Cartel: Difference between revisions
Myeconomics (talk | contribs) Added reference to description of Sherman Act 1890. |
Jb45329999 (talk | contribs) Added leniency programme info, examples. More info on laws surrounding detection and penalties Tags: references removed Visual edit |
||
Line 19: | Line 19: | ||
== Types == |
== Types == |
||
Cartels have many structures and functions that ideally enable corporations to navigate and control market uncertainties and gain collusive profits within their industry. A typical cartel often requires what competition authorities refer to as a CAU (Contact, Agreement or Understanding). <ref>{{Cite journal|last=Jeffrey|first=R|title=Cartels, Concerns and Trusts|journal=The Oxford handbook of business history|publisher=Ontario 2001|pages=269-274|via=Oxford Univ. Pres, 2007}}</ref> Typologies have emerged to distinguish distinct forms of cartels: |
|||
Cartels have many structures and functions. Typologies have emerged to distinguish distinct forms of cartels:<ref>Jeffrey R. Fear: Cartels. In: Geoffrey Jones; Jonathan Zeitlin (ed.): The Oxford handbook of business history. Oxford: Univ. Press, 2007, p. 269–274; [[Robert Liefmann]]: ''Cartels, Concerns and Trusts'', Ontario 2001 [London 1932], p. 63–71.</ref> |
|||
* Selling or buying cartels unite against the cartel's customers or suppliers, respectively. The former type is more frequent than the latter. |
* Selling or buying cartels unite against the cartel's customers or suppliers, respectively. The former type is more frequent than the latter. |
||
* Domestic cartels only have members from one country, whereas international cartels have members from more than one country.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Regulating Competition: Cartel registers in the twentieth-century world|last1=Fellman|first1=Susanna|last2=Shanahan|first2=Martin|publisher=Routledge|year=2015|isbn=9781138021648|location=London|pages=224}}</ref> There have been full-fledged international cartels that have comprised the whole world, such as the international steel cartel of the period between World War I and II. |
* Domestic cartels only have members from one country, whereas international cartels have members from more than one country.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Regulating Competition: Cartel registers in the twentieth-century world|last1=Fellman|first1=Susanna|last2=Shanahan|first2=Martin|publisher=Routledge|year=2015|isbn=9781138021648|location=London|pages=224}}</ref> There have been full-fledged international cartels that have comprised the whole world, such as the international steel cartel of the period between World War I and II. |
||
* Price cartels engage in [[price fixing]], normally to raise [[price]]s for a commodity above the competitive price level. The loosest form of a price cartel can be recognized in [[tacit collusion]], wherein smaller enterprises |
* Price cartels engage in [[price fixing]], normally to raise [[price]]s for a commodity above the competitive price level. The loosest form of a price cartel can be recognized in [[tacit collusion]], wherein smaller enterprises individually devise their prices and market shares in response to the same market conditions, without direct communication, resulting in a less competitive outcome. This type of collusion is generally legal and can achieve a monopolistic outcome. |
||
* Quota cartels distribute proportional shares of the market to their members. |
* Quota cartels distribute proportional shares of the market to their members. |
||
* Common sales cartels sell their joint [[Output (economics)|output]] through a central selling agency (in [[French language|French]]: ''[[wikt:comptoir|comptoir]]''). They are also known as [[syndicate]]s (French: ''syndicat industriel''). |
* Common sales cartels sell their joint [[Output (economics)|output]] through a central selling agency (in [[French language|French]]: ''[[wikt:comptoir|comptoir]]''). They are also known as [[syndicate]]s (French: ''syndicat industriel''). |
||
Line 35: | Line 35: | ||
A survey of hundreds of published economic studies and legal decisions of antitrust authorities found that the median price increase achieved by cartels in the last 200 years is about 23 percent. Private international cartels (those with participants from two or more nations) had an average price increase of 28 percent, whereas domestic cartels averaged 18 percent. Less than 10 percent of all cartels in the sample failed to raise market prices.<ref>John M. Connor. Cartel Overcharges, p. 249–387 of The Law and Economics of Class Actions, in Vol. 29 of Research in Law and Economics, edited by James Langenfeld (March 2014). Bingley, UK: Emerald House Publishing Ltd. June 2017</ref> |
A survey of hundreds of published economic studies and legal decisions of antitrust authorities found that the median price increase achieved by cartels in the last 200 years is about 23 percent. Private international cartels (those with participants from two or more nations) had an average price increase of 28 percent, whereas domestic cartels averaged 18 percent. Less than 10 percent of all cartels in the sample failed to raise market prices.<ref>John M. Connor. Cartel Overcharges, p. 249–387 of The Law and Economics of Class Actions, in Vol. 29 of Research in Law and Economics, edited by James Langenfeld (March 2014). Bingley, UK: Emerald House Publishing Ltd. June 2017</ref> |
||
