Jump to content

Social trap: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
formatting, punctuation, copyedit, caps, alphabetize See also and remove link already included in article
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Nofootnotes|article|date=March 2008}} {{Original research|date=March 2008}}
{{Nofootnotes|article|date=March 2008}} {{Original research|date=March 2008}}
'''Social trap''' is a term used by psychologists to describe a situation in which a group of people act to obtain short-term individual gains, which in the long run leads to a loss for the group as a whole. Examples of social traps include the overharvesting of fish species by commercial and sport fishers, the near-[[extinction]] of the [[American bison]], energy "brownout" and "blackout" [[power outage]]s during periods of extreme temperatures, the [[overgrazing]] of cattle on the [[Sahel]]ian Desert, and the destruction of the [[rainforest]] by [[logging]] interests and [[agriculture]].
'''''Social trap''''' is a term used by psychologists to describe a situation in which a group of people act to obtain short-term individual gains, which in the long run leads to a loss for the group as a whole. Examples of social traps include the overharvesting of fish species by commercial and sport fishers, the near-[[extinction]] of the [[American bison]], energy "brownout" and "blackout" [[power outage]]s during periods of extreme temperatures, the [[overgrazing]] of cattle on the [[Sahel]]ian Desert, and the destruction of the [[rainforest]] by [[logging]] interests and [[agriculture]].


== Origin of the concept ==
== Origin of the concept ==


The term "social trap" was first introduced to the scientific community by John Platt's 1973 paper in ''[[American Psychologist]]''. The term was developed in an interdisciplinary symposium held at the [[University of Michigan]] (Cross & Guyer, 1980). Building upon the concept of the "[[tragedy of the commons]]" in [[Garrett Hardin]]'s pivotal article in ''[[Science (journal)|Science]]'' (1968), Platt and others in the seminar applied behavioral [[psychology]] concepts to actions of people operating in social traps. Using a behavioral analysis based upon the work of [[B.F. Skinner]] (1938, 1948, 1953, 1957) and his colleagues (Keller and Schoenfeld, 1950), Platt recognized that individuals operating for short-term positive [[reinforcement]] had a tendency to over-exploit the resource which led to a long-term negative loss to society.
The term ''social trap'' was first introduced to the scientific community by John Platt's 1973 paper in ''[[American Psychologist]]'', and developed in an interdisciplinary symposium held at the [[University of Michigan]] (Cross & Guyer, 1980). Building upon the concept of the "[[tragedy of the commons]]" in [[Garrett Hardin]]'s pivotal article in ''[[Science (journal)|Science]]'' (1968), Platt and others in the seminar applied behavioral [[psychology]] concepts to actions of people operating in social traps. Using a behavioral analysis based upon the work of [[B.F. Skinner]] (1938, 1948, 1953, 1957) and his colleagues (Keller and Schoenfeld, 1950), Platt recognized that individuals operating for short-term positive [[reinforcement]] had a tendency to over-exploit a resource, which led to a long-term negative loss to society.


The application of behavioral psychology terms to behaviors in the tragedy of the commons led to the realization that the same short-term/long-term cause-effect relationship also applied to other human traps in addition to the exploitation of commonly held resources. Platt ''et al.'' also introduced the terms "social fence" and "individual trap." Social Fence refers to a short-term avoidance behavior by individuals that leads to a long-term loss to the entire group. The example presented of a social fence is the anecdote of a mattress that falls from a vehicle on a two lane highway. Motorists tend to back up in a traffic jam behind the mattress, waiting for a break in the oncoming traffic to pass around the mattress. Each individual motorist avoided the opportunity to exit their stopped car and pull the mattress to the side of the road. The long-term consequence of this avoidance behavior was that all the motorists (except for perhaps one) arrived at their destinations later than they would have had an individual removed the mattress barrier.
The application of behavioral psychology terms to behaviors in the tragedy of the commons led to the realization that the same short-term/long-term cause-effect relationship also applied to other human traps, in addition to the exploitation of commonly held resources. Platt et al. also introduced the terms ''social fence'' and ''individual trap''. ''Social fence'' refers to a short-term avoidance behavior by individuals that leads to a long-term loss to the entire group. An example is the anecdote of a mattress that falls from a vehicle on a two lane highway. Motorists tend to back up in a traffic jam behind the mattress, waiting for a break in the oncoming traffic to pass around the mattress. Each individual motorist avoids the opportunity to exit their stopped car and pull the mattress to the side of the road. The long-term consequence of this avoidance behavior is that all of the motorists (except for perhaps one) arrived at their destinations later than they would have if an individual had removed the mattress barrier.


