Jump to content

Austerity: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Line 132: Line 132:
[[Category:Fiscal policy]]
[[Category:Fiscal policy]]
[[Category:Public finance]]
[[Category:Public finance]]
[[Category:Feedback Article 5]]
[[Category:Feedback Articles 5]]
[[ar:تقشف]]
[[ar:تقشف]]
[[de:Austerität]]
[[de:Austerität]]

Revision as of 03:18, 19 October 2012

In economics, austerity refers to a policy of deficit-cutting by lowering spending via a reduction in the amount of benefits and public services provided.[1] Austerity policies are often used by governments to try to reduce their deficit spending[2] and are sometimes coupled with increases in taxes to demonstrate long-term fiscal solvency to creditors.[3]

Supporters of austerity predict that under expansionary fiscal contraction (EFC), a major reduction in government spending can change future expectations about taxes and government spending, encouraging private consumption and resulting in overall economic expansion.[4]

Critics argue that, in periods of recession and high unemployment, austerity policies are counter-productive, because: a) reduced government spending can increase unemployment, which increases safety net spending while reducing tax revenue; b) reduced government spending reduces GDP, which means the debt to GDP ratio examined by creditors and rating agencies does not improve; and c) short-term government spending financed by deficits supports economic growth when consumers and businesses are unwilling or unable to do so.[5]

Justifications

Austerity measures are typically taken if there is a threat that a government cannot honor its debt liabilities. Such a situation may arise if a government has borrowed in foreign currencies that they have no right to issue or they have been legally forbidden from issuing their own currency. In such a situation, banks and investors may lose trust in a government's ability and/or willingness to pay and either refuse to roll over existing debts or demand extremely high interest rates. In such situations, inter-governmental institutions such as the International Monetary Fund (IMF) may demand austerity measures in exchange for functioning as a lender of last resort. When the IMF requires such a policy, the terms are known as 'IMF conditionalities'.

In some cases, governments became highly indebted after assuming private debts following banking crises. For example, this occurred after Ireland assumed the debts of its private banking sector during the European sovereign debt crisis.[6]

Typical effects

Development projects, welfare, and other social spending are common programs that are targeted for cuts: Taxes, port and airport fees, train and bus fares are common sources of increased user fees. Retirement ages may be raised and government pensions reduced.

In many cases, austerity measures have been associated with protest movements claiming significant decline in standard of living. A representative example is the nation of Greece. The financial crisis—particularly the austerity package put forth by the EU and the IMF— was met with great anger by the Greek public, leading to riots and social unrest. On 27 June 2011, trade union organizations commenced a forty-eight hour labor strike in advance of a parliamentary vote on the austerity package, the first such strike since 1974. Massive demonstrations were organized throughout Greece, intended to pressure parliament members into voting against the package. The second set of austerity measures was approved on 29 June 2011, with 155 out of 300 members of parliament voting in favor. However, one United Nations official warned that the second package of austerity measures in Greece could pose a violation of human rights.[7]

Theoretical considerations

Keynesian viewpoint

John Maynard Keynes said in 1937: “The boom, not the slump, is the right time for austerity at the Treasury.” Contemporary Keynesian economists argue that budget deficits are appropriate when an economy is in recession, to reduce unemployment and help spur GDP growth.[8]

Economist Paul Krugman explained that a government is not like a household. Across an economy, one person's spending is another person's income. If everyone is trying to reduce their spending, the economy can be trapped in what economists call the paradox of thrift, worsening the recession as GDP falls. If the private sector is unable or unwilling to consume at a level that increases GDP and employment sufficiently, he argued the government should be spending more.[9]

Multiplier effects

Different revenue (tax) and spending choices of equal magnitude have different economic effects.[10][11] For example, the U.S. Congressional Budget Office estimated that the payroll tax (levied on all workers earning a wage) has a higher multiplier (impact on GDP) than the income tax (which is levied primarily on wealthier workers).[12] In other words, raising the payroll tax by $1 as part of an austerity strategy would slow the economy more than raising the income tax by $1, resulting in less net deficit reduction. In theory, it would be stimulative to the economy and reduce the deficit if the payroll tax were lowered and the income tax raised in equal amounts.[13]

Other views

Old-Keynesians, such as Alvin Hansen argued that government deficits provide the private sector both with new money for saving (the deficit) and a means to save (government interest-bearing bonds), increasing private sector wealth, and this wealth effect would reduce the need to save from current income. In their view government debt enabled the private sector to continue consuming. It was therefore not a burden, at least when held domestically, but a necessity.[14] This approach has interesting parallels with Richard Koo's recent concept of balance-sheet recession.