In general, cartel agreements are economically unstable in that there is an [[incentive]] for members to cheat by selling at below the cartel's agreed price or selling more than the cartel's production quotas. Many cartels that attempt to set product prices are unsuccessful in the long term because of cheating punishment mechanisms such as price wars or financial punishment<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Levenstein|first=Margaret C.|last2=Suslow|first2=Valerie Y.|date=2006|title=What determined cartel success?|journal=Journal of Economic Literature|volume=44|pages=43-95|via=American Economic Association}}</ref>. Empirical studies of 20th-century cartels have determined that the mean duration of discovered cartels is from 5 to 8 years.<ref>[[Margaret Levenstein|Levenstein, Margaret C.]] and Valerie Y. Suslow. "What Determines Cartel Success?" Journal of Economic Literature 64 (March 2006): 43–95</ref> Once a cartel is broken, the incentives to form a new cartel return, and the cartel may be re-formed. Publicly known cartels that do not follow this [[business cycle]] include, by some accounts, OPEC. |
In general, cartel agreements are economically unstable in that there is an [[incentive]] for members to cheat by selling at below the cartel's agreed price or selling more than the cartel's production quotas. Many cartels that attempt to set product prices are unsuccessful in the long term because of cheating punishment mechanisms such as price wars or financial punishment<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Levenstein|first=Margaret C.|last2=Suslow|first2=Valerie Y.|date=2006|title=What determined cartel success?|journal=Journal of Economic Literature|volume=44|pages=43-95|via=American Economic Association}}</ref>. Empirical studies of 20th-century cartels have determined that the mean duration of discovered cartels is from 5 to 8 years and overcharged by approximately 32%.<ref>[[Margaret Levenstein|Levenstein, Margaret C.]] and Valerie Y. Suslow. "What Determines Cartel Success?" Journal of Economic Literature 64 (March 2006): 43–95</ref> Within the industries that have operating cartels, the median number of cartel members is 8. Once a cartel is broken, the incentives to form a new cartel return, and the cartel may be re-formed. Publicly known cartels that do not follow this [[business cycle]] include, by some accounts, OPEC. |
||
Cartels often practice price fixing internationally. When the agreement to control prices is sanctioned by a multilateral treaty or protected by national sovereignty, no antitrust actions may be initiated.<ref>Connor, John M. ''Private International Cartels: A Concise Introduction: SSRN Working Paper.'' (November 12, 2014). [http://ssrn.com/abstract=2523883 Abstract].</ref> OPEC countries partially control the price of oil, and the [[International Air Transport Association]] (IATA) fixes prices for international airline tickets while the organization is excepted from antitrust law.<ref>{{Cite journal| last=Hannigan| first=John A.|date=1982|title=Unfriendly Skies: The Decline of the World Aviation Cartel| journal=The Pacific Sociological Review| volume=25 |issue=1| pages=107–136| doi=10.2307/1388890| issn=0030-8919| jstor=1388890| s2cid=158297510}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal | last=Koffler| first=Warren|date=Spring 1966|title=IATA: It's legal structure - A critical review| url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/jalc32&id=238&collection=journals&index=| journal=Journal of Air Law and Commerce | volume=32| pages=222–235| via=HeinOnline}}</ref> |
Cartels often practice price fixing internationally. When the agreement to control prices is sanctioned by a multilateral treaty or protected by national sovereignty, no antitrust actions may be initiated.<ref>Connor, John M. ''Private International Cartels: A Concise Introduction: SSRN Working Paper.'' (November 12, 2014). [http://ssrn.com/abstract=2523883 Abstract].</ref> OPEC countries partially control the price of oil, and the [[International Air Transport Association]] (IATA) fixes prices for international airline tickets while the organization is excepted from antitrust law.<ref>{{Cite journal| last=Hannigan| first=John A.|date=1982|title=Unfriendly Skies: The Decline of the World Aviation Cartel| journal=The Pacific Sociological Review| volume=25 |issue=1| pages=107–136| doi=10.2307/1388890| issn=0030-8919| jstor=1388890| s2cid=158297510}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal | last=Koffler| first=Warren|date=Spring 1966|title=IATA: It's legal structure - A critical review| url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/jalc32&id=238&collection=journals&index=| journal=Journal of Air Law and Commerce | volume=32| pages=222–235| via=HeinOnline}}</ref> |
||
Line 50: | Line 50: | ||
Prior to World War II, members of cartels could sign contracts that were enforceable in courts of law except in the United States. Before 1945, cartels were tolerated in Europe and specifically promoted as a business practice in German-speaking countries.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Competition Policy in the European Union|last1=Cini|first1=Michelle|last2=McGowan|first2=Lee|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan|year=2009|isbn=978-0-230-00675-1|location=New York|pages=63}}</ref> In ''U.S. v. National Lead Co. et al.'', the [[Supreme Court of the United States]] noted the testimony of individuals who cited that a cartel, in its versatile form, is {{blockquote|a combination of producers for the purpose of regulating production and, frequently, prices, and an association by agreement of companies or sections of companies having common interests so as to prevent extreme or unfair competition.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Strategies to Achieve a Binding International Agreement on Regulating Cartels: Overcoming Doha Standstill|last=Lee|first=John|publisher=Springer|year=2016|isbn=978-981-10-2755-0|location=Berlin|pages=13}}</ref>}} |
