Revealed preference: Difference between revisions
Kaustubh85 (talk | contribs) No edit summary |
|||
Line 1: | Line 1: | ||
'''Revealed preference theory''', pioneered by [[United States|American]] [[economist]] [[Paul Samuelson]], is a method by which it is possible to discern the best possible option on the basis of [[consumer behavior]]. Essentially, this means that the [[preference]]s of consumers can be revealed by their purchasing habits. Revealed preference theory came about because the theories of consumer [[demand]] were based on a diminishing [[marginal rate of substitution]] (MRS). This diminishing MRS is based on the assumption that consumers make consumption decisions based on their intent to maximize their utility. While [[utility]] maximization was not a controversial assumption, the [[Consumer theory|underlying utility functions]] could not be measured with great certainty. Revealed preference theory was a means to reconcile demand theory by creating a means to define utility functions by observing behavior. |
'''Revealed preference theory''', pioneered by [[United States|American]] [[economist]] [[Paul Samuelson]], is a method by which it is possible to discern the best possible option on the basis of [[consumer behavior]]. Essentially, this means that the [[preference]]s of consumers can be revealed by their purchasing habits. Revealed preference theory came about because the theories of consumer [[demand]] were based on a diminishing [[marginal rate of substitution]] (MRS). This diminishing MRS is based on the assumption that consumers make consumption decisions based on their intent to maximize their utility. While [[utility]] maximization was not a controversial assumption, the [[Consumer theory|underlying utility functions]] could not be measured with great certainty. Revealed preference theory was a means to reconcile demand theory by creating a means to define utility functions by observing behavior. |
||
==Theory==The revealed preference theory is understanding the preferences of a consumer among the bundle of goods available to him, given the budget constraint. For instance the bundle of goods available to a consumer are bundle of goods 'A' and bundle of goods 'B' if the consumer buys the bundle of goods 'A' over the bundle of goods 'B' where both the bundles of goods are affordable within the budget constraint and income level it is said that, goods 'A' bundle is directly revealed preferred over bundle of goods 'B'. It is hypothetically assumed that the consumer's preferences are stable over the period of time for which we observe the behaviour of the consumer or in other words the consumer will not choose bundle of goods "A" over bundle "B" at one time and bundle of goods "B" over bundle of goods "A" the other time in a situation where both the bundles are present. Another example being if a person chooses a certain bundle of goods (ex. 2 apples, 3 bananas) while another bundle of goods is affordable (ex. 3 apples, 2 bananas), then we say that the first bundle is revealed preferred to the second. It is then assumed that the first bundle of goods is always preferred to the second. This means that if the consumer ever purchases the second bundle of goods then it is assumed that the first bundle is unaffordable. This ''implies'' that preferences are [[transitive relation|transitive]]. In other words if we have bundles A, B, C, ...., Z, and A is revealed preferred to B which is revealed preferred to C and so on then it is concluded that A is revealed preferred to C through Z. With this theory economists can chart [[indifference curves]] which adhere to already developed models of consumer theory.===Algebric Analysis===Let there be 2 bundles of goods (x1,x2) and (y1,y2) available at price (p1,p2),assuming that the consumer has an income 'm'. It is observed that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods.To translate this arithematically following equation is formulated p1y1+p2y2<m or p1y1+p2y2=mThe above equation indicates that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) satisfies the budget constraint or in other words (y1,y2) is affordable by the consumer.But it is already stated that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods,which implies p1x1+p2x2=mthe above equation also satisfies the condition of the bundle of goods being affordable within the budget constraint and in this case it satisfies the condition with equality.Now, putting the above equations together, knowning that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) was affordable at the given budget constraint(p1,p2,m) the consumer bought (x1,x2) bundle of goods , thus the final equation of revealed preference is as stated below p1x1+p2x2>p1y1+p2y2 from the preceding equation we derive that the ,consumer prefers bundle of goods (x1,x2) over bundle of goods (y1,y2) or we can say that bundle of goods (x1,x2) is directly revealed preferred to (y1,y2). <ref>{{cite book|isbn=81-7671-058-X}}</ref>===The weak axiom of revealed preference===The ''weak axiom of revealed preference'' (WARP) is a characteristic on the choice behavior of an economic agent.The weak axiom of revealed preference states that if a consumer prefers bundle of good "A" over bundle of good "B" it will never happen so that