An individual trap is similar to a social trap except that it involves the behavior of only a single person rather than a group of people. The basic concept is that an individual's behavior for short-term reinforcers leads to a long-term loss for the individual. Examples of individual traps are [[tobacco smoking]] leading to [[lung cancer]] or [[alcohol]] ingestion leading to [[cirrhosis]] of the liver.
An individual trap is similar to a social trap except that it involves the behavior of only a single person rather than a group of people. The basic concept is that an individual's behavior for short-term reinforcers leads to a long-term loss for the individual. Examples of individual traps are [[tobacco smoking]] leading to [[lung cancer]] or [[alcohol]] ingestion leading to [[cirrhosis]] of the liver.


== First empirical test and the use of superimposed schedules of reinforcement ==
== First empirical test and the use of superimposed schedules of reinforcement ==
The first empirical test of the concept of social traps was by Brechner (1974, 1977) at [[Arizona State University]], who operationalized the concepts underlying Platt ''et al.'''s theoretical analysis. By creating a laboratory game, Brechner had groups of college students playing a game where they could accumulate points by pressing buttons for the individual short-term positive rewards of experimental credit in their introductory psychology classes. Players could see a lighted display that indicated the total quantity of points available at any given time in the experiment. Players were told that if they completely drained the pool of points, the game was over and they could not accumulate more points. By responding for points at a moderate rate all the players in the group could accumulate enough points to fulfill their entire semester's experimental requirements. But if one or more players took points for themselves at too fast a rate, the pool would be drained of points and none of the players would achieve the maximum potential experimental credit.
The first empirical test of the concept of social traps was by Brechner (1974, 1977) at [[Arizona State University]], who operationalized the concepts underlying Platt et al's theoretical analysis. By creating a laboratory game, Brechner had groups of college students playing a game where they could accumulate points by pressing buttons for the individual short-term positive rewards of experimental credit in their introductory psychology classes. Players could see a lighted display that indicated the total quantity of points available at any given time in the experiment. Players were told that if they completely drained the pool of points, the game was over and they could not accumulate more points. By responding for points at a moderate rate all the players in the group could accumulate enough points to fulfill their entire semester's experimental requirements. But if one or more players took points for themselves at too fast a rate, the pool would be drained of points and none of the players would achieve the maximum potential experimental credit.


In building the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner introduced the concept of "[[superimposed schedules of reinforcement]]." [[Skinner]] and Ferster (1957) had demonstrated that reinforcers could be delivered on schedules ([[reinforcement#schedules of reinforcement|schedule of reinforcement]]), and further that organisms behaved differently under different schedules. Rather than a reinforcer, such as food or water, being delivered every time as a consequence of some behavior, a reinforcer could be delivered after more than one instance of the behavior. For example, a [[pigeon]] may be required to peck a button switch five times before food is made available to the pigeon. This is called a "ratio schedule." Also, a reinforcer could be delivered after an interval of time passed following a target behavior. An example is a [[rat]] that is given a food pellet one minute after the rat pressed a lever. This is called an "interval schedule." In addition, ratio schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable number of behaviors by the individual organism. Likewise, interval schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable intervals of time following a single response by the organism. Individual behaviors tend to generate response rates that differ based upon how the reinforcement schedule is created. Much subsequent research in many labs examined the effects on behaviors of scheduling reinforcers.
In building the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner introduced the concept of "[[superimposed schedules of reinforcement]]". [[Skinner]] and Ferster (1957) had demonstrated that reinforcers could be delivered on schedules ([[reinforcement#schedules of reinforcement|schedule of reinforcement]]), and further that organisms behaved differently under different schedules. Rather than a reinforcer, such as food or water, being delivered every time as a consequence of some behavior, a reinforcer could be delivered after more than one instance of the behavior. For example, a [[pigeon]] may be required to peck a button switch five times before food is made available to the pigeon. This is called a "ratio schedule". Also, a reinforcer could be delivered after an interval of time passed following a target behavior. An example is a [[rat]] that is given a food pellet one minute after the rat pressed a lever. This is called an "interval schedule". In addition, ratio schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable number of behaviors by the individual organism. Likewise, interval schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable intervals of time following a single response by the organism. Individual behaviors tend to generate response rates that differ based upon how the reinforcement schedule is created. Much subsequent research in many labs examined the effects on behaviors of scheduling reinforcers.