Prior to World War II, members of cartels could sign contracts that were enforceable in courts of law except in the United States. Before 1945, cartels were tolerated in Europe and specifically promoted as a business practice in German-speaking countries.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Competition Policy in the European Union|last1=Cini|first1=Michelle|last2=McGowan|first2=Lee|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan|year=2009|isbn=978-0-230-00675-1|location=New York|pages=63}}</ref> In ''U.S. v. National Lead Co. et al.'', the [[Supreme Court of the United States]] noted the testimony of individuals who cited that a cartel, in its versatile form, is {{blockquote|a combination of producers for the purpose of regulating production and, frequently, prices, and an association by agreement of companies or sections of companies having common interests so as to prevent extreme or unfair competition.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Strategies to Achieve a Binding International Agreement on Regulating Cartels: Overcoming Doha Standstill|last=Lee|first=John|publisher=Springer|year=2016|isbn=978-981-10-2755-0|location=Berlin|pages=13}}</ref>}} |
||
The first legislation against cartels to be enforced is the [[Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890|Sherman Act 1890]], which also prohibits price fixing, market-sharing, output restrictions and other anti-competitive conduct.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Sullivan|first=E. Thomas|title=The political economy of the Sherman Act: The first one hundred years|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=1991|isbn=9780195066425}}</ref> |
The first legislation against cartels to be enforced is the [[Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890|Sherman Act 1890]], which also prohibits price fixing, market-sharing, output restrictions and other anti-competitive conduct.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Sullivan|first=E. Thomas|title=The political economy of the Sherman Act: The first one hundred years|publisher=Oxford University Press|year=1991|isbn=9780195066425}}</ref> Section 1 and 2 of the Act outlines the law in regards to cartels,<blockquote>Section 1: |
||
Every contract, combination in the form of [[Trust (19th century)|trust]] or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.<sup>[26]</sup> |
|||
⚫ | Today, price fixing by private entities is illegal under the antitrust laws of more than 140 countries. The commodities of prosecuted international cartels include [[lysine]], [[citric acid]], [[graphite]] [[electrode]]s, and bulk [[vitamin]]s.<ref>Connor, John M. (2008): ''Global Price Fixing: 2nd Paperback Edition''. Heidelberg: Springer.</ref> In many countries, the predominant belief is that cartels are contrary to free and fair competition, considered the backbone of political democracy.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Controlling International Technology Transfer: Issues, Perspectives, and Policy Implications|last1=Sagafi-Nejad|first1=Tagi|last2=Moxon|first2=Richard|last3=Perlmutter|first3=Howard|publisher=Pergamon Press|year=2017|isbn=978-0-08-027180-4|location=New York|pages=180}}</ref> Maintaining cartels continues to become harder for cartels. Even if international cartels cannot be regulated as a whole by individual nations, their individual activities in domestic markets are affected.<ref>Fellman & Shanahan, p. 224.</ref> |
||
Section 2: |
|||
⚫ | Unlike other cartels, export cartels are legal in virtually all jurisdictions, despite their harmful effects on affected markets.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Martyniszyn |first1=Marek |title=Export Cartels: Is it Legal to Target your Neighbour? Analysis in Light of Recent Case Law |journal=Journal of International Economic Law |date=2012 |volume=15 |issue=1 |page=181 |doi=10.1093/jiel/jgs003 |s2cid=153887704 |url=https://pure.qub.ac.uk/en/publications/export-cartels-is-it-legal-to-target-your-neighbour-analysis-in-light-of-recent-case-law(76b0a369-a9db-4f5e-aadb-7ffdc7b84164).html }}</ref> |
||
Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $100 million if a corporation, or, if any other person, $1 million, or by imprisonment not exceeding ten years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court.<sup>[27]</sup></blockquote> |
|||
== Leniency programme == |
|||
To fight back hardcore cartels, competition authorities create leniency programme as a means to detect cartel by encouraging cartel members to come forward with proof of cartel conduct in exchange for reduced penalties. |
|||
In 1996, the European Commission adopted the first Leniency Notice, which was reformed in 2002 in the [[European Union competition law]]. The policy offers “whistle blowers” up to full immunity or reduced fines<ref>{{Cite book|last=Andersson|first=Helene|title=Access and cartel cases: Ensuring effective competition law enforcement (First edition)|publisher=Hart Publishing|year=2020|location=Oxford|pages=218}}</ref>. The policy has proved its effectiveness in approximately 60% of detected cases of European cartels.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Carmeliet|first=Tine|date=2012|title=How lenient is the European leniency system? An overview of current (dis)incentives to blow the whistle|url=https://www.law.kuleuven.be/apps/jura/public/art/48n3/carmeliet.pdf|journal=Jura Falconis Jg|volume=48|pages=463-512}}</ref> |
|||
In practice, detecting and desisting cartels is undertaken through the use of economic analysis and leniency programmes. Economic analysis is implemented to identify any discrepancies in market behaviour between both suspected and unsuspected cartel engaged firms. A structural approach is done in the form of screening already suspicious firms for industry traits of a typical cartel price path. On the contrary, when aiming to create suspicion around potential cartels, a behavioural approach is often used to identify behavioural collusive patterns, to initiate further economic analysis into identifying and prosecuting those involved in cartel operations. |
|||
Leniency policies have become the most used tool to detect cartels around the world with the adoption of over 50 jurisdictions.<ref>{{Cite book|last=Beaton-Wells|first=Caron|title=Anti-cartel enforcement in a contemporary age: Leniency religion|last2=Tran|first2=Christopher|publisher=Hart Publishing|year=2015|location=Oxford|pages=3}}</ref> |
|||