in any situation where ,both "A" and "B" are present the consumer chooses bundle of good "B", we can also say that when good"A" is revealed prefered to good "B" good "B" will never be revealed prefered to good "A". For example, if an individual chooses orange out of a set of options including apple, they should never choose apple when faced with a choice of a different set of options which also includes orange and apple. More formally, if Apple is ever chosen when orange is available, then there can be no set containing both alternatives from which apple is chosen and orange is not. These two definitions however do not state the same necessary restrictions to satisfy WARP. The former prohibits ever choosing apple after orange was once chosen over aaple. The latter (and weaker rectriction) only requires to choose orange as well, if apple were to be chosen out of several choices.This characteristic can be stated as a characteristic of [[Marshallian demand function|Walrasian demand functions]] as seen in the following example. Let p<sub>a</sub> be the price of apples and p<sub>b</sub> be the price of bananas, and let the amount of money available be m=5. If p<sub>a </sub>=1 and p<sub>b</sub>=1, and if the bundle (2,3) is chosen, it is said that the bundle (2,3) is ''revealed preferred'' to (3,2), as the latter bundle could have been chosen as well at the given prices. More formally, assume a consumer has a demand function x such that they choose bundles x(p,w) and x(p',w') when faced with price-wealth situations (p,w) and (p',w') respectively. If p·x(p',w') ≤ w then the consumer chooses x(p,w) even when x(p',w') was available under prices p at wealth w, so x(p,w) must be preferred to x(p',w').===The strong axiom of revealed preference===The ''strong axiom of revealed preference'' (SARP) is an expansion of the concept of the weak axiom. A choice behavior that satisfies the weak axiom can form circles. That is if A is preferred to B and B to C then under the weak axiom it is possible that C is preferred to A. The strong axiom makes this behavior impossible, as it is the same as weak axiom plus the requirement that circles are not possible. (In two dimensions WARP=SARP). |
|||
==Theory== |
|||
The revealed preference theory is understanding the preferences of a consumer among the bundle of goods available to him, given the budget constraint. For instance the bundle of goods available to a consumer are bundle of goods 'A' and bundle of goods 'B' if the consumer buys the bundle of goods 'A' over the bundle of goods 'B' where both the bundles of goods are affordable within the budget constraint it is said that, goods 'A' bundle is directly revealed preferred over bundle of goods 'B'. It is hypothetically assumed that the consumer's preferences are stable over the period of time for which we observe the behaviour of the consumer. Another example being if a person chooses a certain bundle of goods (ex. 2 apples, 3 bananas) while another bundle of goods is affordable (ex. 3 apples, 2 bananas), then we say that the first bundle is revealed preferred to the second. It is then assumed that the first bundle of goods is always preferred to the second. This means that if the consumer ever purchases the second bundle of goods then it is assumed that the first bundle is unaffordable. This ''implies'' that preferences are [[transitive relation|transitive]]. In other words if we have bundles A, B, C, ...., Z, and A is revealed preferred to B which is revealed preferred to C and so on then it is concluded that A is revealed preferred to C through Z. With this theory economists can chart [[indifference curves]] which adhere to already developed models of consumer theory. |
|||
===Algebric Analysis=== |
|||
Let there be 2 bundles of goods (x1,x2) and (y1,y2) available at price (p1,p2),assuming that the consumer has an income 'm'. It is observed that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods.To translate this arithematically following equation is formulated |
|||
p1y1+p2y2<m or p1y1+p2y2=m |
|||
The above equation indicates that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) satisfies the budget constraint or in other words (y1,y2) is affordable by the consumer. |
|||
But it is already stated that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods,which implies |
|||
p1x1+p2x2=m |
|||
the above equation also satisfies the condition of the bundle of goods being affordable within the budget constraint and in this case it satisfies the condition with equality. |
|||
Now, putting the above equations together, knowning that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) was affordable at the given budget constraint(p1,p2,m) the consumer bought (x1,x2) bundle of goods , thus the final equation of revealed preference is as stated below |
|||
p1x1+p2x2>p1y1+p2y2 |
|||
from the preceding equation we derive that the ,consumer prefers bundle of goods (x1,x2) over bundle of goods (y1,y2) or we can say that bundle of goods (x1,x2) is directly revealed preferred to (y1,y2). <ref>{{cite book|isbn=81-7671-058-X}}</ref> |
|||
===The weak axiom of revealed preference=== |
|||
