Jump to content

Hyperinflation: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
mNo edit summary
Chimbwidz (talk | contribs)
Line 77: Line 77:
== Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation ==
== Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation ==


Hyperinflation currently has two components.
'''Hyperinflation has two components''' under the current Historical Cost Accounting paradigm: Cash Hyperinflation and Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation.


I.Cash hyperinflation is the economic process that results in the hyper destruction of the real value of hyper depreciating monetary items over time.


There are three distinct economic items in a hyperinflationary economy: 1. Hyper depreciating monetary items are hyper depreciating functional currency units held and accounted hyper depreciating monetary values only of the hyper depreciating functional currency.
'''I. CASH HYPERINFLATION'''


'''Cash hyperinflation''' is the economic process that results in the hyper destruction of the real value of hyper depreciating monetary items over time.
Non-monetary items are all items that are not hyper depreciating monetary items.


2. Variable real value non-monetary items include items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value.
There are '''three distinct economic items''' in a hyperinflationary economy:


Under real value accounting accounting variable real value non-monetary items are valued in terms of International Accounting Standards and International Financial Reporting Standards as issued by the International Accounting Standards Board with the exception of the stable measuring unit assumption, the whole of International Accounting Standard IAS 29: Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies and the definition of monetary items in IAS 21 The Effects of Changes in Foreign Exchange Rates.
:'''1. Hyper depreciating monetary items'''

:'''2. Variable real value non-monetary items'''

:'''3. Constant real value non-monetary items.'''

''' ''1. Hyper depreciating Monetary Items'' '''

Hyper depreciating monetary items are hyper depreciating functional currency units held and accounted hyper depreciating monetary values only of the hyper depreciating functional currency.

'''Non-monetary items''' are all items that are not hyper depreciating monetary items. Non-monetary items are subdivided into two classes: variable real value non-monetary items and constant real value non-monetary items.

''' ''2. Variable real value non-monetary items.'' '''

'''Variable real value non-monetary items''' include items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value.

Under Real Value Accounting variable real value non-monetary items are valued in terms of International Accounting Standards and International Financial Reporting Standards as issued by the International Accounting Standards Board with the exception of the stable measuring unit assumption, the whole of International Accounting Standard IAS 29: Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies and the definition of monetary items in IAS 21 The Effects of Changes in Foreign Exchange Rates.


Examples of variable real value non-monetary items are property, plant, equipment, land, buildings, raw material, work-in-progress, finished goods, stock, marketable securities, foreign currency and vehicles.
Examples of variable real value non-monetary items are property, plant, equipment, land, buildings, raw material, work-in-progress, finished goods, stock, marketable securities, foreign currency and vehicles.


Examples of hyper depreciating money held are hyper depreciating bank notes. Examples of hyper depreciating monetary values are hyper depreciating bank account balances, hyperdepreciating money loans owed or made, hyper depreciating notes payable and hyperde preciating notes receivable. Hyper depreciating monetary items have fixed nominal values but hyper depreciating real values as their hyper depreciating real values are very rapidly being destroyed by cash hyperinflation.
The '''hyper depreciating functional currency''' is the hyper depreciating monetary unit of account of the principle hyperinflationary economic environment in which an economic entity operates.

The hyper depreciating functional currency is hyper depreciating money in a hyperinflationary national economy. An item can only be hyper depreciating money when it fulfills all '''three functions of hyper depreciating money''' in a hyperinflationary national economy:

'''a.) Hyper depreciating medium of exchange'''

Hyper depreciating '''money’s basic function''' is that it is a hyper depreciating medium of exchange of equivalent real economic values at the moment of exchange. Without this function or attribute the invention cannot be hyper depreciating money. This attribute makes the invention hyper depreciating money.

Hyper depreciating currencies are normally not internationally traded and sometimes not even regionally. This happens because a hyper depreciating currency loses real value on a daily basis at a sometimes astonishing rate and it is very difficult to have access to the correct daily rate with the result that foreign banks in foreign capitals refuse to accept hyper depreciating currencies and thus there are no foreign exchange facilities made available for hyper depreciating currencies. Governments of countries with chronically hyper destroyed currencies sometimes prohibit people from taking the local hyper depreciating currency out of the country.

In a cash hyperinflationary economy hyper depreciating money is almost exclusively used only as a hyper depreciating medium of exchange since it has almost no store of value function and its combination with the Historical Cost Accounting model makes it completely useless as a unit of account for accounting economic activity

'''b.) Hyper depreciating store of value'''

Hyper depreciating money’s second function is that it is a store of hyper depreciating real value. Although the store of value function and nominal values of hyper depreciating bank notes are legally defined, their hyper depreciating real values are determined by the economic process of cash hyperinflation.

Cash hyperinflation actually manifests itself in the hyper depreciating store of value function of hyper depreciating money. Hyper depreciating money has a constantly hyper decreasing real value.

In a low cash inflationary economy depreciating money is a store of decreasing real value but accountants apply the stable measuring unit assumption only as far as the valuation of constant real value non-monetry items are concerned. They assume that the functional currency unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its real value are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the nominal values of constant real value non-monetary items in the basic financial statements. This assumption is now totally unacceptable. It always was and now still is fundamentally wrong and incredibly costly to the world economy.

In cash hyperinflationary economies the above `stable´ money assumption prevalent in low cash inflation economies does not manifest itself in actual economic transactions where
a hyper depreciating monetary unit is used. The fact that hyper depreciating money loses real value continuously is the basis of transaction monetary practices in cash hyperinflationary economies. In a cash hyperinflationary economy local currency free market prices are continuously updated in the parallel market in terms of a relatively stable foreign currency, normally the parallel or black market or street rate for the US Dollar. In hyperinflationary economies there are normally two exchange rate for the US Dollar. The official rate that is not often changed by the monetary authorities and the parallel rate that changes daily or sometimes twice a day. For example the offial rate for the Zimbabwean Dollar is 250 ZimDollars for 1 US Dollar while the parallel rate can be up to 250 000 ZimDollars for 1 US Dollar.

'''Money illusion''' still prevails as far as the “stable” foreign currency is concerned. In this way the `stable´ money assumption is applied only to the real value of the foreign currency while the hyper decrease in the real value of the local currency is fully adjusted for on a daily basis by the continuous updating of parallel market prices only, but, all other nominal prices of constant real value non-monetary items are left intact with the result that Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation hyper destroys the real value of these constant real value nonmonetary items not fully or never updated on a devastating scale.

'''The assumption that money is stable''' – as in fixed - in real value is thus still applied in the accounting of economic activity in cash hyperinflationary economies because of the continued mistaken use of the Historical Cost Accounting model as the traditional accounting model to account all economic transactions. The result is that Historical Cost Accounting financial statement based on a hyper depreciating monetary unit are completely meaningless. Using the
Historical Cost Accounting model to prepare operating results or any financial reports in a cash hyperinflationary economy is a complete mistake. These results are completely useless and
meaningless. They are a complete fantasy. The use of the Historical Cost Accounting model should be specifically banned by law in all cash hyperinflationary economies.

Not only is the use of the Historical Cost Accounting model in a cash hyperinflationary economy completely misleading and useless, it also caused and is now actually causing the hyper
destruction of massive amounts of real economic value in constant real value non-monetary items not fully or never updated in the cash hyperinflationary economy of Zimbabwe. In the case of Zimbabwe the combination of the stable measuring unit assumption and the Historical Cost Accounting model is currently destroying the Zimbabwean economy.

'''c.) Hyper depreciating unit of account'''

Originally a medium of exchange was needed to facilitate the exchange of economic items in barter economies. Money was invented over time to be used as the medium of exchange. Money consisted of precious metal coins and thus automatically had a store of value function too. Hyper depreciating money always consists of hyper depreciating units of value and thus serves as a hyper depreciating unit of measure in an hyperinflationary economy. These hyper depreciating measured values are recorded and accounted via the use of a fundamental model of accounting. Historical Cost Accounting is still used as the generally accepted fundamental model of accounting in the world economy today.