Leniency programmes were first introduced in 1978 in the US, before being successfully reformed in 1993. The underlying principle of a leniency program is to offer discretionary penalty reductions for corporations or individuals who are affiliated with cartel operations in exchange for their cooperation with enforcement authorities to identify and penalise other participating members.<sup>[28]</sup> According to the Australian Department of Justice, the following 6 conditions must be met for for admission into a leniency program: |
|||
# The corporation is the first one to come forward and qualify for leniency with respect to the illegal activity being reported; |
|||
# The Division, at the time the corporation comes in, does not yet have evidence against the company that is likely to result in a sustainable conviction; |
|||
# The corporation, upon its discovery of the illegal activity being reported, took prompt and effective action to terminate its part in the activity; |
|||
# The corporation reports the wrongdoing with candor and completeness and provides full, continuing and complete cooperation that advances the Division in its investigation; |
|||
# The confession of wrongdoing is truly a corporate act, as opposed to isolated confessions of individual executives or officials; |
|||
# Where possible, the corporation makes restitution to injured parties; and |
|||
# The Division determines that granting leniency would not be unfair to others, considering the nature of the illegal activity, the confessing corporation's role in it, and when the corporation comes forward. <sup>[29]</sup> |
|||
The application of leniency programme penalties varies according to individual countries policies and are proportional to cartel profits and years of infringement. However, typically the first corporation or individual to cooperate will receive the most reduced penalty in comparison to those who come forward later. The effectiveness of leniency programmes in destabilising and deterring cartels is evidenced by the decreased formation and discovery of cartels in the US since the introduction of the programmes in 1993.<sup>[30]</sup> Some examples include |
|||
* [[Lysine price-fixing conspiracy|Lysine]] Cartel: An employee of [[Archer Daniels Midland|Archer Daniels Midland (ADM)]] alerted authorities of the existence of the cartel within the Lysine industry. |
|||
* Stainless steel: Buyers of the product complained to the [[European Commission|European Commission (EC)]] about price spikes. |
|||
* Sodium gluconate: Defendants in the lysine case informed authorities of collusive behaviours between corporations in this industry. |
|||
⚫ | Today, price fixing by private entities is illegal under the antitrust laws of more than 140 countries. The commodities of prosecuted international cartels include [[lysine]], [[citric acid]], [[graphite]] [[electrode]]s, and bulk [[vitamin]]s.<ref>Connor, John M. (2008): ''Global Price Fixing: 2nd Paperback Edition''. Heidelberg: Springer.</ref> In many countries, the predominant belief is that cartels are contrary to free and fair competition, considered the backbone of political democracy.<ref>{{Cite book|title=Controlling International Technology Transfer: Issues, Perspectives, and Policy Implications|last1=Sagafi-Nejad|first1=Tagi|last2=Moxon|first2=Richard|last3=Perlmutter|first3=Howard|publisher=Pergamon Press|year=2017|isbn=978-0-08-027180-4|location=New York|pages=180}}</ref> Maintaining cartels continues to become harder for cartels. Even if international cartels cannot be regulated as a whole by individual nations, their individual activities in domestic markets are affected.<ref>Fellman & Shanahan, p. 224.</ref> |
||
⚫ | Unlike other cartels, export cartels are legal in virtually all jurisdictions, despite their harmful effects on affected markets.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Martyniszyn |first1=Marek |title=Export Cartels: Is it Legal to Target your Neighbour? Analysis in Light of Recent Case Law |journal=Journal of International Economic Law |date=2012 |volume=15 |issue=1 |page=181 |doi=10.1093/jiel/jgs003 |s2cid=153887704 |url=https://pure.qub.ac.uk/en/publications/export-cartels-is-it-legal-to-target-your-neighbour-analysis-in-light-of-recent-case-law(76b0a369-a9db-4f5e-aadb-7ffdc7b84164).html }}</ref> |
||
==Examples== |
== Examples == |
||
[[File:ATF policy.jpg|thumb|The printing equipment company [[American Type Founders]] (ATF) explicitly states in its 1923 manual that its goal is to "discourage unhealthy competition" in the printing industry.]] |
[[File:ATF policy.jpg|thumb|The printing equipment company [[American Type Founders]] (ATF) explicitly states in its 1923 manual that its goal is to "discourage unhealthy competition" in the printing industry.]] |
||
* [[Asian Racing Federation]]: The [[Asian Racing Federation]] formed a cartel, documented in the [[Good Neighbour Policy (horse racing)|Good Neighbour Policy]] signed on September 1, 2003. |
* [[Asian Racing Federation]]: The [[Asian Racing Federation]] formed a cartel, documented in the [[Good Neighbour Policy (horse racing)|Good Neighbour Policy]] signed on September 1, 2003. |
Revision as of 01:23, 26 April 2021
This article needs additional citations for verification. (December 2019) |
Competition law |
---|
Basic concepts |
Anti-competitive practices |
|
Enforcement authorities and organizations |
A cartel is a group of independent market participants who collude with each other in order to improve their profits and dominate the market. Cartels are usually associations in the same sphere of business, and thus an alliance of rivals. Most jurisdictions consider it anti-competitive behavior and have outlawed such practices. Cartel behavior includes price fixing, bid rigging, and reductions in output. The doctrine in economics that analyzes cartels is cartel theory. Cartels are distinguished from other forms of collusion or anti-competitive organization such as corporate mergers.
