Jump to content

Furniss v Dawson: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Tim! (talk | contribs)
m Removed category 1984 in law; Quick-adding category 1984 in case law (using HotCat)
m Arguments: rm bullets & indentation
Line 19: Line 19:


==Arguments==
==Arguments==
* The Dawsons argued:
The Dawsons argued:
:# that the CGT rule mentioned above worked in their favour and they could not be taxed until such time (if ever) as they sold their shares in Greenjacket Investments Ltd.; and
# that the CGT rule mentioned above worked in their favour and they could not be taxed until such time (if ever) as they sold their shares in Greenjacket Investments Ltd.; and
:# that the Ramsay Principle did not apply, since what they had done had "real" enduring consequences.
# that the Ramsay Principle did not apply, since what they had done had "real" enduring consequences.
* The tax authorities argued:
The tax authorities argued:
:# that Greenjacket Investments Ltd. only existed as a vehicle to create a tax saving;
# that Greenjacket Investments Ltd. only existed as a vehicle to create a tax saving;
:# that the ''effect'' of the transaction as a whole was that the Dawsons had sold the operating companies to Wood Bairstow Holdings Ltd.;
# that the ''effect'' of the transaction as a whole was that the Dawsons had sold the operating companies to Wood Bairstow Holdings Ltd.;
:# that because the intervening stages of the transaction had only been inserted to generate a tax saving, they were to be ignored under the Ramsay Principle, and instead the ''effect'' of the transaction should be taxed; and
# that because the intervening stages of the transaction had only been inserted to generate a tax saving, they were to be ignored under the Ramsay Principle, and instead the ''effect'' of the transaction should be taxed; and
:# that the transaction being "real" (which is to say, not a [[sham]]) was not enough to save it from falling within the Ramsay Principle.
# that the transaction being "real" (which is to say, not a [[sham]]) was not enough to save it from falling within the Ramsay Principle.
* The Court of Appeal had given a judgement agreeing with the Dawsons on these points.
The Court of Appeal had given a judgement agreeing with the Dawsons on these points.


==The Decision==
==The Decision==

Revision as of 21:49, 26 June 2010

Furniss v. Dawson is an important House of Lords case in the field of UK tax. Its full name is "Furniss (Inspector of Taxes) v. Dawson D.E.R., Furniss (Inspector of Taxes) v. Dawson G.E., Murdoch (Inspector of Taxes) v. Dawson R.S.", and its citation is [1984] A.C. 474, or alternatively [1984] 2 W.L.R. 226.

The Ramsay Principle

See main article at The Ramsay Principle.

The most important background to Furniss v. Dawson was the decision of the House of Lords a few years earlier in W. T. Ramsay Ltd. v. Inland Revenue Commissioners [1982] A. C. 300. In the Ramsay case, a company which had made a substantial capital gain had entered into a complex and self-cancelling series of transactions which had generated an artificial capital loss. The House of Lords decided that where a transaction has pre-arranged artificial steps which serve no commercial purpose other than to save tax, then the proper approach is to tax the effect of the transaction as a whole.

Facts of the Case

The facts of the case are of less significance than the general principle which arose from it. However, in summary, they are:

  • The three respondents, the Dawsons, were a father and his two sons. They owned two successful clothing companies called Fordham and Burton Ltd. and Kirkby Garments Ltd. (which are together called "the operating companies" throughout the case).
  • A company called Wood Bairstow Holdings Ltd. offered to buy the operating companies from the Dawsons, and a price was agreed.
  • If the Dawsons had sold the operating companies direct to Wood Bairstow the Dawsons would have had to pay substantial capital gains tax ("CGT").
  • There was a rule that if a person sold his shares in Company A to Company B, and instead of receiving cash he received shares in Company B, then there was no CGT payable immediately. Instead, CGT would become payable when (if ever) that person later sold his shares in company B.
  • With the intention of taking advantage of this rule to delay the payment of CGT, the Dawsons arranged for an Isle of Man company called Greenjacket Investments Ltd. to be formed. (It was intended to become "Company B".)
  • The Dawsons sold the operating companies to Greenjacket Investments Ltd. in exchange for the shares of Greenjacket Investments Ltd.
  • Greenjacket Investments Ltd. sold the operating companies to Wood Bairstow Holdings Ltd.

Arguments

The Dawsons argued:

  1. that the CGT rule mentioned above worked in their favour and they could not be taxed until such time (if ever) as they sold their shares in Greenjacket Investments Ltd.; and
  2. that the Ramsay Principle did not apply, since what they had done had "real" enduring consequences.

The tax authorities argued:

  1. that Greenjacket Investments Ltd. only existed as a vehicle to create a tax saving;
  2. that the effect of the transaction as a whole was that the Dawsons had sold the operating companies to Wood Bairstow Holdings Ltd.;
  3. that because the intervening stages of the transaction had only been inserted to generate a tax saving, they were to be ignored under the Ramsay Principle, and instead the effect of the transaction should be taxed; and
  4. that the transaction being "real" (which is to say, not a sham) was not enough to save it from falling within the Ramsay Principle.

The Court of Appeal had given a judgement agreeing with the Dawsons on these points.

The Decision

The judgement of the court was given by Lord Brightman. The other four judges (Lord Fraser of Tullybelton, Lord Scarman, Lord Roskill and Lord Bridge of Harwich) gave shorter judgements agreeing with Lord Brightman's more detailed judgement.

The court decided in favour of the Inland Revenue (as it then was: it is now HM Revenue and Customs).

The judgement can be viewed as a battle between:

two conflicting ideas which could, at their extremes, be expressed as:

  • a rule that any taxpayer may organise his affairs in any way he wishes (provided it is legal) so as to minimise tax (Westminster) and
  • a rule that a taxpayer will be taxed on the effect of his transactions, not upon the way he has chosen to organise them for tax purposes (Ramsay).

Lord Brightman came down firmly in favour of an extension of the Ramsay Principle. He said that the appeal court judge (Oliver L. J.), by finding for the Dawsons and favouring the Westminster rule, had wrongly limited the Ramsay Principle (as it had been expressed by Lord Diplock in a case called IRC v. Burmah Oil Co. Ltd.). Lord Brightman said:

The effect of his [Oliver L. J.'s] judgment was to change Lord Diplock's formulation from "a pre-ordained series of transactions ... into which there are inserted steps that have no commercial purpose apart from the avoidance of a liability to tax" to "a pre-ordained series of transactions ... into which there are inserted steps that have no enduring legal consequences." That would confine the Ramsay principle to so-called self-cancelling transactions.

Oliver L. J. had given considerable weight to the fact that the existence of Greenjacket Investments Ltd. was real and had enduring consequences. At the end of the transaction, the Dawsons did not own the money which had been paid by Wood Bairstow Ltd.: instead, Greenjacket Investments Ltd. owned that money and the Dawsons owned Greenjacket Investments Limited. Legally speaking, those are two very different situations. However Lord Brightman saw this as irrelevant. In any case where a predetermined series of transactions contains steps which are only there for the purpose of avoiding tax, the tax is to be calculated on the effect of the composite transaction as a whole.

Consequences

Furniss v. Dawson has had far-reaching consequences. It applies not only to capital gains tax but to all forms of direct taxation. It also applies in most jurisdictions where decisions of the English courts have precedential value, including many of the offshore financial centres.