In a cash hyperinflationary economy hyper depreciating money is used as a hyper depreciating unit of account to record all economic activity. It is very tempting to state that it is very clear that you cannot have a unit of account that is not stable – as in fixed - in real value for accounting purposes. However, we have been doing exactly that for the last 700 years.

Hyper depreciating money’s third function is therefore that it is used as the hyper depreciating unit of account to record real economic activity in cash hyperinflationary economies. How anyone can have a unit of account that is not a constant real value is very difficult to explain to anyone who is introduced to the idea of a unit of account for the first time. This is a direct result of the longstanding stable measuring unit assumption by which we mistakenly assume that changes in money’s general purchasing power are not sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial reports.

Cash hyperinflation is the real problem with hyper depreciating money since real value is the most fundamental economic concept in any economy under any economic model including the Historical Cost Accounting model and not money as is generally accepted under the mistaken belief that money is equal to constant real value. The combination of the use of Historical Cost Accounting as the fundamental model of accounting with cash hyperinflation elevates money’s function as hyper depreciating unit of account to one of critical importance.



'''Foreign exchange''' is not money in a hyperinflationary national economy since it is not the hyperinflationary unit of account. Foreign exchange is a variable real value non-monetary item valued at market value in foreign exchange markets.

'''The essential feature''' of a hyper depreciating monetary item is that it is a hyper depreciating functional currency unit or a hyper depreciating functional currency value that only pertains to the hyper depreciating functional currency. Actual hyper depreciating monetary units cannot be updated and actual hyper depreciating accounted monetary values are not updated in current financial accounts and statements.

'''Hyper depreciating monetary values''' have the exact same attributes as hyper depreciating money held with the single exception that they are hyper depreciating accounted monetary values and not actual hyper depreciating bank notes. A hyper depreciating monetary item never has a microeconomic non-monetary base during its entire hyperinflationary economic life in our modern hyperinflatinary economies where our hyper depreciating functional currencies have no intrinsic value. A hyper depreciating monetary item cannot be the hyper depreciating accounted value of a hyper depreciating non-monetary item in any way or form in an hyperinflationary economy with fiat money.

Hyper depreciating money’s real value is continuously being destroyed by cash hyperinflation in a cash hyperinflationary economy. Cash hyperinflation cannot be stopped by a change in the accounting model, for example, from the Historical Cost Accounting model to the Real Vale Accounting model. Real Value Accounting only stops Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation in all hyper depreciating non-monetary items.

The real value of a non monetary item treated incorrectly like a hyper depreciating monetary item under the Historical Cost Accounting model, on the other hand, is being destroyed, not by cash hyperinflation, but by Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation which can be stopped at any time by adopting the Real Value Accounting model.

'''Examples''' of hyper depreciating money held are hyper depreciating bank notes.

'''Examples''' of hyper depreciating monetary values are hyper depreciating bank account balances, hyperdepreciating money loans owed or made, hyper depreciating notes payable and hyperde preciating notes receivable. Hyper depreciating monetary items have fixed nominal values but hyper depreciating real values as their hyper depreciating real values are very rapidly being destroyed by cash hyperinflation.´

Starting in 1992 and lasting 24 months, what was left of '''Yugoslavia''' endured the second-highest and second-longest hyperinflation in world history, peaking in January 1994 when prices increased by 313,000,000% in one month. In all, there were 14 maxi-devaluations during the hyperinflation, with each of the final three exceeding 99.9%, completely wiping out the dinar's value in November '93, December '93 and January '94.


Cash hyperinflation can be reduced by reducing the rate of hyperinflation through sound monetary, economic, political, social and other policies. This will reduce the rate of hyper destruction in the real value of hyper depreciating money.
Cash hyperinflation can be reduced by reducing the rate of hyperinflation through sound monetary, economic, political, social and other policies. This will reduce the rate of hyper destruction in the real value of hyper depreciating money.


II.Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation is the Historical Cost Accounting practice whereby accountants in hyperinflationary economies hyperdestroy the real value of non-monetary items not fully or never hyperupdated over time in their respective companies or the public sector due to the use of the Historical Cost Accounting model or any other accounting model which does not allow the continuous hyperupdating of non-monetary items at the current (daily) parallel rate or in terms of a current (daily) non-monetary real value unit in an economy subject to cash hyperinflation in the absence of the implementation of IAS 29. Implementing IAS 29 does not stop the massive economy destroying results of Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation as very well proven in the case of Zimbabwe. Revoking the stable measuring unit assumption and implementing real value accounting or a Brazilian style [[Unidade Real de Valor]] will stop Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation and stabilise the economy.


3. Constant real value non-monetary items are economic items with constant real values as a result of the double entry accounting model introduced in about the year 1300 in Venice, Italy.
'''II. HISTORICAL COST ACCOUNTING HYPERINFLATION'''

'''Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation''' is the Historical Cost Accounting practice whereby accountants in hyperinflationary economies hyperdestroy the real value of non-monetary items not fully or never hyperupdated over time in their respective companies or the public sector due to the use of the Historical Cost Accounting model or any other accounting model which does not allow the continuous hyperupdating of non-monetary items at the current (daily) '''parallel rate''' or in terms of a current (daily) non-monetary Real Value Unit in an economy subject to cash hyperinflation in the absence of the implementation of IAS 29. Implementing IAS 29 does not stop the massive economy destroying results of Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation as very well proven in the case of Zimbabwe. '''Revoking the stable measuring unit assumption''' and implementing '''Real Value Accounting''' or a Brazilian style [[Unidade Real de Valor]] will stop Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation and stabilise the economy.

Currently (July 2007) this is happening on a massive scale in Zimbabwe where the economy is being completely destroyed by the combination of cash hyperinflation and the application of the stable measuring unit assumption as part of the Historical Cost Accounting model by Zimbabwean acccountants. The introduction of Real Value Accounting or the proven and very successful Brazilian style [[Unidade Real de Valor]] would stabilise the Zimbabwean economy.

''' ''3. Constant real value non-monetary items.'' '''

'''Constant real value non-monetary items''' are economic items with constant real values as a result of the double entry accounting model introduced in about the year 1300 in Venice, Italy.

Since hyper depreciating money is hyper depreciating legal tender in a hyperinflationary national economy, all economic items, including constant real value non-monetary items, are accounted using hyper depreciating money as the hyper depreciating monetary unit of account. Unfortunately cash hyperinflation continuously destroys the real value of hyper depreciating money over time.

'''Under Real Value Accounting''' constant real value non-monetary items in hyperinflationary economies are updated at the parallel exchange rate or in terms of a Real Value Unit similar to the Unidade de Valor Real used during the last hyperinflationary period in Brazil, always at the current, that is, the daily rate at the date of the transaction or payment or the date of presentation (not preparation unless prepared and presented on the same day) of financial results.


Since hyper depreciating money is hyper depreciating legal tender in a hyperinflationary national economy, all economic items, including constant real value non-monetary items, are accounted using hyper depreciating money as the hyper depreciating monetary unit of account. Unfortunately cash hyperinflation continuously destroys the real value of hyper depreciating money over time. Under real value accounting constant real value non-monetary items in hyperinflationary economies are updated at the parallel exchange rate or in terms of a real value unit similar to the Unidade de Valor Real used during the last hyperinflationary period in Brazil, always at the current, that is, the daily rate at the date of the transaction or payment or the date of presentation (not preparation unless prepared and presented on the same day) of financial results.
'''Financial results''' are prepared in terms of the parallel rate on the balance sheet date. All the values in these financial statements are then updated at the current parallel rate every time the statements are accessed or presented afterwards. Computerised updating and presentation is the best form of implementation.