The ''weak axiom of revealed preference'' (WARP) is a characteristic on the choice behavior of an economic agent. For example, if an individual chooses A out of a set of options including B, they should never choose B when faced with a choice of a different set of options which also includes A and B. More formally, if A is ever chosen when B is available, then there can be no set containing both alternatives from which B is chosen and A is not. These two definitions however do not state the same necessary restrictions to satisfy WARP. The former prohibits ever choosing B after A was once chosen over B. The latter (and weaker rectriction) only requires to choose A as well, if B were to be chosen out of several choices. |
|||
This characteristic can be stated as a characteristic of [[Marshallian demand function|Walrasian demand functions]] as seen in the following example. Let p<sub>a</sub> be the price of apples and p<sub>b</sub> be the price of bananas, and let the amount of money available be m=5. If p<sub>a </sub>=1 and p<sub>b</sub>=1, and if the bundle (2,3) is chosen, it is said that the bundle (2,3) is ''revealed preferred'' to (3,2), as the latter bundle could have been chosen as well at the given prices. More formally, assume a consumer has a demand function x such that they choose bundles x(p,w) and x(p',w') when faced with price-wealth situations (p,w) and (p',w') respectively. If p·x(p',w') ≤ w then the consumer chooses x(p,w) even when x(p',w') was available under prices p at wealth w, so x(p,w) must be preferred to x(p',w'). |
|||
===The strong axiom of revealed preference=== |
|||
The ''strong axiom of revealed preference'' (SARP) is an expansion of the concept of the weak axiom. A choice behavior that satisfies the weak axiom can form circles. That is if A is preferred to B and B to C then under the weak axiom it is possible that C is preferred to A. The strong axiom makes this behavior impossible, as it is the same as weak axiom plus the requirement that circles are not possible. (In two dimensions WARP=SARP). |
|||
==Criticism== |
==Criticism== |
Revision as of 15:56, 24 September 2011
Revealed preference theory, pioneered by American economist Paul Samuelson, is a method by which it is possible to discern the best possible option on the basis of consumer behavior. Essentially, this means that the preferences of consumers can be revealed by their purchasing habits. Revealed preference theory came about because the theories of consumer demand were based on a diminishing marginal rate of substitution (MRS). This diminishing MRS is based on the assumption that consumers make consumption decisions based on their intent to maximize their utility. While utility maximization was not a controversial assumption, the underlying utility functions could not be measured with great certainty. Revealed preference theory was a means to reconcile demand theory by creating a means to define utility functions by observing behavior.
==Theory==The revealed preference theory is understanding the preferences of a consumer among the bundle of goods available to him, given the budget constraint. For instance the bundle of goods available to a consumer are bundle of goods 'A' and bundle of goods 'B' if the consumer buys the bundle of goods 'A' over the bundle of goods 'B' where both the bundles of goods are affordable within the budget constraint and income level it is said that, goods 'A' bundle is directly revealed preferred over bundle of goods 'B'. It is hypothetically assumed that the consumer's preferences are stable over the period of time for which we observe the behaviour of the consumer or in other words the consumer will not choose bundle of goods "A" over bundle "B" at one time and bundle of goods "B" over bundle of goods "A" the other time in a situation where both the bundles are present. Another example being if a person chooses a certain bundle of goods (ex. 2 apples, 3 bananas) while another bundle of goods is affordable (ex. 3 apples, 2 bananas), then we say that the first bundle is revealed preferred to the second. It is then assumed that the first bundle of goods is always preferred to the second. This means that if the consumer ever purchases the second bundle of goods then it is assumed that the first bundle is unaffordable. This implies that preferences are transitive. In other words if we have bundles A, B, C, ...., Z, and A is revealed preferred to B which is revealed preferred to C and so on then it is concluded that A is revealed preferred to C through Z. With this theory economists can chart indifference curves which adhere to already developed models of consumer theory.