Etymology
The word cartel comes from the Italian word cartello, which means a "leaf of paper" or "placard". The Italian word became cartel in Middle French, which was borrowed into English. Its current use in Mexican and Colombian drug-trafficking world comes from Spanish cartel. In English, the word was originally used for a written agreement between warring nations to regulate the treatment and exchange of prisoners.[1]
History
Cartels have existed since ancient times.[2] Guilds in the European Middle Ages, associations of craftsmen or merchants of the same trade, have been regarded as cartel-like.[3] Tightly organized sales cartels in the mining industry of the late Middle Ages, like the 1301 salt syndicate in France and Naples, or the Alaun cartel of 1470 between the Papal State and Naples.[4] Both unions had common sales organizations for overall production called the Societas Communis Vendicionis [Common Sales Society].
Laissez-faire (liberal) economic conditions dominated Europe and North America in the 18th and 19th centuries. Around 1870, cartels first appeared in industries formerly under free-market conditions.[5] Although cartels existed in all economically developed countries, the core area of cartel activities was in central Europe. The German Empire and Austria-Hungary were nicknamed the "lands of the cartels".[6] Cartels were also widespread in the United States during the period of robber barons and industrial trusts.[7]
The creation of cartels increased globally after World War I. They became the leading form of market organization, particularly in Europe and Japan. In the 1930s, authoritarian regimes such as Nazi Germany, Italy under Mussolini, and Spain under Franco used cartels to organize their corporatist economies. Between the late 19th century and around 1945, the United States was ambivalent about cartels and trusts. There were periods of both opposition to market concentration and relative tolerance of cartels. During World War II, the United States strictly turned away from cartels.[8] After 1945, American-promoted market liberalism led to a worldwide cartel ban, where cartels continue to be obstructed in an increasing number of countries and circumstances.
Types
Cartels have many structures and functions that ideally enable corporations to navigate and control market uncertainties and gain collusive profits within their industry. A typical cartel often requires what competition authorities refer to as a CAU (Contact, Agreement or Understanding). [9] Typologies have emerged to distinguish distinct forms of cartels:
- Selling or buying cartels unite against the cartel's customers or suppliers, respectively. The former type is more frequent than the latter.
- Domestic cartels only have members from one country, whereas international cartels have members from more than one country.[10] There have been full-fledged international cartels that have comprised the whole world, such as the international steel cartel of the period between World War I and II.
- Price cartels engage in price fixing, normally to raise prices for a commodity above the competitive price level. The loosest form of a price cartel can be recognized in tacit collusion, wherein smaller enterprises individually devise their prices and market shares in response to the same market conditions, without direct communication, resulting in a less competitive outcome. This type of collusion is generally legal and can achieve a monopolistic outcome.
- Quota cartels distribute proportional shares of the market to their members.
- Common sales cartels sell their joint output through a central selling agency (in French: comptoir). They are also known as syndicates (French: syndicat industriel).
- Territorial cartels distribute districts of the market to be used only by individual participants, which act as monopolists.
- Submission cartels control offers given to public tenders. They use bid rigging: bidders for a tender agree on a bid price. They then do not bid in unison, or share the return from the winning bid among themselves.[11]
- Technology and patent cartels share knowledge about technology or science within themselves while they limit the information from outside individuals.
- Condition cartels unify contractual terms – the modes of payment and delivery, or warranty limits.
- Standardization cartels implement common standards for sold or purchased products. If the members of a cartel produce different sorts or grades of a good, conversion factors are applied to calculate the value of the respective output.
- Compulsory cartels, also called "forced cartels", are established or maintained by external pressure. Voluntary cartels are formed by the free will of their participants.
Effects
A survey of hundreds of published economic studies and legal decisions of antitrust authorities found that the median price increase achieved by cartels in the last 200 years is about 23 percent. Private international cartels (those with participants from two or more nations) had an average price increase of 28 percent, whereas domestic cartels averaged 18 percent. Less than 10 percent of all cartels in the sample failed to raise market prices.[12]
In general, cartel agreements are economically unstable in that there is an incentive for members to cheat by selling at below the cartel's agreed price or selling more than the cartel's production quotas. Many cartels that attempt to set product prices are unsuccessful in the long term because of cheating punishment mechanisms such as price wars or financial punishment[13]. Empirical studies of 20th-century cartels have determined that the mean duration of discovered cartels is from 5 to 8 years and overcharged by approximately 32%.[14] Within the industries that have operating cartels, the median number of cartel members is 8. Once a cartel is broken, the incentives to form a new cartel return, and the cartel may be re-formed. Publicly known cartels that do not follow this business cycle include, by some accounts, OPEC.