Financial results are prepared in terms of the parallel rate on the balance sheet date. All the values in these financial statements are then updated at the current parallel rate every time the statements are accessed or presented afterwards. Computerised updating and presentation is the best form of implementation.
'''Constant real value non-monetary items include''', for example: issued share capital, retained income, provisions, reserves, share premiums, retained losses, net monetary loss, net monetary gain, all items in shareholders equity, '''trade debtors, trade creditors''', other debtors, other creditors, salaries, wages, fees, royalties, rent, interest paid in the Profit and Loss Account, interest received in the Profit and Loss Account, dividends, taxes, VAT, all Profit and Loss Account income/sales/revenue and all Profit and Loss Account costs and expenses, salaries payable, wages payable, rent payable, fees payable, royalties payable, interest payable, interest receivable, dividends payable, taxes payable, VAT payable, contstant real value non-monetary items stated at cost, salaries receivable, wages receivable, rent receivable, fees receivable, royalties receivable, dividends receivable taxes receivable, VAT receivable.


Constant real value non-monetary items include, for example: issued share capital, retained income, provisions, reserves, share premiums, retained losses, net monetary loss, net monetary gain, all items in shareholders equity, trade debtors, trade creditors, other debtors, other creditors, salaries, wages, fees, royalties, rent, interest paid in the Profit and Loss Account, interest received in the Profit and Loss Account, dividends, taxes, VAT, all Profit and Loss Account income/sales/revenue and all Profit and Loss Account costs and expenses, salaries payable, wages payable, rent payable, fees payable, royalties payable, interest payable, interest receivable, dividends payable, taxes payable, VAT payable, contstant real value non-monetary items stated at cost, salaries receivable, wages receivable, rent receivable, fees receivable, royalties receivable, dividends receivable taxes receivable, VAT receivable.
In most countries, '''primary financial statements''' are prepared on the Historical Cost basis of accounting without regard either to changes in the general level of prices or to increases in specific prices of assets held, except to the extent that property, plant and equipment and investments may be revalued.


In most countries, primary financial statements are prepared on the Historical Cost basis of accounting without regard either to changes in the general level of prices or to increases in specific prices of assets held, except to the extent that property, plant and equipment and investments may be revalued.
'''The International Accounting Standards Board''' only identifies two instead of the three distinct economic items, namely, monetary and non-monetary items. The difference between variable and constant real value non-monetary items is ignored by the IASB as a result of the implementation of the stable measuring unit assumption - the cornerstone of the Historical Cost Accounting model - whereby it is accepted in low cash inflationary economies that the functional currency's internal real value is constantly being destroyed by cash inflation - but, this destruction of real value is regarded as of not sufficient importance to adjust the real values of constant real value non-monetary items in the financial statements. They are valued at Historical Cost which results in the destruction of their real values at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation year after year when they are not fully or never updated.


The International Accounting Standards Board only identifies two instead of the three distinct economic items, namely, monetary and non-monetary items. The difference between variable and constant real value non-monetary items is ignored by the IASB as a result of the implementation of the stable measuring unit assumption - the cornerstone of the Historical Cost Accounting model - whereby it is accepted in low cash inflationary economies that the functional currency's internal real value is constantly being destroyed by cash inflation - but, this destruction of real value is regarded as of not sufficient importance to adjust the real values of constant real value non-monetary items in the financial statements. They are valued at Historical Cost which results in the destruction of their real values at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation year after year when they are not fully or never updated.
'''The IASB´s definition of non-monetary items''' include variable real value non-monetary items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value.


They also include Historical Cost items based on '''the stable measuring unit assumption'''.
The IASB´s definition of non-monetary items include variable real value non-monetary items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value. They also include Historical Cost items based on the stable measuring unit assumption.


One of the basic principles in accounting is the '''Measuring Unit principle''': The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency.
One of the basic principles in accounting is the Measuring Unit principle: The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency.


This principle also '''assumes the unit of measure is stable'''; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements.
This principle also assumes the unit of measure is stable'''; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements.


Valuing these items at Historical Cost results in their real values being destroyed at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation every single year when they are not fully or never updated, exactly the same as in monetary items or cash.
Valuing these items at Historical Cost results in their real values being destroyed at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation every single year when they are not fully or never updated, exactly the same as in monetary items or cash.

Revision as of 12:28, 7 July 2007

Certain figures in this article use scientific notation for readability.

In economics, hyperinflation is inflation that is "out of control," a condition in which prices increase rapidly as a currency loses its value. No precise definition of hyperinflation is universally accepted. One simple definition requires a monthly inflation rate of 20 or 30% or more. In informal usage the term is often applied to much lower rates.

The definition used by most economists is "an inflationary cycle without any tendency toward equilibrium." A vicious circle is created in which more and more inflation is created with each iteration of the cycle. Although there is a great deal of debate about the root causes of hyperinflation, it becomes visible when there is an unchecked increase in the money supply or drastic debasement of coinage, and is often associated with wars (or their aftermath), economic depressions, and political or social upheavals.

Hyperinflation has two components under the current Historical Cost Accounting paradigm: Cash Hyperinflation and Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation.

Characteristics

File:Inflation-1923.jpg
Inflation 1923-24: A German woman feeding a stove with currency notes, which burn longer than the amount of firewood they can buy.

In 1956, Phillip Cagan wrote "Monetary Dynamics of Hyperinflation", generally regarded as the first serious study of hyperinflation and its effects. In it he defined hyperinflation as a monthly inflation rate of at least 50% (prices doubling every 51 days).

International Accounting Standard 29 describes four signs that an economy may be in hyperinflation:

  1. The general population prefers to keep its wealth in non-monetary assets or in a relatively stable foreign currency. Amounts of local currency held are immediately invested to maintain purchasing power.
  2. The general population regards monetary amounts not in terms of the local currency but in terms of a relatively stable foreign currency. Prices may be quoted in that currency.
  3. Sales and purchases on credit take place at prices that compensate for the expected loss of purchasing power during the credit period, even if the period is short.
  4. Interest rates, wages and prices are linked to a price index and the cumulative inflation rate over three years approaches, or exceeds, 100%.

Rates of inflation of several hundred percent per month are often seen. Extreme examples include Germany in the early 1920s when the rate of inflation hit 3.25 × 106 percent per month (prices double every 49 hours) and Greece during its occupation by German troops (1941-1944) with 8.55 × 109 percent per month (prices double every 28 hours). The most severe known incident of inflation was in Hungary after the end of World War II at 4.19 × 1016 percent per month (prices double every 15 hours). More recently, Yugoslavia suffered 5 × 1015 percent inflation per month (prices double every 16 hours) between 1 October 1993 and 24 January 1994. Other more moderate examples include other Eastern European countries such as Ukraine in the period of economic transition in the early 1990s, in Latin American countries such as Bolivia and Peru in 1985 and 1988-1990, in Mexico from 1982 to 1988, in Argentina in 1989, in Brazil in the early 1990s, and in the African nation of Zimbabwe in 2006 and early 2007.

Root causes of hyperinflation

The main cause of hyperinflation is a massive imbalance between the supply and demand of a certain currency or type of money, usually due to a complete loss of confidence in the currency similar to a bank-run. This has most often occurred because of excessive money printing, although other factors may have a reinforcing effect. Often the body responsible for printing the currency cannot physically print paper currency faster than the rate at which it is devaluing, thus neutralising their attempts to stimulate the economy.

Hyperinflation is generally associated with paper money because the means to increasing the money supply with paper money is the simplest: add more zeroes to the plates and print, or even stamp old notes with new numbers. It also is the most dramatic so far with electronic money now posing the possibility of even faster "printing" and de-regulated capital markets allowing currency to "go global". There have been numerous episodes of hyperinflation, followed by a return to "hard money". Older economies would revert to hard currency and barter when the circulating medium became excessively devalued, generally following a "run" on the store of value.