When an organism is offered the opportunity to choose between or among two or more simple schedules of reinforcement at the same time, the reinforcement structures are called "[[concurrent schedules of reinforcement]]." In creating the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner created a situation where simple reinforcement schedules were superimposed upon each other. In other words, a single response or group of responses by an organism led to multiple consequences. Concurrent schedules of reinforcement can be thought of as "or" schedules, and [[superimposed schedules of reinforcement]] can be thought of as "and" schedules.
When an organism is offered the opportunity to choose between or among two or more simple schedules of reinforcement at the same time, the reinforcement structures are called "[[concurrent schedules of reinforcement]]". In creating the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner created a situation where simple reinforcement schedules were superimposed upon each other. In other words, a single response or group of responses by an organism led to multiple consequences. Concurrent schedules of reinforcement can be thought of as "or" schedules, and [[superimposed schedules of reinforcement]] can be thought of as "and" schedules.


To simulate social traps a short-term positive reward is superimposed upon a long-term negative consequence. In the specific experiment, the short-term positive reinforcer was earning points that applied to class credits. The long-term negative consequence was that each point earned by a player also drained the pool of available points. Responding too rapidly for short-term gains led to the long-term loss of draining the resource pool. What makes the traps social is that any individual can respond in a way that the long-term consequence also comes to bear on the other individuals in the environment.
To simulate social traps a short-term positive reward is superimposed upon a long-term negative consequence. In the specific experiment, the short-term positive reinforcer was earning points that applied to class credits. The long-term negative consequence was that each point earned by a player also drained the pool of available points. Responding too rapidly for short-term gains led to the long-term loss of draining the resource pool. What makes the traps social is that any individual can respond in a way that the long-term consequence also comes to bear on the other individuals in the environment.


Superimposed schedules of reinforcement have many real-world applications in addition to generating social traps (Brechner and Linder, 1981; Brechner, 1987). Many different human individual and social situations can be created by superimposing simple reinforcement schedules. For example, a human being could have simultaneous tobacco and alcohol addictions. Even more complex situations can be created or simulated by superimposing two or more concurrent schedules. For example, a high school senior could have a choice between going to Stanford University or UCLA, and at the same time have the choice of going into the Army or the Air Force, and simultaneously the choice of taking a job with an internet company or a job with a software company. That would be a reinforcement structure of three superimposed concurrent schedules of reinforcement. An example of the use of superimposed schedules as a a tool in the analysis of the contingencies of rent control can be found online in the website "Economic and Game Theory Forum," (Brechner, 2003).
Superimposed schedules of reinforcement have many real-world applications in addition to generating social traps (Brechner and Linder, 1981; Brechner, 1987). Many different human individual and social situations can be created by superimposing simple reinforcement schedules. For example, a human being could have simultaneous tobacco and alcohol addictions. Even more complex situations can be created or simulated by superimposing two or more concurrent schedules. For example, a high school senior could have a choice between going to Stanford University or UCLA, and at the same time have the choice of going into the Army or the Air Force, and simultaneously the choice of taking a job with an internet company or a job with a software company. That would be a reinforcement structure of three superimposed concurrent schedules of reinforcement. An example of the use of superimposed schedules as a a tool in the analysis of the contingencies of rent control can be found online in the website "Economic and Game Theory Forum", (Brechner, 2003).