Contemporary mainstream economists[15] model macroeconomic policy in a dynamic stochastic general equilibrium (DSGE) framework, where fiscal policy is discussed within an optimal taxation framework that assumes a representative agent is optimizing over a long-term horizon. The reasoning behind such models is that the effect of any government deficit is mitigated by compensatory changes in the representative agent's spending decisions. This occurs because the agent will be responsible for paying off that deficit in the future. Thus, from a modern mainstream macroeconomist's point of view, reducing government deficits allows the private sector to consume more and support the economy. This viewpoint stems from their belief in the existence of a general economic equilibrium, which predicts that economic fluctuations revert back toward a "normal" state of affairs automatically. For this reason econometric models that are used in economic forecasting are calibrated to show convergence to full resource utilization and employment despite government's fiscal tightening.[citation needed]

According to modern monetary theory austerity measures by a national government are usually counterproductive because neither taxation nor bond issuance acts as a funding mechanism for the government.[16] Instead all spending is done by crediting bank accounts, so national governments cannot run out of money unless they have fixed exchange rate to either foreign currency or gold or are part of a larger currency area like the eurozone where they do not have the right to issue money.[16][17]

Austrian School economists argue that austerity measures do not necessarily increase or decrease economic growth.[18] Rather, they argue that all attempts by central governments to prop up asset prices, bail out insolvent banks, or "stimulate" the economy with deficit spending make stable growth less likely.[18]

Empirical considerations

Public Debt to GDP Ratio for Selected European Countries - 2008 to 2011. Source Data: Eurostat

A typical goal of austerity is to reduce the annual budget deficit without sacrificing growth. Over time, this may reduce the overall debt burden, often measured as the ratio of public debt to GDP. During the European sovereign-debt crisis, many countries embarked on austerity programs, reducing their budget deficits relative to GDP from 2010 to 2011. For example, according to the CIA World Factbook Greece improved its budget deficit from 10.4% GDP in 2010 to 9.6% in 2011. Iceland, Italy, Ireland, Portugal, France and Spain also improved their budget deficits from 2010 to 2011 relative to GDP.[19][20]

However, with the exception of Germany, each of these countries had public debt to GDP ratios that increased (worsened) from 2010 to 2011, as indicated in the chart at right. Greece's public debt to GDP ratio increased from 143% in 2010 to 165% in 2011.[19] This indicates that despite improving budget deficits, GDP growth was not sufficient to support a decline (improvement) in the debt to GDP ratio for these countries during this period. Eurostat reported that the debt to GDP ratio for the 17 Euro area countries together was 70.1% in 2008, 79.9% in 2009, 85.3% in 2010, and 87.2% in 2011.[20][21]

Unemployment is another variable that might be considered in evaluating austerity measures. According to the CIA World Factbook, from 2010 to 2011, the unemployment rates in Spain, Greece, Ireland, Portugal and the UK increased. France and Italy had no significant changes, while in Germany and Iceland the unemployment rate declined.[19]

Discretionary spending, mandatory spending, and revenue increases over nine-year intervals

Another historical example of austerity was in the United States, which balanced its budget from 1998 to 2001. The basic strategy was to limit the rate of growth in defense and non-defense discretionary spending (which funds the major cabinet departments and agencies) during most of the 1990s, while growing revenues along with the economy. Comparing 1990 vs. 1999, defense and non-defense discretionary spending grew by a total of 14%, while revenues grew 77%. Public debt to GDP declined from 42.1% in 1990 to 39.4% by 1999, although it rose during the interim slightly. In contrast, from 2000–2009, discretionary spending grew by a total of 101% while revenues grew only 4%. Public debt to GDP increased from 34.7% in 2000 to 53.5% in 2009. Revenue grew nearly 25% when comparing 2000 to the pre-crisis peak in 2007, still considerably less than the prior decade.[22]