Unlike inflation, which is widely considered to be normal in a healthy economy, hyperinflation is always regarded as destructive. It effectively wipes out the purchasing power of private and public savings, distorts the economy in favor of extreme consumption and hoarding of real assets, causes the monetary base whether specie or hard currency to flee the country, and makes the afflicted area anathema to investment. Hyperinflation is met with drastic remedies, whether by imposing a shock therapy of slashing government expenditures or by altering the currency basis. An example of the latter is placing the nation in question under a currency board as Bosnia-Herzegovina had in 2005, which allows the central bank to print only as much money as it has in foreign reserves. Another example is dollarization as Ecuador officially initiated in September 2000 in response to a massive 75% loss of value of the Sucre currency in early January 2000. Dollarization is the use of a foreign currency (not necessarily the U.S. dollar) as a national unit of currency.

The aftermath of hyperinflation is equally complex. As hyperinflation has always been a traumatic experience for the area which suffers it, the next policy regime almost always enacts policies to prevent its recurrence. Often this means making the central bank very aggressive about maintaining price stability as is the case with the German Bundesbank, or moving to some hard basis of currency such as a currency board. Many governments have enacted extremely stiff wage and price controls in the wake of hyperinflation, which is, in effect, a form of forced savings: goods become unavailable, and hence people hoard cash, as was the case in the People's Republic of China under "Great Leap Forward" and "Cultural Revolution".

A 500,000,000,000 (500 billion) Yugoslav dinar banknote circa 1993, the largest nominal value ever officially printed in Yugoslavia, the final result of hyperinflation. Photo courtesy of National Bank of Serbia (www.nbs.yu)

For a variety of reasons, governments have occasionally resorted to printing money to meet their expenses. During hyperinflation, the monetary authority can't even do that as it becomes a net loss. Those holding government debt, directly or indirectly, have less buying power. Theories of hyperinflation generally look for a relationship between seignorage and the inflation tax. In both Cagan's model and the neo-classical models, a crucial point is when the increase in money supply or the drop in basic money stock makes it impossible for a government to improve its financial position. That is, when fiat money is printed government obligations that are not denominated in money increase in cost by more than the value of the money created.

From this, it might be wondered why any state would engage in actions that cause or continue hyperinflation. One reason is that often the alternative to hyperinflation is depression. In late 2001, the Argentine peso collapsed in value. Rather than printing sufficient cash for the public to carry, which they feared would start a run on the banks, the government took the peso off its dollar peg. Many international economists predicted that they would have to get a new loan from the IMF and impose shock therapy in order to avoid hyperinflation. Currency controls were imposed, tariffs were instituted, and the economy was allowed to fall into a severe recession during which unemployment hit 25%, homelessness and crime spiraled upwards, and the poverty rate peaked at over 50%.

The root cause is a matter of more dispute. In both classical economics and monetarism, it is always the result of the monetary authority irresponsibly borrowing money to pay all its expenses. These models focus on the unrestrained seignorage of the monetary authority, and the gains from the inflation tax. In Neoliberalism, hyperinflation is considered to be the result of a crisis of confidence. The monetary base of the country flees, producing widespread fear that individuals will not be able to convert local currency to some more transportable form, such as gold or an internationally recognized hard currency. This is a quantity theory of hyper-inflation.

In neo-classical economic theory, hyperinflation is rooted in a deterioration of the monetary base, that is the confidence that there is a store of value which the currency will be able to command later. In this model, the perceived risk of holding currency rises dramatically, and sellers demand increasingly high premiums to accept the currency. This in turn leads to a greater fear that the currency will collapse, causing even higher premiums. One example of this is during periods of warfare, civil war, or intense internal conflict of other kinds: governments need to do whatever is necessary to continue fighting, since the alternative is defeat. Expenses cannot be cut significantly since the main outlay is armaments. Further, a civil war may make it difficult to raise taxes or to collect existing taxes. While in peacetime the deficit is financed by selling bonds, during a war it is typically difficult and expensive to borrow, especially if the war is going poorly for the government in question. The banking authorities, whether central or not, "monetize" the deficit, printing money to pay for the government's efforts to survive. The hyperinflation under the Chinese Nationalists from 1939-1945 is a classic example of a government printing money to pay civil war costs. By the end, currency was flown in over the Himalaya, and then old currency was flown out to be destroyed.

Hyperinflation is regarded as a complex phenomenon and one explanation may not be applicable to all cases. However, in both of these models, whether loss of confidence comes first, or central bank seignorage, the other phase is ignited. In the case of rapid expansion of the money supply, prices rise rapidly in response to the increased demand beyond the ability of the economy to supply it, and in the case of loss of confidence, the monetary authority responds to the risk premiums it has to pay by "running the printing presses".

In the United States, hyperinflation was seen during the Revolutionary War and during the Civil War, especially on the Confederate side. Many other cases of extreme social conflict encouraging hyperinflation can be seen, as in Germany after World War I, Hungary at the end of World War II and in Yugoslavia in late 1980s just before break up of the country.

Less commonly, hyperinflation may occur when there is debasement of the coinage — wherein coins are consistently shaved of some of their silver and gold, increasing the circulating medium and reducing the value of the currency. The "shaved" specie is then often restruck into coins with lower weight of gold or silver. Historical examples include Ancient Rome and China during the Song Dynasty. When "token" coins begin circulating, it is possible for the minting authority to engage in fiat creation of currency.

Hyperinflation can also occur in the absence of a central bank. One case is when there is "free banking" but banks are allowed suspend convertibility, often in violation of explicit or implicit promises and contracts. These episodes often cause a panicked run on banks and a collapse in the money supply, leading to a depression and deflation.

The 1920s German inflation

A 1000 Mark banknote, over-stamped in red with 1,000,000,000 (1 billion) mark, issued in Germany during the hyperinflation of 1923

The hyperinflation episode in the Weimar Republic in the 1920s was not the first hyperinflation, nor was it the only one in early 1920s Europe. However, as the most prominent case following the emergence of economics as a science, it drew interest in a way that previous instances had not. Many of the surreal economic behaviors now associated with hyperinflation were first documented systematically in Germany: order-of-magnitude increases in prices and interest rates, redenomination of the currency, consumer flight from cash to hard assets, and the rapid expansion of industries that produced those assets.

It is sometimes argued that Germany had to inflate its currency to pay the war reparations required under the Treaty of Versailles, but this is only part of the story. Reparations accounted for about one third of the German deficit from 1920 to 1923 (Costantino Bresciani-Turroni, The Economics of Inflation. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1937. p. 93). Nonetheless, the government found reparations a convenient scapegoat. Other scapegoats included bankers and speculators (particularly foreign). The inflation reached its peak by November 1923, but ended when a new currency (the Rentenmark) was introduced. The government stated this new currency had a fixed value, and this was accepted.

Hyperinflation did not directly bring about the Nazi takeover of Germany; the inflation ended with the introduction of the Rentenmark and the Weimar Republic continued for a decade afterward. The inflation did, however, raise doubts about the competence of liberal institutions, especially amongst a middle class who had held cash savings and bonds. It also produced resentment of Germany's bankers and speculators, many of them Jewish, whom the government and press blamed for the inflation.

Models of hyperinflation

File:Millionlira.jpg
A 1,000,000 (1 Million) Lira banknote, issued by Turkey. The Lira was replaced by the New Turkish Lira in 2005, at 1 million old Lira = 1 New Lira
File:500kcruzeiros.jpg
A 500,000 Cruzeiro banknote, issued by Brazil in 1993. If exchanged, would be worth R$ 0.20 in 1994. Every few years the currency was renamed, and three zeros dropped from the bank notes. A 1960s Cruzeiro is now worth less than one trillionth of a US cent, after adjusting for multiple devaluations and note changes.
A 100,000 Ukrainian karbovanets (used between 1992 and 1996). In 1996, it was taken out of circulation, and was replaced by the Hryvnya at an exchange rate of 100,000 karbovanzi = 1 Hryvnya (approx. USD 0.20 at the time). This translates to an average inflation rate of approximately 1400% per month during between 1992 and 1996

Since hyperinflation is visible as a monetary effect, models of hyperinflation center on the demand for money. Economists see both a rapid increase in the money supply and an increase in the velocity of money. Either one or both of these encourage inflation and hyperinflation. A dramatic increase in the velocity of money as the cause of hyperinflation is central to the "crisis of confidence" model of hyperinflation, where the risk premium that sellers demand for the paper currency over the nominal value grows rapidly. The second theory is that there is first a radical increase in the amount of circulating medium, which can be called the "monetary model" of hyperinflation. In either model, the second effect then follows from the first — either too little confidence forcing an increase in the money supply, or too much money destroying confidence.