== Subsequent experimentation ==
== Subsequent experimentation ==
Subsequent empirical studies by other researchers explored aspects of social traps other than the underlying reinforcement structure. Studies tended to concentrate on manipulating social and cognitive variables. Cass and Edney (1978) created a simpler game using a bowl of nuts to simulate a commonly held resource. The Nuts Game as they called it had some distinct advantages over Brechner's electronically wired laboratory simulation. The Nuts Game could be transported easily to any environment in or out of the laboratory. It was simple and required no electronics. The reinforcers used were primary food rewards rather than the secondary conditioned reinforcers of class credit used in the earlier study.
Subsequent empirical studies by other researchers explored aspects of social traps other than the underlying reinforcement structure. Studies tended to concentrate on manipulating social and cognitive variables. Cass and Edney (1978) created a simpler game using a bowl of nuts to simulate a commonly held resource. The Nuts Game as they called it had some distinct advantages over Brechner's electronically wired laboratory simulation. The Nuts Game could be transported easily to any environment in or out of the laboratory. It was simple and required no electronics. The reinforcers used were primary food rewards rather than the secondary conditioned reinforcers of class credit used in the earlier study.


From Platt ''et al'''s initial concept, social trap research has spread to laboratories all over the world and has expanded into the fields of Sociology and Economics. Summaries of the many other diverse studies of social traps can be found in Messick and McClelland (1983) and Rothstein (2005).
From Platt et al's initial concept, social trap research has spread to laboratories all over the world and has expanded into the fields of Sociology and Economics. Summaries of the many other diverse studies of social traps can be found in Messick and McClelland (1983) and Rothstein (2005).


==See also==
==See also==
*[[prisoner's dilemma]]
*[[Prisoner's dilemma]]
*[[trigger strategy]]
*[[Trigger strategy]]
*[[War of attrition (game)]]
*[[War of attrition (game)|War of attrition]]
*[[Zero-sum]]
*[[Zero-sum]]
*[[Tragedy of commons]]

{{Game theory}}


==References==
==References==
Brechner. K. C. (1974) An experimental analysis of social traps. Ph.D. Dissertation, Arizona State University.
*Brechner. K. C. (1974) An experimental analysis of social traps. Ph.D. Dissertation, Arizona State University.
Brechner, K. C. (1977). An experimental analysis of social traps. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 13, 552-564.
*Brechner, K. C. (1977). An experimental analysis of social traps. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 13, 552-564.
Brechner, K.C. (1987) Social Traps, Individual Traps, and Theory in Social Psychology. Pasadena, CA: Time River Laboratory, Bulletin No. 870001.
*Brechner, K.C. (1987) Social Traps, Individual Traps, and Theory in Social Psychology. Pasadena, CA: Time River Laboratory, Bulletin No. 870001.