Controversy

Austerity programs can be controversial. In the Overseas Development Institute briefing paper "The IMF and the Third World" the ODI addresses five major complaints against the IMF's austerity 'conditionalities'. These complaints include these measures being "anti-developmental", "self-defeating", and "they tend to have an adverse impact on the poorest segments of the population". In many situations, austerity programs are implemented by countries that were previously under dictatorial regimes, leading to criticism that the citizens are forced to repay the debts of their oppressors.[23][24][25]

Economist Richard D. Wolff has stated that instead of cutting government programs and raising taxes, austerity should be attained by collecting (taxes) from non-profit multinational corporations, churches, and private tax-exempt institutions such as universities, which currently pay no taxes at all.[26]

In 2009, 2010, and 2011, workers and students in Greece and other European countries demonstrated against cuts to pensions, public services and education spending as a result of government austerity measures.[27][28] Following the announcement of plans to introduce austerity measures in Greece, massive demonstrations were witnessed throughout the country, aimed at pressing parliamentarians to vote against the austerity package. In Athens alone 19 arrests were made while 46 civilians and 38 policemen had been injured by 29 June 2011. The third round austerity has been approved by the Greece parliament on 12 February 2012 and has met strong opposition especially in the cities of Athens and Thessaloniki where police clashed with demonstrators.

Opponents argue that austerity measures depress economic growth, and ultimately cause reduced tax revenues that outweigh the benefits of reduced public spending. This is especially the case when austerity measures affect the private sector and do not merely correct unreasonable expenditures on the public sector workforce. The case of Greece significantly corroborates these views. Moreover, in countries with already anemic economic growth, austerity can engender deflation which inflates existing debt. Such austerity packages can also cause the country to fall into a liquidity trap, causing credit markets to freeze up and unemployment to increase. Opponents point to cases in Ireland and Spain in which austerity measures instituted in response to financial crises in 2009 proved ineffective in combating public debt, and placing those countries at risk of defaulting in late 2010.[29]

Austerity sequence

Several economists have argued that an appropriate strategy when an economy is faced with unusually high private debt levels is to exchange private debts for public debts initially, then cut government debt via an austerity strategy once the economy recovers. Applying an austerity strategy to a struggling economy can be counter-productive according to Keynesian theory described above.

For example, the private sector may become highly indebted, such as when a housing bubble bursts. Housing prices fall while the mortgage obligations remain fixed, leading to "underwater" homeowners unable to consume at sufficient levels to drive economic growth. A banking crisis can result, as defaulting homeowners result in banks unable to lend or stay in business, which slows the economy and worsens unemployment. These effects can become self-reinforcing, creating a downward economic spiral. This spiral is at the core of the subprime mortgage crisis in the U.S. and the European sovereign debt crisis.

Economist Amir Sufi at the University of Chicago argued in July 2011 that a high level of household debt was holding back the U.S. economy. Households focused on paying down private debt are not able to consume at historical levels. He advocated mortgage write-downs and other debt-related solutions to re-invigorate the economy when household debt levels are exceptionally high.[30]

Economists Joseph Stiglitz and Mark Zandi both advocated significant mortgage refinancing or write-downs during August 2012. This could be financed by the government taking on additional debt in the short-run as a form of stimulus. The government would borrow at a very low interest rate and create an entity to purchase mortgages, receiving a higher interest rate from mortgages it refinances. Losses due to mortgage principal write-downs would be shared between the government and financial institutions, with the government losses offset by the interest rate differential.[31]