In the confidence model, some event, or series of events, such as defeats in battle, or a run on stocks of the specie which back a currency, removes the belief that the authority issuing the money will remain solvent — whether a bank or a government. Because people do not want to hold notes which may become valueless, they want to spend them in preference to holding notes which will lose value. Sellers, realizing that there is a higher risk for the currency, demand a greater and greater premium over the original value. Under this model, the method of ending hyperinflation is to change the backing of the currency — often by issuing a completely new one. War is one commonly cited cause of crisis of confidence, particularly losing in a war, as occurred during Napoleonic Vienna, and capital flight, sometimes because of "contagion" is another. In this view, the increase in the circulating medium is the result of the government attempting to buy time without coming to terms with the root cause of the lack of confidence itself.

In the monetary model, hyperinflation is a positive feedback cycle of rapid monetary expansion. It has the same cause as all other inflation: money-issuing bodies, central or otherwise, produce currency to pay spiralling costs, often from lax fiscal policy, or the mounting costs of warfare. When businesspeople perceive that the issuer is committed to a policy of rapid currency expansion, they mark up prices to cover the expected decay in the currency's value. The issuer must then accelerate its expansion to cover these prices, which pushes the currency value down even faster than before. According to this model the issuer cannot "win" and the only solution is to abruptly stop expanding the currency. Unfortunately, the end of expansion can cause a severe financial shock to those using the currency as expectations are suddenly adjusted. This policy, combined with reductions of pensions, wages, and government outlays, formed part of the Washington consensus of the 1990s.

Whatever the cause, hyperinflation involves both the supply and velocity of money. Which comes first is a matter of debate, and there may be no universal story that applies to all cases. But once the hyperinflation is established, the pattern of increasing the money stock, by which ever agencies are allowed to do so, is universal. Because this practice increases the supply of currency without any matching increase in demand for it, the price of the currency, that is the exchange rate, naturally falls relative to other currencies. Inflation becomes hyperinflation when the increase in money supply turns specific areas of pricing power into a general frenzy of spending quickly before money becomes worthless. The purchasing power of the currency drops so rapidly that holding cash for even a day is an unacceptable loss of purchasing power. As a result, no one holds currency, which increases the velocity of money, and worsens the crisis.

That is, rapidly rising prices undermine money's role as a store of value, so that people try to spend it on real goods or services as quickly as possible. Thus, the monetary model predicts that the velocity of money will rise endogenously as a result of the excessive increase in the money supply. At the point where ordinary purchases are affected by inflation pressures, hyperinflation is out of control, in the sense that ordinary policy mechanisms, such as increasing reserve requirements, raising interest rates or cutting government spending will all be responded to by shifting away from the rapidly dwindling currency and towards other means of exchange.

During a period of hyperinflation, bank runs, loans for 24 hour periods, switching to alternate currencies, the return to use of gold or silver or even barter becomes common. Many of the people who hoard gold today expect hyperinflation, and are hedging against it by holding specie. There is, also, extensive capital flight or flight to a "hard" currency such as the U.S. dollar. These are sometimes met with capital controls, an idea which has swung from standard, to anathema, and back into semi-respectability. All of this constitutes an economy which is operating in an "abnormal" way, which may lead to decreases in real production. If so, that intensifies the hyperinflation, since it means that the amount of goods in "too much money chasing too few goods" formulation is also reduced. This is also part of the vicious circle of hyperinflation.

Once the vicious circle of hyperinflation has been ignited, dramatic policy means are almost always required, simply raising interest rates is insufficient. Bolivia, for example, underwent a period of hyperinflation in 1985, where prices increased 12,000% in the space of less than a year. The government raised the price of gasoline, which it had been selling at a huge loss to quiet popular discontent, and the hyperinflation came to a halt almost immediately, since it was able to bring in hard currency by selling its oil abroad. The crisis of confidence ended, and people returned deposits to banks. The German hyperinflation of the 1920s was ended by producing a currency based on assets loaned against by banks, called the Rentenmark. Hyperinflation often ends when a civil conflict ends with one side winning. Though sometimes used, wage and price controls to control or prevent inflation, no episode of hyperinflation has been ended by the use of price controls alone, though they have sometimes been part of the mix of policies used to halt hyperinflation.

Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation

Hyperinflation currently has two components.

I.Cash hyperinflation is the economic process that results in the hyper destruction of the real value of hyper depreciating monetary items over time.

There are three distinct economic items in a hyperinflationary economy: 1. Hyper depreciating monetary items are hyper depreciating functional currency units held and accounted hyper depreciating monetary values only of the hyper depreciating functional currency.

Non-monetary items are all items that are not hyper depreciating monetary items.

2. Variable real value non-monetary items include items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value.

Under real value accounting accounting variable real value non-monetary items are valued in terms of International Accounting Standards and International Financial Reporting Standards as issued by the International Accounting Standards Board with the exception of the stable measuring unit assumption, the whole of International Accounting Standard IAS 29: Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies and the definition of monetary items in IAS 21 The Effects of Changes in Foreign Exchange Rates.

Examples of variable real value non-monetary items are property, plant, equipment, land, buildings, raw material, work-in-progress, finished goods, stock, marketable securities, foreign currency and vehicles.

Examples of hyper depreciating money held are hyper depreciating bank notes. Examples of hyper depreciating monetary values are hyper depreciating bank account balances, hyperdepreciating money loans owed or made, hyper depreciating notes payable and hyperde preciating notes receivable. Hyper depreciating monetary items have fixed nominal values but hyper depreciating real values as their hyper depreciating real values are very rapidly being destroyed by cash hyperinflation.

Cash hyperinflation can be reduced by reducing the rate of hyperinflation through sound monetary, economic, political, social and other policies. This will reduce the rate of hyper destruction in the real value of hyper depreciating money.

II.Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation is the Historical Cost Accounting practice whereby accountants in hyperinflationary economies hyperdestroy the real value of non-monetary items not fully or never hyperupdated over time in their respective companies or the public sector due to the use of the Historical Cost Accounting model or any other accounting model which does not allow the continuous hyperupdating of non-monetary items at the current (daily) parallel rate or in terms of a current (daily) non-monetary real value unit in an economy subject to cash hyperinflation in the absence of the implementation of IAS 29. Implementing IAS 29 does not stop the massive economy destroying results of Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation as very well proven in the case of Zimbabwe. Revoking the stable measuring unit assumption and implementing real value accounting or a Brazilian style Unidade Real de Valor will stop Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation and stabilise the economy.

3. Constant real value non-monetary items are economic items with constant real values as a result of the double entry accounting model introduced in about the year 1300 in Venice, Italy.

Since hyper depreciating money is hyper depreciating legal tender in a hyperinflationary national economy, all economic items, including constant real value non-monetary items, are accounted using hyper depreciating money as the hyper depreciating monetary unit of account. Unfortunately cash hyperinflation continuously destroys the real value of hyper depreciating money over time. Under real value accounting constant real value non-monetary items in hyperinflationary economies are updated at the parallel exchange rate or in terms of a real value unit similar to the Unidade de Valor Real used during the last hyperinflationary period in Brazil, always at the current, that is, the daily rate at the date of the transaction or payment or the date of presentation (not preparation unless prepared and presented on the same day) of financial results.

Financial results are prepared in terms of the parallel rate on the balance sheet date. All the values in these financial statements are then updated at the current parallel rate every time the statements are accessed or presented afterwards. Computerised updating and presentation is the best form of implementation.