Brechner, K.C. (2003) Superimposed schedules of reinforcement applied to rent control. Economic and Game Theory Forum, 2/18/03, http://www.dklevine.com/bin/workshops-php/discuss/discuss.php3?showID=396467000000000285.
*Brechner, K.C. (2003) Superimposed schedules of reinforcement applied to rent control. Economic and Game Theory Forum, 2/18/03, http://www.dklevine.com/bin/workshops-php/discuss/discuss.php3?showID=396467000000000285.
Brechner, K.C. and Linder, D.E. (1981), A social trap analysis of energy distribution systems, in Advances in Environmental Psychology, Vol. 3, A. Baum & Singer, JE, eds. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum & Associates.
*Brechner, K.C. and Linder, D.E. (1981), A social trap analysis of energy distribution systems, in Advances in Environmental Psychology, Vol. 3, A. Baum & Singer, JE, eds. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum & Associates.
Cass, R., & Edney, J. J. (1978) The commons dilemma: A simulation testing the effects of resource visibility and territorial division. Human Ecology, 6, 371—386.
*Cass, R., & Edney, J. J. (1978) The commons dilemma: A simulation testing the effects of resource visibility and territorial division. Human Ecology, 6, 371—386.
Cross, J.G. and M.J. Guyer (1980) Social Traps. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press; ISBN 0-472-06315-4.
*Cross, J.G. and M.J. Guyer (1980) Social Traps. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press; ISBN 0-472-06315-4.
Edney, J.J. and C. S. Harper (1978) The effects of information in a resource management problem: A social trap analog. Human Ecology,6 (4), 387-395.
*Edney, J.J. and C. S. Harper (1978) The effects of information in a resource management problem: A social trap analog. Human Ecology,6 (4), 387-395.
[[Hardin]], G. (1968) The Tragedy of the Commons, Science, 162, 1243-1248.
*[[Hardin]], G. (1968) The Tragedy of the Commons, Science, 162, 1243-1248.
Keller, F. S. and W. N. Schoenfeld (1950) Principles of Psychology, New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
*Keller, F. S. and W. N. Schoenfeld (1950) Principles of Psychology, New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
Messick, D.M. and C.L. McClelland (1983) Social Traps and Temporal Traps, [[Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin]], Vol. 9, No. 1, 105-110 (1983)
*Messick, D.M. and C.L. McClelland (1983) Social Traps and Temporal Traps, [[Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin]], Vol. 9, No. 1, 105-110 (1983)
Platt, J. (1973) Social Traps, American Psychologist, 28, 641-65.
*Platt, J. (1973) Social Traps, American Psychologist, 28, 641-65.
Rothstein, B. (2005) Social Traps and the Problem of Trust, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ISBN-13: 9780521612821 | ISBN-10: 0521612829)
*Rothstein, B. (2005) Social Traps and the Problem of Trust, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ISBN-13: 9780521612821 | ISBN-10: 0521612829)


[[Skinner]], B.F. (1938) The Behavior of Organisms: An Experimental Analysis, ISBN 1-58390-007-1, ISBN 0-87411-487-X.
*[[Skinner]], B.F. (1938) The Behavior of Organisms: An Experimental Analysis, ISBN 1-58390-007-1, ISBN 0-87411-487-X.
[[Skinner]], B.F. (1948) Walden Two. ISBN 0-02-411510-X.
*[[Skinner]], B.F. (1948) Walden Two. ISBN 0-02-411510-X.
[[Skinner]], B.F. (1953) Science and Human Behavior, ISBN 0-02-929040-6.
*[[Skinner]], B.F. (1953) Science and Human Behavior, ISBN 0-02-929040-6.
[[Skinner]], B.F. with C. B. Ferster, (1957) Schedules of Reinforcement, ISBN 0-13-792309-0.
*[[Skinner]], B.F. with C. B. Ferster, (1957) Schedules of Reinforcement, ISBN 0-13-792309-0.
[[Skinner]], B.F. (1957) Verbal Behavior, ISBN 1-58390-021-7.
*[[Skinner]], B.F. (1957) Verbal Behavior, ISBN 1-58390-021-7.
{{Game theory}}

[[Category:Social psychology]]
[[Category:Social psychology]]
[[Category:Figures of speech]]
[[Category:Figures of speech]]

Revision as of 22:38, 26 March 2008

Social trap is a term used by psychologists to describe a situation in which a group of people act to obtain short-term individual gains, which in the long run leads to a loss for the group as a whole. Examples of social traps include the overharvesting of fish species by commercial and sport fishers, the near-extinction of the American bison, energy "brownout" and "blackout" power outages during periods of extreme temperatures, the overgrazing of cattle on the Sahelian Desert, and the destruction of the rainforest by logging interests and agriculture.