The International Monetary Fund (IMF) reported in April 2012: "Household debt soared in the years leading up to the Great Recession. In advanced economies, during the five years preceding 2007, the ratio of household debt to income rose by an average of 39 percentage points, to 138 percent. In Denmark, Iceland, Ireland, the Netherlands, and Norway, debt peaked at more than 200 percent of household income. A surge in household debt to historic highs also occurred in emerging economies such as Estonia, Hungary, Latvia, and Lithuania. The concurrent boom in both house prices and the stock market meant that household debt relative to assets held broadly stable, which masked households’ growing exposure to a sharp fall in asset prices. When house prices declined, ushering in the global financial crisis, many households saw their wealth shrink relative to their debt, and, with less income and more unemployment, found it harder to meet mortgage payments. By the end of 2011, real house prices had fallen from their peak by about 41% in Ireland, 29% in Iceland, 23% in Spain and the United States, and 21% in Denmark. Household defaults, underwater mortgages (where the loan balance exceeds the house value), foreclosures, and fire sales are now endemic to a number of economies. Household deleveraging by paying off debts or defaulting on them has begun in some countries. It has been most pronounced in the United States, where about two-thirds of the debt reduction reflects defaults." These countries might also benefit from household debt reduction policies involving exchanging private debt for public debt.[32][33]

The "Age of Austerity"

The term “Age of austerity” was popularized by British Conservative leader David Cameron in his keynote speech to the Conservative party forum in Cheltenham on 26 April 2009, when he committed to put an end to what he called years of excessive government spending.[34][35]

Word of the year

Merriam-Webster's Dictionary named the word "austerity" as its "Word of the Year" for 2010 because of the number of web searches this word generated that year. According to the president and publisher of the dictionary, "austerity had more than 250,000 searches on the dictionary's free online [website] tool" and the spike in searches "came with more coverage of the debt crisis".[36]