Cartels often practice price fixing internationally. When the agreement to control prices is sanctioned by a multilateral treaty or protected by national sovereignty, no antitrust actions may be initiated.[15] OPEC countries partially control the price of oil, and the International Air Transport Association (IATA) fixes prices for international airline tickets while the organization is excepted from antitrust law.[16][17]
Organization
Drawing upon research on organizational misconduct, scholars in economics, sociology and management have studied the organization of cartels.[18][19] They have paid attention to the way cartel participants work together to conceal their activities from antitrust authorities. Even more than reaching efficiency, participating firms need to ensure that their collective secret is maintained.[20] It has also been argued that the diversity of the participants (e.g., age and size of the firms) influences their ability to coordinate to avoid being detected.[21]
Cartel theory versus antitrust concept
The scientific analysis of cartels is based on cartel theory. It was pioneered in 1883 by the Austrian economist Friedrich Kleinwächter and in its early stages was developed mainly by German-speaking scholars.[22] These scholars tended to regard cartels as an acceptable part of the economy. At the same time, American lawyers increasingly turned against trade restrictions, including all cartels. The Sherman act, which impeded the formation and activities of cartels, was passed in the United States in 1890. The American viewpoint, supported by activists like Thurman Arnold and Harley M. Kilgore, eventually prevailed when governmental policy in Washington could have a larger impact in World War II.
Legislation
Because cartels are likely to have an impact on market positions, they are subjected to competition law, which is executed by governmental competition regulators. Very similar regulations apply to corporate mergers. A single entity that holds a monopoly is not considered a cartel but can be sanctioned through other abuses of its monopoly.
Prior to World War II, members of cartels could sign contracts that were enforceable in courts of law except in the United States. Before 1945, cartels were tolerated in Europe and specifically promoted as a business practice in German-speaking countries.[23] In U.S. v. National Lead Co. et al., the Supreme Court of the United States noted the testimony of individuals who cited that a cartel, in its versatile form, is
a combination of producers for the purpose of regulating production and, frequently, prices, and an association by agreement of companies or sections of companies having common interests so as to prevent extreme or unfair competition.[24]
The first legislation against cartels to be enforced is the Sherman Act 1890, which also prohibits price fixing, market-sharing, output restrictions and other anti-competitive conduct.[25] Section 1 and 2 of the Act outlines the law in regards to cartels,
Section 1:
Every contract, combination in the form of trust or otherwise, or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, is declared to be illegal.[26]
Section 2:
Every person who shall monopolize, or attempt to monopolize, or combine or conspire with any other person or persons, to monopolize any part of the trade or commerce among the several States, or with foreign nations, shall be deemed guilty of a felony, and, on conviction thereof, shall be punished by fine not exceeding $100 million if a corporation, or, if any other person, $1 million, or by imprisonment not exceeding ten years, or by both said punishments, in the discretion of the court.[27]
In practice, detecting and desisting cartels is undertaken through the use of economic analysis and leniency programmes. Economic analysis is implemented to identify any discrepancies in market behaviour between both suspected and unsuspected cartel engaged firms. A structural approach is done in the form of screening already suspicious firms for industry traits of a typical cartel price path. On the contrary, when aiming to create suspicion around potential cartels, a behavioural approach is often used to identify behavioural collusive patterns, to initiate further economic analysis into identifying and prosecuting those involved in cartel operations.
Leniency programmes were first introduced in 1978 in the US, before being successfully reformed in 1993. The underlying principle of a leniency program is to offer discretionary penalty reductions for corporations or individuals who are affiliated with cartel operations in exchange for their cooperation with enforcement authorities to identify and penalise other participating members.[28] According to the Australian Department of Justice, the following 6 conditions must be met for for admission into a leniency program:
- The corporation is the first one to come forward and qualify for leniency with respect to the illegal activity being reported;
- The Division, at the time the corporation comes in, does not yet have evidence against the company that is likely to result in a sustainable conviction;
- The corporation, upon its discovery of the illegal activity being reported, took prompt and effective action to terminate its part in the activity;
- The corporation reports the wrongdoing with candor and completeness and provides full, continuing and complete cooperation that advances the Division in its investigation;
- The confession of wrongdoing is truly a corporate act, as opposed to isolated confessions of individual executives or officials;
- Where possible, the corporation makes restitution to injured parties; and
- The Division determines that granting leniency would not be unfair to others, considering the nature of the illegal activity, the confessing corporation's role in it, and when the corporation comes forward. [29]
The application of leniency programme penalties varies according to individual countries policies and are proportional to cartel profits and years of infringement. However, typically the first corporation or individual to cooperate will receive the most reduced penalty in comparison to those who come forward later. The effectiveness of leniency programmes in destabilising and deterring cartels is evidenced by the decreased formation and discovery of cartels in the US since the introduction of the programmes in 1993.[30] Some examples include
- Lysine Cartel: An employee of Archer Daniels Midland (ADM) alerted authorities of the existence of the cartel within the Lysine industry.
- Stainless steel: Buyers of the product complained to the European Commission (EC) about price spikes.
- Sodium gluconate: Defendants in the lysine case informed authorities of collusive behaviours between corporations in this industry.