Origin of the concept

The term social trap was first introduced to the scientific community by John Platt's 1973 paper in American Psychologist, and developed in an interdisciplinary symposium held at the University of Michigan (Cross & Guyer, 1980). Building upon the concept of the "tragedy of the commons" in Garrett Hardin's pivotal article in Science (1968), Platt and others in the seminar applied behavioral psychology concepts to actions of people operating in social traps. Using a behavioral analysis based upon the work of B.F. Skinner (1938, 1948, 1953, 1957) and his colleagues (Keller and Schoenfeld, 1950), Platt recognized that individuals operating for short-term positive reinforcement had a tendency to over-exploit a resource, which led to a long-term negative loss to society.

The application of behavioral psychology terms to behaviors in the tragedy of the commons led to the realization that the same short-term/long-term cause-effect relationship also applied to other human traps, in addition to the exploitation of commonly held resources. Platt et al. also introduced the terms social fence and individual trap. Social fence refers to a short-term avoidance behavior by individuals that leads to a long-term loss to the entire group. An example is the anecdote of a mattress that falls from a vehicle on a two lane highway. Motorists tend to back up in a traffic jam behind the mattress, waiting for a break in the oncoming traffic to pass around the mattress. Each individual motorist avoids the opportunity to exit their stopped car and pull the mattress to the side of the road. The long-term consequence of this avoidance behavior is that all of the motorists (except for perhaps one) arrived at their destinations later than they would have if an individual had removed the mattress barrier.

An individual trap is similar to a social trap except that it involves the behavior of only a single person rather than a group of people. The basic concept is that an individual's behavior for short-term reinforcers leads to a long-term loss for the individual. Examples of individual traps are tobacco smoking leading to lung cancer or alcohol ingestion leading to cirrhosis of the liver.

First empirical test and the use of superimposed schedules of reinforcement

The first empirical test of the concept of social traps was by Brechner (1974, 1977) at Arizona State University, who operationalized the concepts underlying Platt et al's theoretical analysis. By creating a laboratory game, Brechner had groups of college students playing a game where they could accumulate points by pressing buttons for the individual short-term positive rewards of experimental credit in their introductory psychology classes. Players could see a lighted display that indicated the total quantity of points available at any given time in the experiment. Players were told that if they completely drained the pool of points, the game was over and they could not accumulate more points. By responding for points at a moderate rate all the players in the group could accumulate enough points to fulfill their entire semester's experimental requirements. But if one or more players took points for themselves at too fast a rate, the pool would be drained of points and none of the players would achieve the maximum potential experimental credit.

In building the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner introduced the concept of "superimposed schedules of reinforcement". Skinner and Ferster (1957) had demonstrated that reinforcers could be delivered on schedules (schedule of reinforcement), and further that organisms behaved differently under different schedules. Rather than a reinforcer, such as food or water, being delivered every time as a consequence of some behavior, a reinforcer could be delivered after more than one instance of the behavior. For example, a pigeon may be required to peck a button switch five times before food is made available to the pigeon. This is called a "ratio schedule". Also, a reinforcer could be delivered after an interval of time passed following a target behavior. An example is a rat that is given a food pellet one minute after the rat pressed a lever. This is called an "interval schedule". In addition, ratio schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable number of behaviors by the individual organism. Likewise, interval schedules can deliver reinforcement following fixed or variable intervals of time following a single response by the organism. Individual behaviors tend to generate response rates that differ based upon how the reinforcement schedule is created. Much subsequent research in many labs examined the effects on behaviors of scheduling reinforcers.

When an organism is offered the opportunity to choose between or among two or more simple schedules of reinforcement at the same time, the reinforcement structures are called "concurrent schedules of reinforcement". In creating the laboratory analogy of social traps, Brechner created a situation where simple reinforcement schedules were superimposed upon each other. In other words, a single response or group of responses by an organism led to multiple consequences. Concurrent schedules of reinforcement can be thought of as "or" schedules, and superimposed schedules of reinforcement can be thought of as "and" schedules.