Examples of austerity

See also

References

  1. ^ Elmhirst, Sophie (24 September 2010). "Word Games: Austerity". New Statesman. Archived from the original on 29 September 2010. Retrieved 29 September 2010. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |deadurl= ignored (|url-status= suggested) (help)
  2. ^ Traynor, Ian (11 June 2010). "Austerity Europe: who faces the cuts". London: Guardian News. Retrieved 29 September 2010. {{cite news}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  3. ^ Wesbury, Brian S. (26 July 2010). "Government Austerity: The Good, Bad And Ugly". Forbes. Archived from the original on 29 September 2010. Retrieved 29 September 2010. {{cite news}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help); Unknown parameter |deadurl= ignored (|url-status= suggested) (help)
  4. ^ {{cite web [1], Tales of Fiscal Adjustments, Alberto Alesina & Silvia Ardagna}}
  5. ^ Krugman, Paul (15 April 2012). "Europe's Economic Suicide". The New York Times.
  6. ^ Heard on Fresh Air from WHYY (4 October 2011). "NPR-Michael Lewis-How the Financial Crisis Created a New Third World-October 2011". Npr.org. Retrieved 7 July 2012.
  7. ^ "Greek austerity measures could violate human rights, UN expert says". United Nations. 30 June 2011. Retrieved 3 July 2011.
  8. ^ NYT-Paul Krugman-Keynes Was Right-December 2011
  9. ^ NYT-Paul Krugman-The Austerity Agenda-May 2012
  10. ^ Zandi, Mark. "A Second Quick Boost From Government Could Spark Recovery." Edited excerpts from congressional testimony July 24, 2008.
  11. ^ CBO-Assessing the Short-Term Effects on Output from Changes in Fiscal Policies-May 2012
  12. ^ Washington Post-Ezra Klein-CBO Ranks Democratic and Republican Proposals in One Chart-November 2011
  13. ^ Think Progress-CBO Report Proves Spending Cuts Won't Boost Economic Growth-May 2012
  14. ^ Alvin H. Hansen Fiscal Policy and Business Cycles
  15. ^ Both the new classical and the new Keynesian schools use DSGE -modeling
  16. ^ a b "Can Taxes and Bonds Finance Government Spending?". Papers.ssrn.com. 14 August 1998. doi:10.2139/ssrn.115128. Retrieved 1 July 2011.
  17. ^ L. Randall, Wray (1998), Understanding modern money: the key to full employment and price stability, Edward Elgar Publishing, ISBN 978-1845429416
  18. ^ a b America's Great Depression, Murray Rothbard
  19. ^ a b c CIA World Factbook-Greece Example-Retrieved August 2012
  20. ^ a b Eurostat-Selected Principal European Economic Indicators-Retrieved 15 August 2012
  21. ^ Eurostat News Release-Euro indicators-23 April 2012
  22. ^ CBO Historical Tables 1971-2010
  23. ^ Harvey, D (2005) A Brief History of Neoliberalism
  24. ^ Klein, N. (2007) The Shock Doctrine
  25. ^ Chomsky, N (2004) Hegemony or Survival
  26. ^ Wolff, Richard (4 July 2010). "Austerity: Why and for Whom?". RDWolff.com. Archived from the original on 6 October 2010. Retrieved 29 September 2010. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |deadurl= ignored (|url-status= suggested) (help)
  27. ^ Kyriakidou, Dina (4 August 2010). "In Greece you get a bonus for showing up for work – Arcane benefits add billions to Greece's bloated budget". Toronto Star. Toronto. Retrieved 29 September 2010.
  28. ^ Costas Kantouris and Nicholas Paphitis (10 September 10, 2011). "Greek police, firefighters protest". The Boston Globe. Associated Press Sm,meme,emme,e,e,e. Retrieved 29 September 2011. {{cite news}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  29. ^ Leung, Sophie (11 November 2010). "Stiglitz Says Ireland Has Bleak Prospect of Cutting Deficit, Saving Banks". Bloomberg. Retrieved 1 July 2011.
  30. ^ Bloomberg-Household Debt is at Heart of Weak U.S. Economy-July 2011
  31. ^ NYT-Stiglitz and Zandi-The One Housing Solution Left-Mass Mortgage Refinancing-August 2012
  32. ^ IMF-Report Extract Chapter 3-April 2012
  33. ^ McKinsey-Debt and deleveraging: The global credit bubble and its economic consequences-Updated-July 2011
  34. ^ Deborah Summers (26 April 2009). "David Cameron warns of 'new age of austerity'". The Guardian. . Archived from the original on 29 April 2009. Retrieved 26 April 2009. {{cite news}}: Unknown parameter |deadurl= ignored (|url-status= suggested) (help)
  35. ^ M. Nicolas Firzli & Vincent Bazi (Q4 2011). "Infrastructure Investments in an Age of Austerity : The Pension and Sovereign Funds Perspective". Revue Analyse Financière, volume 41. Retrieved 30 July 2011. {{cite news}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  36. ^ Contreras, Russell (20 December 2010). "Audacity of 'austerity,' 2010 Word of the Year". Associated Press. Retrieved 20 December 2010.[dead link]
  37. ^ Time Magazine (1952), "ARGENTINA: Inflexible Austerity"
  38. ^ Sonja Pace (16 June 2010). "Germany Approves Biggest Austerity Plan Since World War II | News | English". .voanews.com. Retrieved 1 July 2011. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |unused_data= ignored (help)
  39. ^ "WRAPUP 4-Greek debt costs spike on budget jitters". Reuters. 21 January 2010.
  40. ^ "UPDATE 2-Italy joins Europe's austerity club with deep cuts". Reuters. 25 May 2010.
  41. ^ (AFP) – 27 Jul 2010 (27 July 2010). "AFP: Japan unveils budget austerity guidelines". Google. Retrieved 1 July 2011.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link)
  42. ^ "Soros says EU "wrong" to push austerity on Latvia". Reuters. 10 October 2009.
  43. ^ "Mexico's Austerity Plans". The New York Times. 8 February 1985.
  44. ^ "Revista Envío – President Arnoldo Alemán Between the Fund and the Front". Envio.org.ni. Retrieved 1 July 2011.
  45. ^ "Bankrupt Hamas government unveils austerity package". Americanintifada.com. Archived from the original on 7 July 2011. Retrieved 1 July 2011. {{cite web}}: Unknown parameter |deadurl= ignored (|url-status= suggested) (help)
  46. ^ Leigh Phillips (20 May 2010). "EUobserver / Romania sees biggest protest since 1989 over austerity measures". Euobserver.com. Retrieved 1 July 2011.
  47. ^ Salvadó, Francisco J. Romero (1999) Twentieth-century Spain: politics and society in Spain, 1898–1998
  48. ^ Coates, Sam; Evans, Judith (7 June 2010). "Cameron fingers culprits for Britains 770bn debt pile". The Times. London.