Constant real value non-monetary items include, for example: issued share capital, retained income, provisions, reserves, share premiums, retained losses, net monetary loss, net monetary gain, all items in shareholders equity, trade debtors, trade creditors, other debtors, other creditors, salaries, wages, fees, royalties, rent, interest paid in the Profit and Loss Account, interest received in the Profit and Loss Account, dividends, taxes, VAT, all Profit and Loss Account income/sales/revenue and all Profit and Loss Account costs and expenses, salaries payable, wages payable, rent payable, fees payable, royalties payable, interest payable, interest receivable, dividends payable, taxes payable, VAT payable, contstant real value non-monetary items stated at cost, salaries receivable, wages receivable, rent receivable, fees receivable, royalties receivable, dividends receivable taxes receivable, VAT receivable.

In most countries, primary financial statements are prepared on the Historical Cost basis of accounting without regard either to changes in the general level of prices or to increases in specific prices of assets held, except to the extent that property, plant and equipment and investments may be revalued.

The International Accounting Standards Board only identifies two instead of the three distinct economic items, namely, monetary and non-monetary items. The difference between variable and constant real value non-monetary items is ignored by the IASB as a result of the implementation of the stable measuring unit assumption - the cornerstone of the Historical Cost Accounting model - whereby it is accepted in low cash inflationary economies that the functional currency's internal real value is constantly being destroyed by cash inflation - but, this destruction of real value is regarded as of not sufficient importance to adjust the real values of constant real value non-monetary items in the financial statements. They are valued at Historical Cost which results in the destruction of their real values at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation year after year when they are not fully or never updated.

The IASB´s definition of non-monetary items include variable real value non-monetary items valued, for example, at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value. They also include Historical Cost items based on the stable measuring unit assumption.

One of the basic principles in accounting is the Measuring Unit principle: The unit of measure in accounting shall be the base money unit of the most relevant currency.

This principle also assumes the unit of measure is stable; that is, changes in its general purchasing power are not considered sufficiently important to require adjustments to the basic financial statements.

Valuing these items at Historical Cost results in their real values being destroyed at the rate of inflation/hyperinflation every single year when they are not fully or never updated, exactly the same as in monetary items or cash.

Although it is broadly known in low inflation economies that the destruction of the internal real value of the monetary unit of account is a very important matter and that inflation thus destroys the real value of all variable real value non-monetary items when they are not valued at fair value, market value, present value, net realizable value or recoverable value, for the purpose of valuing constant real value non-monetary items, the change in the real value of money is not regarded as sufficiently important to update their values in the financial statements.

However, when companies operate in an economy with hyperinflation (perhaps only Zimbabwe at the moment with 4 530% inflation), then it is International Accounting Standard practice to update everything in terms of International Accounting Standard IAS 29 Financial Reporting in Hyperinflationary Economies. Companies in hyperinflationary economies have to update variable AND constant real value non-monetary items.

But, ONLY as long as their annual inflation rate has been 26% for three years in a row adding up to 100% - the rate required for the implementation of IAS 29.

Once they are not in hyperinflation anymore, for example, 20% consecutive annual inflation for an indefinite period of time, then they are forbidden to update constant real value non-monetary items under the rules of Historical Cost Accounting. Then they must destroy their real value again – at 20% per annum – or at the many different levels of low inflation prevailing in the world today.

The stable measuring unit assumption is revoked under the Real Value Acounting model.

Historical Cost Accounting Hyperinflation is stopped with the implementation of the Real Value Accounting model.

The Historical Cost Accounting model automatically becomes the Real Value Accounting model only at 0% cash inflation. Real Value Accounting results in 0% Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation or 0% destruction of real value in all non-monetary items under any level of cash hyperinflation - all else except cash hyperinflation being equal.

Under the Real Value Accounting model hyperinflation only has one component, namely, a monetary component, that is, cash hyperinflation. Real Value Accounting stops Historical Cost Accounting hyperinflation.

Hyperinflation and the currency

In times of hyperinflation, gold is a store of value which cannot be printed out of existence
File:3sovriegns.jpg
A krugerrand and three sovereigns. Gold coins are hoarded to escape inflation. In times of inflation, the price of gold rises by roughly the devaluation of the paper currency.

As noted, in countries experiencing hyperinflation, the central bank often prints money in larger and larger denominations as the smaller denomination notes become worthless. This can result in the production of some interesting banknotes, including those denominated in amounts of 1,000,000,000 or more.

  • By late 1923, the Weimar Republic of Germany was issuing fifty-million Mark banknotes and postage stamps with a face value of fifty billion Mark. The highest value banknote issued by the Weimar government's Reichsbank had a face value of 100 billion Mark (100,000,000,000,000) {100 Trillion US/UK}. [1]. One of the firms printing these notes submitted an invoice for the work to the Reichsbank for 32,776,899,763,734,490,417.05 (3.28×1019, or 33 quintillion) Mark.
  • The largest denomination banknote ever officially issued for circulation was in 1946 by the Hungarian National Bank for the amount of 100 quintillion pengő (100,000,000,000,000,000,000, or 1020). image (There was even a banknote worth 10 times more, i.e. 1021 pengő, printed, but not issued image.) The banknotes however didn't depict the number, making the 500,000,000,000 Yugoslav dinar banknote the world's leader when it comes to depicted zeros on banknotes. The Post-WWII hyperinflation of Hungary holds the record for the most extreme monthly inflation rate ever — 41,900,000,000,000,000% (4.19 × 1016%) for July, 1946, amounting to prices doubling every fifteen hours.

One way to avoid the use of large numbers is by declaring a new unit of currency (so, instead of 10,000,000,000 Dollars, a bank might set 1 new dollar = 1,000,000,000 old dollars, so the new note would read "10 new dollars".) An example of this would be Turkey's revaluation of the Lira on January 1, 2005, when the old Turkish Lira (TRL) was converted to the new Turkish Lira (YTL) at a rate of 1,000,000 old to 1 new Turkish Lira. While this does not lessen actual value of a currency, it is called revaluation and also happens over time in countries with standard inflation levels. During hyperinflation, currency inflation happens so quickly that bills reach large numbers before revaluation.

Some banknotes were stamped to indicate changes of denomination. This is because it would take too long to print new notes. By time the new notes would be printed, they would be obsolete (that is, they would be of too low a denomination to be useful).

Metallic coins were rapid casualties of hyperinflation, as the scrap value of metal enormously exceeded the face value. Massive amounts of coinage were melted down, usually illicitly, and exported for hard currency.

Governments will often try to disguise the true rate of inflation through a variety of techniques. These can include the following:

  • Outright lying as to official statistics such as money supply, inflation or reserves.
  • Suppression of publication of money supply statistics, or inflation indices.
  • Price and wage controls.
  • Forced savings schemes, designed to suck up excess liquidity. These savings schemes may be described as pensions schemes, emergency funds, war funds, or similar.
  • Adjusting the components of the Consumer Price Index, to remove those items whose prices are rising the fastest.

None of these actions address the root causes of inflation, and in fact, if discovered, tend to further undermine trust in the currency, causing further increases in inflation.