To simulate social traps a short-term positive reward is superimposed upon a long-term negative consequence. In the specific experiment, the short-term positive reinforcer was earning points that applied to class credits. The long-term negative consequence was that each point earned by a player also drained the pool of available points. Responding too rapidly for short-term gains led to the long-term loss of draining the resource pool. What makes the traps social is that any individual can respond in a way that the long-term consequence also comes to bear on the other individuals in the environment.

Superimposed schedules of reinforcement have many real-world applications in addition to generating social traps (Brechner and Linder, 1981; Brechner, 1987). Many different human individual and social situations can be created by superimposing simple reinforcement schedules. For example, a human being could have simultaneous tobacco and alcohol addictions. Even more complex situations can be created or simulated by superimposing two or more concurrent schedules. For example, a high school senior could have a choice between going to Stanford University or UCLA, and at the same time have the choice of going into the Army or the Air Force, and simultaneously the choice of taking a job with an internet company or a job with a software company. That would be a reinforcement structure of three superimposed concurrent schedules of reinforcement. An example of the use of superimposed schedules as a a tool in the analysis of the contingencies of rent control can be found online in the website "Economic and Game Theory Forum", (Brechner, 2003).

Subsequent experimentation

Subsequent empirical studies by other researchers explored aspects of social traps other than the underlying reinforcement structure. Studies tended to concentrate on manipulating social and cognitive variables. Cass and Edney (1978) created a simpler game using a bowl of nuts to simulate a commonly held resource. The Nuts Game as they called it had some distinct advantages over Brechner's electronically wired laboratory simulation. The Nuts Game could be transported easily to any environment in or out of the laboratory. It was simple and required no electronics. The reinforcers used were primary food rewards rather than the secondary conditioned reinforcers of class credit used in the earlier study.

From Platt et al's initial concept, social trap research has spread to laboratories all over the world and has expanded into the fields of Sociology and Economics. Summaries of the many other diverse studies of social traps can be found in Messick and McClelland (1983) and Rothstein (2005).

See also

References

  • Brechner. K. C. (1974) An experimental analysis of social traps. Ph.D. Dissertation, Arizona State University.
  • Brechner, K. C. (1977). An experimental analysis of social traps. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 13, 552-564.
  • Brechner, K.C. (1987) Social Traps, Individual Traps, and Theory in Social Psychology. Pasadena, CA: Time River Laboratory, Bulletin No. 870001.
  • Brechner, K.C. and Linder, D.E. (1981), A social trap analysis of energy distribution systems, in Advances in Environmental Psychology, Vol. 3, A. Baum & Singer, JE, eds. Hillsdale, NJ: Lawrence Erlbaum & Associates.
  • Cass, R., & Edney, J. J. (1978) The commons dilemma: A simulation testing the effects of resource visibility and territorial division. Human Ecology, 6, 371—386.
  • Cross, J.G. and M.J. Guyer (1980) Social Traps. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press; ISBN 0-472-06315-4.
  • Edney, J.J. and C. S. Harper (1978) The effects of information in a resource management problem: A social trap analog. Human Ecology,6 (4), 387-395.
  • Hardin, G. (1968) The Tragedy of the Commons, Science, 162, 1243-1248.
  • Keller, F. S. and W. N. Schoenfeld (1950) Principles of Psychology, New York: Appleton-Century-Crofts.
  • Platt, J. (1973) Social Traps, American Psychologist, 28, 641-65.
  • Rothstein, B. (2005) Social Traps and the Problem of Trust, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, ISBN-13: 9780521612821 | ISBN-10: 0521612829)
  • Skinner, B.F. (1938) The Behavior of Organisms: An Experimental Analysis, ISBN 1-58390-007-1, ISBN 0-87411-487-X.
  • Skinner, B.F. (1948) Walden Two. ISBN 0-02-411510-X.
  • Skinner, B.F. (1953) Science and Human Behavior, ISBN 0-02-929040-6.
  • Skinner, B.F. with C. B. Ferster, (1957) Schedules of Reinforcement, ISBN 0-13-792309-0.
  • Skinner, B.F. (1957) Verbal Behavior, ISBN 1-58390-021-7.