===Algebric Analysis===Let there be 2 bundles of goods (x1,x2) and (y1,y2) available at price (p1,p2),assuming that the consumer has an income 'm'. It is observed that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods.To translate this arithematically following equation is formulated p1y1+p2y2<m or p1y1+p2y2=mThe above equation indicates that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) satisfies the budget constraint or in other words (y1,y2) is affordable by the consumer.But it is already stated that the consumer buys (x1,x2) bundle of goods,which implies p1x1+p2x2=mthe above equation also satisfies the condition of the bundle of goods being affordable within the budget constraint and in this case it satisfies the condition with equality.Now, putting the above equations together, knowning that the bundle of goods (y1,y2) was affordable at the given budget constraint(p1,p2,m) the consumer bought (x1,x2) bundle of goods , thus the final equation of revealed preference is as stated below p1x1+p2x2>p1y1+p2y2 from the preceding equation we derive that the ,consumer prefers bundle of goods (x1,x2) over bundle of goods (y1,y2) or we can say that bundle of goods (x1,x2) is directly revealed preferred to (y1,y2). [1]===The weak axiom of revealed preference===The weak axiom of revealed preference (WARP) is a characteristic on the choice behavior of an economic agent.The weak axiom of revealed preference states that if a consumer prefers bundle of good "A" over bundle of good "B" it will never happen so that in any situation where ,both "A" and "B" are present the consumer chooses bundle of good "B", we can also say that when good"A" is revealed prefered to good "B" good "B" will never be revealed prefered to good "A". For example, if an individual chooses orange out of a set of options including apple, they should never choose apple when faced with a choice of a different set of options which also includes orange and apple. More formally, if Apple is ever chosen when orange is available, then there can be no set containing both alternatives from which apple is chosen and orange is not. These two definitions however do not state the same necessary restrictions to satisfy WARP. The former prohibits ever choosing apple after orange was once chosen over aaple. The latter (and weaker rectriction) only requires to choose orange as well, if apple were to be chosen out of several choices.This characteristic can be stated as a characteristic of Walrasian demand functions as seen in the following example. Let pa be the price of apples and pb be the price of bananas, and let the amount of money available be m=5. If pa =1 and pb=1, and if the bundle (2,3) is chosen, it is said that the bundle (2,3) is revealed preferred to (3,2), as the latter bundle could have been chosen as well at the given prices. More formally, assume a consumer has a demand function x such that they choose bundles x(p,w) and x(p',w') when faced with price-wealth situations (p,w) and (p',w') respectively. If p·x(p',w') ≤ w then the consumer chooses x(p,w) even when x(p',w') was available under prices p at wealth w, so x(p,w) must be preferred to x(p',w').===The strong axiom of revealed preference===The strong axiom of revealed preference (SARP) is an expansion of the concept of the weak axiom. A choice behavior that satisfies the weak axiom can form circles. That is if A is preferred to B and B to C then under the weak axiom it is possible that C is preferred to A. The strong axiom makes this behavior impossible, as it is the same as weak axiom plus the requirement that circles are not possible. (In two dimensions WARP=SARP).
Criticism
Stanley Wong[2] argues that revealed preference theory is a failed research program. According to Wong, Samuelson's 1938 presented revealed preference theory as an alternative theory to utility theory, while in 1950, Samuelson took the demonstrated equivalence of the two theories as a vindication for his position, rather than as a refutation.
If there exist only an apple and an orange, and an orange is picked, then one can definitely say that an orange is revealed preferred to an apple. In the real world, when it is observed that a consumer purchased an orange, it is impossible to say what good or set of goods or behavioral options were discarded in preference of purchasing an orange. In this sense, preference is not revealed at all in the sense of ordinal utility.[3] One of the critics of the revealed preference theory states that "Instead of replacing 'metaphysical' terms such as 'desire' and 'purpose'" they "used it to legitimize them by giving them operational definitions." Thus in psychology, as in economics, the initial, quite radical operationalist ideas eventually came to serve as little more than a "reassurance fetish" [citation needed] for mainstream methodological practice."[4]
See also
- Conjoint analysis
- Hedonic regression
- Travel cost analysis
- Contingent valuation or stated preference methods
References
- ^ . ISBN 81-7671-058-X.
{{cite book}}
: Missing or empty|title=
(help) - ^ Stanley Wong, Foundations of Paul Samuelson's Revealed Preference Theory: A Study by the Method of Rational Reconstruction, Routledge (1978)
- ^ Koszegi, Botond; Rabin, Matthew (2007). "Mistakes in Choice-Based Welfare Analysis". American Economic Review. 97 (2): 477–481. JSTOR 30034498. Free version: [1]
- ^ Hands, D. Wade (2004). "On Operationalisms and Economics". Journal of Economic Issues. 38 (4): 953–968. JSTOR 4228082.
- Nicholson, W. (2005) Microeconomics, Thomson, Southwestern.
- Mas-Colell, A.; Whinston, M.D.; Green, J.R. (1995) "Microeconomic Theory", First Edition, New York: Oxford University Press, New York
- Samuelson, P. (1938). A Note on the Pure Theory of Consumers' Behaviour. Economica 5:61-71.
- Varian, H. (1992) Microeconomic Analysis, Third edition, New York: Norton, Section 8.7
External links
- Revealed Preference, review by Hal R. Varian, 2005, prepared for Samuelsonian Economics and the 21st Century.
- Lecture Notes in Microeconomic Theory, book by Ariel Rubinstein, 2005.