Today, price fixing by private entities is illegal under the antitrust laws of more than 140 countries. The commodities of prosecuted international cartels include lysine, citric acid, graphite electrodes, and bulk vitamins.[26] In many countries, the predominant belief is that cartels are contrary to free and fair competition, considered the backbone of political democracy.[27] Maintaining cartels continues to become harder for cartels. Even if international cartels cannot be regulated as a whole by individual nations, their individual activities in domestic markets are affected.[28]
Unlike other cartels, export cartels are legal in virtually all jurisdictions, despite their harmful effects on affected markets.[29]
Examples
- Asian Racing Federation: The Asian Racing Federation formed a cartel, documented in the Good Neighbour Policy signed on September 1, 2003.
- British Valve Association
- De Beers
- Quinine cartel: international cartel
- Federation of Quebec Maple Syrup Producers: Canada's maple syrup cartel, which controls the pricing of maple syrup worldwide. Formed in 1966. Called "the OPEC of the maple syrup world" by The Economist[30]
- International Rail Makers Association
- OPEC: As its name suggests, OPEC is organised by sovereign states. Under traditional legal views, it cannot be held to antitrust enforcement in other jurisdictions under the doctrine of state immunity under public international law.[31]
- Phoebus cartel (1925–1955) for light bulbs
- Rhenish-Westphalian Coal Syndicate: Worldwide, the most famous and renowned cartel of its life span (1893–1945)[32]
- Seven Sisters (oil companies)
- Swiss Cheese Union: Many trade associations, especially in industries dominated by only a few major companies, have been accused of being fronts for cartels or facilitating secret meetings among cartel members. The now-defunct Swiss Cheese Union discouraged competition throughout the dairy industry in 20th century Switzerland.
- Standard Oil
- American Medical Association
- Trade unions: Although cartels are usually thought of as a group of corporations, the right-wing economist Charles W. Baird considers trade unions to be cartels because they seek to raise the price of labor (wages) by preventing competition. Negotiated cartelism is a labor arrangement in which labor prices are held above the market-clearing level through union leverage over employers.[33]
See also
Bibliography
- Connor, John M.: Private international cartels. Effectiveness, welfare, and anti-cartel enforcement. Purdue University. West Lafayette, Indiana 2003.
- Fear, Jeffrey R.: Cartels. In: Geoffrey Jones; Jonathan Zeitlin (ed.): The Oxford handbook of business history. Oxford: Univ. Press, 2007, p. 268–293.
- Freyer, Tony A.: Antitrust and global capitalism 1930–2004, New York 2006.
- Hexner, Ervin, The International Steel Cartel, Chapel Hill 1943.
- Kleinwächter, Friedrich, Die Kartelle. Ein Beitrag zur Frage der Organization der Volkswirtschaft, Innsbruck 1883.
- Leonhardt, Holm Arno: Kartelltheorie und Internationale Beziehungen. Theoriegeschichtliche Studien, Hildesheim 2013.
- Leonhardt, Holm Arno: The development of cartel+ theory between 1883 and the 1930s – from international diversity to convergence: syndicats industriels, ententes, comptoirs, trusts, pools, combinations, associations, kartells, cartelle, Unternehmerverbände. Hildesheim 2018. Einloggen | Hildesheimer Beiträge zu Theologie und Geschichte.
- Levenstein, Margaret C. and Valerie Y. Suslow. "What Determines Cartel Success?" Journal of Economic Literature 64 (March 2006): 43–95.
- Liefmann, Robert: Cartels, Concerns and Trusts, Ontario 2001 [London 1932]
- Martyniszyn, Marek, "Export Cartels: Is it Legal to Target Your Neighbour? Analysis in Light of Recent Case Law", Journal of International Economic Law 15 (1) (2012): 181–222.
- Stigler, George J.: The extent and bases of monopoly. In: The American economic review, Vol. 32 (1942), pp. 1–22.
- Stocking, George W. and Myron W. Watkins: Cartels in Action. New York: Twentieth Century Fund (1946).
- Stocking, George W. and Myron W. Watkins: Cartels or competition? The economics of international controls by business and government. New York: Twentieth Century Fund 1948.
- Strieder, Jakob: Studien zur Geschichte kapitalistischer Organizationsformen. Monopole, Kartelle und Aktiengesellschaften im Mittelalter und zu Beginn der Neuzeit. München 1925.
- Wells, Wyatt C.: Antitrust and the Formation of the Postwar World, New York 2002.
References
- ^ "Definition of CARTEL". www.merriam-webster.com. Retrieved 2019-11-29.
- ^ Hans-Heinrich Barnikel: Kartelle in Deutschland. In: Ders. (Hrsg.): Theorie und Praxis der Kartelle, Darmstadt 1972, S. 1.
- ^ Holm A. Leonhardt: Kartelltheorie und Internationale Beziehungen. Theoriegeschichtliche Studien, Hildesheim 2013, p. 79.
- ^ Nino Herlitzka: Bemerkungen zur historischen Entwicklung von Kartellen. In: Ludwig Kastl (Ed.): Kartelle in der Wirklichkeit. Köln 1963, p. 124–127.
- ^ Holm A. Leonhardt: Kartelltheorie und Internationale Beziehungen. Theoriegeschichtliche Studien, Hildesheim 2013, S. 80–87.
- ^ Holm A. Leonhardt: Kartelltheorie und Internationale Beziehungen. Theoriegeschichtliche Studien, Hildesheim 2013, S. 83–84.
- ^ Holm Arno Leonhardt: The development of cartel theory between 1883 and the 1930s. Hildesheim 2018. p. 18.