Hyperinflation around the world

Angola
Angola went through the worst inflation from 1991 to 1995. In early 1991, the highest denomination was 50,000 kwanzas. By 1994, it was 500,000 kwanzas. In the 1995 currency reform, 1 kwanza reajustado was exchanged for 1,000 kwanzas. The highest denomination in 1995 was 5,000,000 kwanzas reajustados. In the 1999 currency reform, 1 new kwanza was exchanged for 1,000,000 kwanzas reajustados. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 new kwanza = 1,000,000,000 pre 1991 kwanzas.
Argentina
Argentina went through steady inflation from 1975 to 1991. At the beginning of 1975, the highest denomination was 1,000 pesos. In late 1976, the highest denomination was 5,000 pesos. In early 1979, the highest denomination was 10,000 pesos. By the end of 1981, the highest denomination was 1,000,000 pesos. In the 1983 currency reform, 1 Peso Argentino was exchanged for 10,000 pesos. In the 1985 currency reform, 1 austral was exchanged for 1,000 pesos argentino. In the 1992 currency reform, 1 new peso was exchanged for 10,000 australes. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 new peso = 100,000,000,000 pre-1983 pesos.
Austria
Between 1921 and 1922, inflation in Austria reached 134%.
Belarus
Belarus went through steady inflation from 1994 to 2002. In 1993, the highest denomination was 5,000 rublei. By 1999, it was 5,000,000 rublei. In the 2000 currency reform, the ruble was replaced by the new ruble at an exchange rate of 1 new ruble = 1,000 old rublei. The highest denomination in 2002 was 50,000 rublei, equal to 50,000,000 pre-2000 rublei.
Bolivia
Bolivia went through the worst inflation between 1984 and 1986. Before 1984, the highest denomination was 1,000 pesos bolivianos. By 1985, the highest denomination was 10 Million pesos bolivianos. In the 1987 currency reform, peso boliviano was replaced by boliviano which was pegged to U. S. dollar.
Bosnia-Herzegovina
Bosnia-Hezegovina went through its worst inflation in 1993. In 1992, the highest denomination was 1,000 dinara. By 1993, the highest denomination was 100,000,000 dinara. In the Republika Srpska, the highest denomination was 10,000 dinara in 1992 and 10,000,000,000 dinara in 1993. 50,000,000,000 dinara notes were also printed in 1993 but never issued.
Brazil
From 1986 to 1994, the base currency unit was shifted three times to adjust for inflation in the final years of the Brazilian military dictatorship era. A 1960s cruzeiro was, in 1994, worth less than one trillionth of a US cent, after adjusting for multiple devaluations and note changes. A new currency called real was adopted in 1994, and hyperinflation was eventually brought under control.
Chile
Beginning in 1971, during the presidency of Salvador Allende who had implemented many marxist or radical left programs. Chilean inflation began to rise and reached peaks of 1,200% in 1973. As a result of the hyperinflation, food became scarce and overpriced. The economic and social troubles culminated in the 1973 coup d'état that deposed the democratically-elected Allende and installed a military government led by Augusto Pinochet. Pinochet's free-market economic policy ended the inflation and except for an economic depression in 1981 the economy has fully recovered.
China
As the first user of fiat currency, China has had an early history of troubles caused by hyperinflation. The Yuan Dynasty printed huge amounts of fiat paper money to fund their wars, and the resulting hyperinflation, coupled with other factors, led to its demise at the hands of a revolution. The Republic of China went through the worst inflation 1948-49. In 1947, the highest denomination was 50,000 yuan. By mid-1948, the highest denomination was 180,000,000 yuan. The 1948 currency reform replaced the yuan by the gold yuan at an exchange rate of 1 gold yuan = 3,000,000 yuan. In less than 1 year, the highest denomination was 10,000,000 gold yuan. The highest denomination by a regional bank was 6,000,000,000 yuan issued by Sinkiang Provincial Bank in 1949
Free City of Danzig
Danzig went through the worst inflation in 1923. In 1922, the highest denomination was 1,000 Mark. By 1923, the highest denomination was 10,000,000,000 Mark.
Georgia
Georgia went through the worst inflation in 1994. In 1993, the highest denomination was 100,000 coupons [kuponi]. By 1994, the highest denomination was 1,000,000 coupons. In the 1995 currency reform, a new currency lari was introduced with 1 lari exchanged for 1,000,000 coupons.
Germany
Germany went through the worst inflation in 1923. In 1922, the highest denomination was 50,000 Mark. By 1923, the highest denomination was 100,000,000,000,000 Mark. In December of 1923 the exchange rate from marks to US dollars was 4,000,000,000,000:1. During the worst times, one U.S. dollar was equal to 80 billion Mark.
Greece
Greece went through its worst inflation in 1944. In 1943, the highest denomination was 25,000 drachmai. By 1944, the highest denomination was 100,000,000,000,000 drachmai. In the 1944 currency reform, 1 new drachma was exchanged for 50,000,000,000 drachmai. Another currency reform in 1953 replaced the drachma at an exchange rate of 1 new drachma = 1,000 old drachma. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 (1953) drachma = 50,000,000,000,000 pre 1944 drachmai. The Greek inflation rate reached 8.5 billion percent.
Hungary
Hungary went through the worst inflation in modern history in 1945-46. Before 1945, the highest denomination was 1,000 pengő. By the end of 1945, it was 10,000,000 pengő. The highest denomination in mid-1946 was 100,000,000,000,000,000,000 pengő. Banknotes The rate of inflation was 4.19 quintillion (4.19 x 1018) percent. A special currency the adópengő - or tax pengő - was created for tax and postal payments [2]. The value of the adópengő was adjusted each day, by radio announcement. On January 1, 1946 one adópengő equaled one pengő. By late July, one adópengő equaled 2,000,000,000,000,000,000,000 or 2×1021pengő. When the pengo was replaced in August 1946 by the forint, the total value of all Hungarian banknotes in circulation amounted to one-thousandth of one US cent. [1]
One source [3] states that this hyperinflation was purposely started by trained Russian Marxists in order to destroy the Hungarian middle and upper classes. The 1946 currency reform changed the currency to forint. Previously, between 1922 and 1924 inflation in Hungary reached 98%.
Israel
Inflation accelerated in the 1970s, rising steadily from 13% in 1971 to 111% in 1979.From 133% in 1980, it leaped to 191% in 1983 and then to 445% in 1984, threatening to become a four-digit figure within a year or two. In 1985 Israel froze all prices by law. That same year, inflation more than halved, to 185%. Within a few months, the authorities began to lift the price freeze on some items; in other cases it took almost a year. By 1986, inflation was down to 19%.
Krajina
Krajina went through the worst inflation in 1993. In 1992, the highest denomination was 50,000 dinara. By 1993, the highest denomination was 50,000,000,000 dinara. Note that this unrecognized country was reincorporated into Croatia in 1998.
Madagascar
The Malagasy franc had a turbulent time in 2004, losing nearly half its value and sparking rampant inflation. On 1 January 2005 the Malagasy ariary replaced the previous currency at a rate of 0.2 ariary for one Malagsy franc. In May 2005 there were riots over rising inflation, although falling prices have since calmed the situation.
Mexico
The Mexican peso had a turbulent time in late 1980's and early 1990's, culmanating in the 1994 economic crisis in Mexico.
Nicaragua
Nicaragua went through the worst inflation from 1987 to 1990. Before 1987, the highest denomination was 1,000 córdobas. By 1987, it was 500,000 córdobas, overprinted on a 1,000-córdoba bill. In the 1988 currency reform, 1 new córdoba was exchanged for 1,000 old córdobas. The highest denomination in 1990 was 100,000,000 new córdobas. In the mid-1990 currency reform, 1 gold cordoba was exchanged for 5,000,000 new córdobas. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 gold córdoba = 5,000,000,000 pre-1988 córdobas.
Peru
Peru went through the worst inflation from 1984 to 1990. The highest denomination in 1984 was 50,000 soles de oro. By 1985, it was 500,000 soles de oro. In the 1985 currency reform, 1 inti was exchanged for 1,000 soles de oro. In 1986, the highest denomination was 1,000 intis. It was 20,000,000 intis by 1991. In the 1991 currency reform, 1 nuevo sol was exchanged for 1,000,000 intis. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 nuevo sol = 1,000,000,000 pre 1985 soles de oro.
Poland
Poland went through the worst inflation between 1990 and 1993. The highest denomination in 1989 was 200,000 zlotych. It was 1,000,000 zlotych in 1991 and 2,000,000 zlotych in 1992. In the 1994 currency reform, 1 new zloty was exchanged for 10,000 old zlotych. Previously, between 1922 and 1924, Polish inflation reached 275%.
Romania
Romania is still working through steady inflation. The highest denomination in 1998 was 100,000 lei. By 2000 it was 500,000 lei. In early 2005 it was 1,000,000 lei. In July 2005 the leu was replaced by the new leu at 10,000 old lei = 1 new leu. Inflation in 2005 was 9%. In 2006 the highest denomination is 500 lei (= 5,000,000 old lei).
Russia
Between 1921 and 1922, during the civil war, inflation in Russia reached 213%.
In 1992, the first year of post-Soviet economic reform, inflation was 2,520%, the major cause being the decontrol of most prices in January. In 1993 the annual rate was 840%, and in 1994, 224%. The ruble devalued from about 100 r/$ in 1991 to about 30,000 r/$ in 1999.
Taiwan
Severe inflation existed in the late 1940s due to factors such as corruption and Chinese Civil War. Increasingly higher denominations were issued on the island, up to one million yuan. one million yuan Inflation was eventually controlled after the new Taiwan dollar was issued in 1949 at a ratio of 40,000-to-1 against the old Taiwan yuan.
Turkey
Throughout the 1990s Turkey dealt with severe inflation rates that finally crippled the economy into a recession in 2001. The highest denomination in 1995 was 1,000,000 lira. By 2000 it was 20,000,000 lira. Recently Turkey has achieved single digit inflation for the first time in decades, and in the 2005 currency reform, introduced the New Turkish Lira; 1 was exchanged for 1,000,000 old lira. There is still double digit inflation from 2005-2007.
Ukraine
Ukraine went through the worst inflation between 1993 and 1995. Before 1993, the highest denomination was 1,000 karbovantsiv. By 1995, it was 1,000,000 karbovantsiv. In 1992, theUkrainian karbovanets was introduced, which was exchanged with the defunct Soviet ruble at a rate of 1 UAK = 1 SUR. In 1996, during the transition to the Hryvnya and the subsequent phase out of the karbovanets, the exchange rate was 100,000 UAK = 1 UAH. This translates to a hyperinflation rate of approximately 1,400% per month.
United States
During The Revolutionary War, the Continental Congress authorized the printing of paper currency called continental currency. The easily counterfeited notes depreciated rapidly, giving rise to the expression "not worth a continental."
Between January 1861 and April 1865, the Lerner Commodity Price Index of leading cities in the eastern Confederacy states increased from 100 to over 9000. As the U.S. Civil War dragged on the Confederate States of America dollar had less and less value, until it was almost worthless by the last few months of the war.
A large (approximately 8 feet in height) example of Yapese stone money
Yap
The island of Yap in the Pacific Ocean used varying sized stones as money, of which the largest weighing several tons were the most valuable. The stones had been brought by sea from the Island of Palau 210 km away. The journey was very perilous given the length of the voyage and the rough seas between the islands of Palau and Yap. Many of the stones were lost at sea. The risk associated with procurement of the "money stones" initially made them highly valuable. The Yapese valued them because large stones were quite difficult to steal and were in relatively short supply. However, in 1874, an enterprising Irishman named David O'Keefe hit upon the idea of employing the Yapese to import more "money" in the form of shiploads of large stones, also from Palau. O'Keefe then traded these stones with the Yapese for other commodities such as sea cucumbers and copra. Over time, the Yapese brought thousands of new stones to the island, debasing the value of the old ones. Today they are almost worthless, except as a tourist curiosity.
Yugoslavia
Yugoslavia went through a period of hyperinflation and subsequent currency reforms from 1989 to 1994. The highest denomination in 1988 was 50,000 dinars. By 1989 it was 2,000,000 dinars. In the 1990 currency reform, 1 new dinar was exchanged for 10,000 old dinars. In the 1992 currency reform, 1 new dinar was exchanged for 10 old dinars. The highest denomination in 1992 was 50,000 dinars. By 1993, it was 10,000,000,000 dinars. In the 1993 currency reform, 1 new dinar was exchanged for 1,000,000 old dinars. But before the year was over, the highest denomination was 500,000,000,000 dinars. In the 1994 currency reform, 1 new dinar was exchanged for 1,000,000,000 old dinars. In another currency reform a month later, 1 novi dinar was exchanged for 10~13 million dinars (1 novi dinar = 1 German mark at the time of exchange). The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 novi dinar = 1 × 1027~1.3 × 1027 pre 1990 dinars.
Zaire (now the Democratic Republic of the Congo)
Zaire went through a period of inflation between 1989 and 1996. In 1988, the highest denomination was 5,000 zaires. By 1992, it was 5,000,000 zaires. In the 1993 currency reform, 1 nouveau zaire was exchanged for 3,000,000 old zaires. The highest denomination in 1996 was 1,000,000 nouveaux zaires. In 1997, Zaire was renamed the Congo Democratic Republic and changed its currency to francs. 1 franc was exchanged for 100,000 nouveaux zaires. The overall impact of hyperinflation: 1 franc = 3 × 1011 pre 1989 zaires.
Zimbabwe

