Too big to fail: Difference between revisions
m Date maintenance tags and general fixes: build 562: |
|||
Line 54: | Line 54: | ||
| publisher=U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Congress, 2nd Session, 18–19 September and 4 October |
| publisher=U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Congress, 2nd Session, 18–19 September and 4 October |
||
| pages= 98–111 |
| pages= 98–111 |
||
| postscript=. }}</ref> Regulatory agencies ([[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation|FDIC]], [[Office of the Comptroller of the Currency]], the [[Federal Reserve System|Fed]], etc.) feared this may cause widespread financial complications and a major [[bank run]] that may easily spread by financial contagion. The implicit guarantee of too-big-to-fail has been criticized by many since then for its preferential treatment of large banks{{Citation needed|date=July 2008}}. Simultaneously, the perception of too-big-to-fail may diminish healthy [[market discipline]], and may have influenced the decisions behind insolvency of |
| postscript=. }}</ref> Regulatory agencies ([[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation|FDIC]], [[Office of the Comptroller of the Currency]], the [[Federal Reserve System|Fed]], etc.) feared this may cause widespread financial complications and a major [[bank run]] that may easily spread by financial contagion. The implicit guarantee of too-big-to-fail has been criticized by many since then for its preferential treatment of large banks{{Citation needed|date=July 2008}}. Simultaneously, the perception of too-big-to-fail may diminish healthy [[market discipline]], and may have influenced the decisions behind the insolvency of [[Washington Mutual]] in 2008. For example, large depositors in banks not covered by the policy tend to have a strong incentive to monitor the bank's financial condition, and/or withdraw in case the bank's policies exposes them to high risks, since FDIC guarantees have an upper limit. However, large depositors in a "too big to fail" bank would have less incentive, since they'd expect to be bailed out in the event of failure. |
||
The [[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991|Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act]] was passed in 1991, giving the FDIC the responsibility to rescue an insolvent bank by the least costly method. The Act had the implicit goal of eliminating the widespread belief among depositors that a loss of depositors and bondholders will be prevented for large banks. However, the Act included an exception in cases of systemic risk, subject to the approval of two-thirds of the FDIC Board of Directors, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, and the Treasury Secretary.<ref>{{Cite news |
The [[Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991|Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act]] was passed in 1991, giving the FDIC the responsibility to rescue an insolvent bank by the least costly method. The Act had the implicit goal of eliminating the widespread belief among depositors that a loss of depositors and bondholders will be prevented for large banks. However, the Act included an exception in cases of systemic risk, subject to the approval of two-thirds of the FDIC Board of Directors, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, and the Treasury Secretary.<ref>{{Cite news |
Revision as of 08:03, 15 November 2010
"Too big to fail" is a term of art in regulation and public policy that refers to businesses dealing with market complications related to moral hazard, economic specialization, and monetary theory.
Entities are considered to be "too big to fail" by those who believe those entities are so central to a macroeconomy that their failure will be disastrous to an economy, and as such believe they should become recipients of beneficial financial and economic policies from governments and/or central banks.[1] It is thought that companies that fall into this category take positions that are high-risk, as they are able to leverage these risks based on the policy preference they receive.[2] The term has emerged as prominent in public discourse since the 2007–2010 global financial crisis.
Some critics see the policy as counterproductive and that large banks or other institutions should be left to fail if their risk management is not effective.[3][4] Moreover, some assert that the "too big to fail" policy has been explicitly refuted in the People's Republic of China, with the bankruptcy of Guangdong International Trust & Investment Corporation in 1998.[5]
Some economists, such as Nobel Laureate Paul Krugman don't see it as necessarily a bad thing, with economy of scale in banks, as in other businesses, as worth preserving, so long as they are well regulated, in proportion to their economic clout.[6][7][8][9]
Regulatory basis
Before 1950, U.S. federal bank regulators had essentially two options for resolving an insolvent institution: closure, with liquidation of assets and payouts for insured depositors, or purchase and assumption, encouraging the acquisition of assets and assumption of liabilities by another firm. A third option was made available by the Federal Deposit Insurance Act of 1950: providing assistance, the power to support an institution through loans or direct federal acquisition of assets, until it could recover from its distress. The statute limited the "assistance" option to cases where "continued operation of the bank is essential to provide adequate banking service." Regulators shunned this third option for many years, fearing that if regionally- or nationally-important banks were thought to be generally immune to liquidation, markets in their shares would be distorted. Thus the assistance option was never employed during the period 1950-1969, and very seldom thereafter.[10]
Continental Illinois case
Distress
The Continental Illinois National Bank and Trust Company experienced a fall in its overall asset quality during the early 1980s. Tight money, Mexico's default and plunging oil prices followed a period when the bank had aggressively pursued commercial lending business, Latin American syndicated loan business, and loan participations in the energy sector. Complicating matters further, the bank's funding mix was heavily dependent on large CDs and foreign money markets, which meant its depositors were more risk-averse than average retail depositors in the US.