- ^ Holm A. Leonhardt: Kartelltheorie und Internationale Beziehungen. Theoriegeschichtliche Studien. Hildesheim 2013, p. 251–292.
- ^ Jeffrey, R. "Cartels, Concerns and Trusts". The Oxford handbook of business history. Ontario 2001: 269–274 – via Oxford Univ. Pres, 2007.
- ^ Fellman, Susanna; Shanahan, Martin (2015). Regulating Competition: Cartel registers in the twentieth-century world. London: Routledge. p. 224. ISBN 9781138021648.
- ^ John M. Connor and Dan Werner. Variation in Bid-Rigging Cartels' Overcharges: SSRN Working Paper No. 3273988. (October 27, 2018). [1].
- ^ John M. Connor. Cartel Overcharges, p. 249–387 of The Law and Economics of Class Actions, in Vol. 29 of Research in Law and Economics, edited by James Langenfeld (March 2014). Bingley, UK: Emerald House Publishing Ltd. June 2017
- ^ Levenstein, Margaret C.; Suslow, Valerie Y. (2006). "What determined cartel success?". Journal of Economic Literature. 44: 43–95 – via American Economic Association.
- ^ Levenstein, Margaret C. and Valerie Y. Suslow. "What Determines Cartel Success?" Journal of Economic Literature 64 (March 2006): 43–95
- ^ Connor, John M. Private International Cartels: A Concise Introduction: SSRN Working Paper. (November 12, 2014). Abstract.
- ^ Hannigan, John A. (1982). "Unfriendly Skies: The Decline of the World Aviation Cartel". The Pacific Sociological Review. 25 (1): 107–136. doi:10.2307/1388890. ISSN 0030-8919. JSTOR 1388890. S2CID 158297510.
- ^ Koffler, Warren (Spring 1966). "IATA: It's legal structure - A critical review". Journal of Air Law and Commerce. 32: 222–235 – via HeinOnline.
- ^ Faulkner, Robert R.; Cheney, Eric R.; Fisher, Gene A.; Baker, Wayne E. (2003). "Crime by Committee: Conspirators and Company Men in the Illegal Electrical Industry Cartel, 1954–1959". Criminology. 41 (2): 511–554. doi:10.1111/j.1745-9125.2003.tb00996.x. ISSN 1745-9125.
- ^ Genesove, David; Mullin, Wallace P (2001). "Rules, Communication, and Collusion: Narrative Evidence from the Sugar Institute Case" (PDF). American Economic Review. 91 (3): 379–398. doi:10.1257/aer.91.3.379. ISSN 0002-8282. S2CID 153786791.
- ^ Baker, Wayne E.; Faulkner, Robert R. (1993). "The Social Organization of Conspiracy: Illegal Networks in the Heavy Electrical Equipment Industry". American Sociological Review. 58 (6): 837. doi:10.2307/2095954. JSTOR 2095954.
- ^ Bertrand, Olivier; Lumineau, Fabrice (2016). "Partners in Crime: The Effects of Diversity on the Longevity of Cartels". Academy of Management Journal. 59 (3): 983–1008. doi:10.5465/amj.2013.1209. ISSN 0001-4273. S2CID 143383363.
- ^ Holm Arno Leonhardt: The development of cartel theory between 1883 and the 1930s. Hildesheim 2018.
- ^ Cini, Michelle; McGowan, Lee (2009). Competition Policy in the European Union. New York: Palgrave Macmillan. p. 63. ISBN 978-0-230-00675-1.
- ^ Lee, John (2016). Strategies to Achieve a Binding International Agreement on Regulating Cartels: Overcoming Doha Standstill. Berlin: Springer. p. 13. ISBN 978-981-10-2755-0.
- ^ Sullivan, E. Thomas (1991). The political economy of the Sherman Act: The first one hundred years. Oxford University Press. ISBN 9780195066425.
- ^ Connor, John M. (2008): Global Price Fixing: 2nd Paperback Edition. Heidelberg: Springer.
- ^ Sagafi-Nejad, Tagi; Moxon, Richard; Perlmutter, Howard (2017). Controlling International Technology Transfer: Issues, Perspectives, and Policy Implications. New York: Pergamon Press. p. 180. ISBN 978-0-08-027180-4.
- ^ Fellman & Shanahan, p. 224.
- ^ Martyniszyn, Marek (2012). "Export Cartels: Is it Legal to Target your Neighbour? Analysis in Light of Recent Case Law". Journal of International Economic Law. 15 (1): 181. doi:10.1093/jiel/jgs003. S2CID 153887704.
- ^ "Sticky fingers". September 19, 2013 – via The Economist.
- ^ Martyniszyn, Marek (2017). "Foreign State's Entanglement in Anticompetitive Conduct". World Competition. 40 (2): 299. SSRN 3116910.
- ^ Holm Arno Leonhardt: Regionalwirtschaftliche Organisationskunst. Vorschlag zur Ergänzung des NRW-Antrags zum UNESCO-Welterbe. In: Forum Geschichtskultur Ruhr 2013, issue 2, pp. 41–42.
- ^ Charles W. Baird. "Unions and Antitrust". Archived from the original on 2010-06-24.