Template:ZWD inflation

At Independence, in 1980, the Zimbabwe dollar was worth about $1.50 US. Since then, rampant inflation and the collapse of the economy have severely devalued the currency, with many organisations using the US dollar instead. Inflation was stable until Mugabe began land reforms, taking land off white farmers, sending food production and export revenues plummeting.
Early in the 21st century Zimbabwe started to experience hyperinflation. Inflation reached 624% in early 2004, then fell back to low triple digits before surging to a new high of 1,730% in March 2007. On April 27, 2007, the government released the latest figures of 2,200%. The predictions for the annual inflation range from 3,000% (according to the IMF) to 8,000% [4].
On 16 February 2006, the governor of the Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, Dr Gideon Gono, announced that the government had printed ZWD 21 trillion in order to buy foreign currency to pay off IMF arrears.
In early May 2006, Zimbabwe's government began rolling the printing presses (once again) to produce about 60 trillion Zimbabwean dollars. The additional currency was required to finance the recent 300% increase in salaries for soldiers and policemen and 200% for other civil servants. The money was not budgeted for the current fiscal year, and the government did not say where it would come from.
In August 2006, the Zimbabwean government issued new currency and asked citizens to turn in old notes; the new currency (issued by the central bank of Zimbabwe) had three zeroes slashed from it. Most financial analysts remained skeptical and said that the new money would not provide relief from record inflation. [5]
In February 2007, the central bank of Zimbabwe declared inflation "illegal", outlawing any raise in prices on certain commodities between March 1 and June 30, 2007. Officials have arrested executives of some Zimbabwean companies for increasing prices on their products. Economists generally suspect that such measures will be ineffective at eliminating the problem in the long term. [6] [7]
In April 2007 it was announced that in the preceding month the cost of living had doubled, bringing Zimbabwe's annual inflation to 3700%.[8]
In June 2007 Inflation in Zimbabwe had risen to 11,000% from an earlier estimate of 9,000%. U.S. ambassador Christopher Dell predicted it will reach 1.5 million percent by December 2007. [9]

See also

References

  1. ^ Judt, Tony (2006). Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945. Penguin. pp. p. 87. ISBN 0143037757. {{cite book}}: |pages= has extra text (help)
  • Costantino Bresciani-Turroni, The Economics of Inflation (English transl.). Northampton, England: Augustus Kelly Publishers, 1937, on the German 1919-1923 inflation.
  • Shun-Hsin Chou, The Chinese Inflation 1937-1949, New York, Columbia University Press, 1963, Library of Congress Cat. 62-18260.
  • Andrew Dickson White, Fiat Money Inflation in France, Caxton Printers, Idaho, 1969. a popular description of the 1789-1799 inflation.
  • F.A. Hayek, Choice in Currency: A Way to Stop Inflation, Institute of Economic Affairs, London, 1976. Free download. Includes section on 1920s Germany.
  • Whittington, G., "Inflation Accounting: An introduction to the debate", Cambridge, Cambridge University Press, 1983.
  • Paul H. Walgenbach, Norman E. Dittrich and Ernest I. Hanson, (1973), Financial Accounting, New York: Harcourt Brace Javonovich, Inc. Page 429.