Payments crisis
The bank held significant participation in highly-speculative oil and gas loans of Oklahoma's Penn Square Bank. When Penn Square failed in July 1982, the Continental's distress became acute, culminating with press rumors of failure and an investor-and-depositor run in early May 1984. In the first week of the run, the Fed permitted the Continental Illinois discount window credits on the order of $3.6 billion. Still in significant distress, the management obtained a further $4.5 billion in credits from a syndicate of money center banks the following week. These measures failed to stop the run, and regulators were confronted with a crisis.
Regulatory crisis
The seventh-largest bank in the nation by deposits would very shortly be unable to meet its obligations. Regulators faced a tough decision about how to resolve the matter. Of the three options available, only two were seriously considered. Even banks much smaller than the Continental were deemed unsuitable for resolution by liquidation, owing to the disruptions this would have inevitably caused. The normal course would be to seek a purchaser (and indeed press accounts that such a search was underway contributed to Continental depositors' fears in 1984). However, in the tight-money financial climate of the early 1980s, no purchaser was forthcoming.
Besides generic concerns of size, contagion of depositor panic and bank distress, regulators feared the significant disruption of national payment and settlement systems. Of special concern was the wide network of correspondent banks with high percentages of their capital invested in the Continental Illinois. Essentially, the bank was deemed "too big to fail," and the "provide assistance" option was reluctantly taken. The dilemma now became, how to provide assistance without significantly unbalancing the nation's banking system?
Stopping the run
To prevent immediate failure, the Federal Reserve announced categorically that it would meet any liquidity needs the Continental might have, while FDIC gave depositors and general creditors a full guarantee (not subject to the $100,000 FDIC deposit-insurance limit) and provided direct assistance of $2 billion (including participations). Money center banks assembled an additional $5.3 billion unsecured facility pending a resolution and resumption of more-normal business. These measures slowed, but did not stop, the outflow of deposits.
Controversy
In a United States Senate hearing afterwards, the then Comptroller of the Currency C. T. Conover defended his position by admitting the regulators will not let the largest 11 banks fail.[11] Regulatory agencies (FDIC, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, the Fed, etc.) feared this may cause widespread financial complications and a major bank run that may easily spread by financial contagion. The implicit guarantee of too-big-to-fail has been criticized by many since then for its preferential treatment of large banks[citation needed]. Simultaneously, the perception of too-big-to-fail may diminish healthy market discipline, and may have influenced the decisions behind the insolvency of Washington Mutual in 2008. For example, large depositors in banks not covered by the policy tend to have a strong incentive to monitor the bank's financial condition, and/or withdraw in case the bank's policies exposes them to high risks, since FDIC guarantees have an upper limit. However, large depositors in a "too big to fail" bank would have less incentive, since they'd expect to be bailed out in the event of failure.
The Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act was passed in 1991, giving the FDIC the responsibility to rescue an insolvent bank by the least costly method. The Act had the implicit goal of eliminating the widespread belief among depositors that a loss of depositors and bondholders will be prevented for large banks. However, the Act included an exception in cases of systemic risk, subject to the approval of two-thirds of the FDIC Board of Directors, the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, and the Treasury Secretary.[12]
Effect on banks' cost of capital
Since the full amount of the deposits and debts of "too big to fail" banks are effectively guaranteed by the government, large depositors view deposits with these banks as a safer investment than deposits with smaller banks. Therefore, large banks are able to pay lower interest rates to depositors than small banks are obliged to pay. In October 2009, Sheila Bair, the current Chairperson of the FDIC, commented that "'Too big to fail' has become worse. It's become explicit when it was implicit before. It creates competitive disparities between large and small institutions, because everybody knows small institutions can fail. So it's more expensive for them to raise capital and secure funding.".[13] A study conducted by the Center for Economic and Policy Research found that the difference between the cost of funds for banks with more than $100 billion in assets and the cost of funds for smaller banks widened dramatically after the formalization of the "too big to fail" policy in the U.S. in the fourth quarter of 2008.[14] This shift in the large banks' cost of funds gave an indirect "too big to fail" subsidy of $34.1 billion per year to the 18 U.S. banks with more than $100 billion in assets.
"Too big to fail is too big"
Mervyn King, the governor of the Bank of England, called for banks that are "too big to fail" to be cut down to size, as a solution to the problem of banks having taxpayer-funded guarantees for their speculative investment banking activities. "If some banks are thought to be too big to fail, then, in the words of a distinguished American economist, they are too big. It is not sensible to allow large banks to combine high street retail banking with risky investment banking or funding strategies, and then provide an implicit state guarantee against failure."[15] However, Alistair Darling disagreed; "Many people talk about how to deal with the big banks – banks so important to the financial system that they cannot be allowed to fail. But the solution is not as simple, as some have suggested, as restricting the size of the banks".[15] As well, Alan Greenspan said that “If they’re too big to fail, they’re too big,” suggesting U.S. regulators to consider breaking up large financial institutions considered “too big to fail.” He added, “I don’t think merely raising the fees or capital on large institutions or taxing them is enough ... they’ll absorb that, they’ll work with that, and it’s totally inefficient and they’ll still be using the savings.”[16]
Too big to fail tax
Willem Buiter proposes a tax to internalize the massive external costs inflicted by "too big to fail" institution. "When size creates externalities, do what you would do with any negative externality: tax it. The other way to limit size is to tax size. This can be done through capital requirements that are progressive in the size of the business (as measured by value added, the size of the balance sheet or some other metric). Such measures for preventing the New Darwinism of the survival of the fattest and the politically best connected should be distinguished from regulatory interventions based on the narrow leverage ratio aimed at regulating risk (regardless of size, except for a de minimis lower limit)."[17]
See also
- Greenspan put
- Lender of last resort
- List of largest U.S. bank failures
- 2008-2009 bank failures in the United States
- List of acquired or bankrupt United States banks in the late 2000s financial crisis
- Volcker Rule
Notes
- ^ http://www.businessdictionary.com/definition/too-big-to-fail.html
- ^ Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond Economic Quarterly Volume 91/2 Spring 2005 by Ennis, Huberto M.; Malek, H.S
- ^ Alton E. Drew, The Business Week, http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/content/feb2009/db20090218_166676.htm retrieved on March 20, 2009
- ^ Benton E. Gup, ed. (2003-12-30). Too Big to Fail: Policies and Practices in Government Bailouts. Westport, Connecticut: Praeger Publishers. p. 368. doi:10.1336/1567206212. ISBN 1-567-20621-2. OCLC 52288783. Retrieved 2008-02-20.
The doctrine of laissez-faire seemingly has been revitalized as Republican and Democratic administrations alike now profess their firm commitment to policies of deregulation and freemarkets in the new global economy. -- Usually associated with large bank failures, the phrase too big to fail, which is a particular form of government bailout, actually applies to a wide range of industries, as this volume makes clear. Examples range from Chrysler to Lockheed Aircraft and from New York City to Penn Central Railroad. Generally speaking, when a corporation, an organization, or an industry sector is considered by the government to be too important to the overall health of the economy, it will not be allowed to fail. Government bailouts are not new, nor are they limited to the United States. This book presents the views of academics, practitioners, and regulators from around the world (e.g., Australia, Hungary, Japan, Europe, and Latin America) on the implications and consequences of government bailouts.
{{cite book}}
: Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help) - ^ Chang, T.K. (2001-01-12). "Ten Lessons of the GITIC Bankruptcy". Asian Wall Street Journal. Retrieved 2009-08-01.
