt Brace & Company (1979). 3rd Edition. ISBN 9780374977719. OCLC 709358069.
- Fu Chen, Liming Wang and John Davis, "Land reform in rural China since the mid-1980s", Land Reform 1998/2, a publication of the Sustainable Development Department of the United Nations' Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO).
- William H. Hinton. Fanshen: A Documentary of Revolution in a Chinese Village. New York: Monthly Review Press, 1966. ISBN 9780520210400. OCLC 258568918.
- Ho, Peter. (2001, June). Who Owns China's Land? Policies, Property Rights and Deliberate Institutional Ambiguity, The China Quarterly, Vol. 166, June 2001, pp. 387–414
- Ho, Peter. (2006). "Institutions In Transition: Land Ownership, Property Rights and Social Conflict in China. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780199280698. OCLC 1292686440.
- Mark Moyar. "Villager attitudes during the final decade of the Vietnam War". Presented at 1996 Vietnam Symposium "After the Cold War: Reassessing Vietnam".
- Summary of "Efficiency and wellbeing for 80 years" by Tarmo Luoma on site of TEHO magazine.
- Rudzani Albert Makhado and Kgabo Lawrance Masehela. (2012). Perspectives on South Africa's Land Reform Debate. Lambert Academic Publishing, Germany. ISBN 9783845416076. OCLC 935209055.
- Henry George, "Progress and Poverty: An inquiry into the cause of industrial depressions and of increase of want with increase of wealth: the remedy", 1879.
- Groppo, Paolo. (1998). Land Reform: Land Settlement and Cooperatives Bulletin. Food and Agriculture Organization (FAO) of the UN.
- Krogh, Peter Frederic. (1986). U.S. and Third World Land Reform. American Interests. Dean Peter Krogh Foreign Affairs Digital Archives. School of Foreign Service, Georgetown University.
- Goodman, Amy. (2010). Global Food Security and Sovereignty Threatened by Corporate and Government “Land Grabs” in Poor Countries. Democracy Now!.
- Wallace, Alfred Russel. (1882). Land Nationalisation: Its necessity and its aims: Being a comparison of the system of landlord and tenant with that of occupying ownership in their influence on the well-being of the people.
External links
[edit]- Land Research Action Network: News, Analysis, and Research on Land Reform.
- Land, Territory and Dignity Forum
- Landesa - Securing land rights for the world's poorest.