- ^ Paul Krugman "Financial Reform 101" April 1, 2010
- ^ Paul Krugman "Stop 'Stop Too Big To Fail'." April 21, 2010
- ^ Paul Krugman "Too big to fail FAIL" June 18, 2009
- ^ Paul Krugman "A bit more on too big to fail and related" June 19, 2009
- ^ http://marriottschool.byu.edu/emp/HBH/mba624/Commercial%20Banking%20Regulation.pdf Heaton, Hal B., Riegger, Christopher. "Commercial Banking Regulation", Class discussion notes.
- ^ Conover, Charles (1984). "Testimony". Inquiry Into the Continental Illinois Corp. and Continental National Bank: Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Financial Institutions Supervision, Regulation, and Insurance of the Committee on Banking, Finance, and Urban Affairs. U.S. House of Representatives, 98th Congress, 2nd Session, 18–19 September and 4 October. pp. 98–111.
{{cite book}}
: CS1 maint: postscript (link) - ^ Bradley, Christine; Craig, Valentine V. (2007). "Privatizing Deposit Insurance: Results of the 2006 FDIC Study" (PDF). FDIC Quarterly. Vol. 1, no. 2. pp. 23–32.
{{cite news}}
: CS1 maint: postscript (link) - ^ Wiseman, Paul (2009-10-19). "FDIC chief: Small banks can't compete with bailed-out giants". USA Today. Retrieved 2009-10-22.
{{cite news}}
: Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help) - ^ Baker, Dean (2009). "The Value of the 'Too Big to Fail' Big Bank Subsidy". Center for Economic and Policy Research Issue Brief. Retrieved 2009-10-22.
{{cite web}}
: Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help); Unknown parameter|month=
ignored (help) - ^ a b Treanor, Jill (2009-06-17). "King calls for banks to be 'cut down to size'". The Guardian. Retrieved 2009-06-18.
{{cite news}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameter:|coauthors=
(help) - ^ "Greenspan Says U.S. Should Consider Breaking Up Large Banks". Bloomberg. 2009-10-12. Retrieved 2010-02-05.
- ^ Buiter, Willem (June 24, 2009). "Too big to fail is too big". The Financial Times. Retrieved 2009-11-22.
{{cite news}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameter:|coauthors=
(help)
Further reading
- "Carping about the TARP: Congress wrangles over how best to avoid financial Armageddon". The Economist. 2008-09-23.
{{cite news}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameter:|coauthors=
(help); Unknown parameter|curly=
ignored (help) - Kaufman, George G. (1990). "Are Some Banks Too Large to Fail? Myth and Reality". Contemporary Economic Policy. 8 (4): 1–14. doi:10.1111/j.1465-7287.1990.tb00298.x.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameters:|month=
and|coauthors=
(help)CS1 maint: postscript (link) - Mishkin, Frederic S. (2006). "How Big a Problem is Too Big to Fail? A Review of Gary Stern and Ron Feldman's Too Big to Fail: The Hazards of Bank Bailouts". Journal of Economic Literature. 44 (4): 988–1004. doi:10.1257/002205106779436233.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameters:|month=
and|coauthors=
(help)CS1 maint: postscript (link) - O'Hara, Maureen (1990). "Deposit Insurance and Wealth Effects: The Value of Being 'Too Big to Fail'". Journal of Finance. 45 (5). American Finance Association: 1587–1600. doi:10.2307/2328751.
{{cite journal}}
: Cite has empty unknown parameter:|month=
(help); Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help)CS1 maint: postscript (link) - Stern, Gary H. (2004). Too Big to Fail: The Hazards of Bank Bailouts. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution Press. ISBN 0815781520.
{{cite book}}
: Unknown parameter|coauthors=
ignored (|author=
suggested) (help) - Moseley, Fred (January/February 2009). "Time for Permanent Nationalization". Dollars & Sense. Retrieved 2009-02-25.
{{cite news}}
: Check date values in:|date=
(help); Cite has empty unknown parameter:|coauthors=
(help); Unknown parameter|curly=
ignored (help)