Jump to content

Glass–Steagall legislation: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Bulba2036 (talk | contribs)
No edit summary
Line 1: Line 1:
The '''Glass–Steagall Act''' is a term often applied to the entire [[Banking Act of 1933]], after its Congressional sponsors, Senator [[Carter Glass]] ([[Democratic Party (United States)|D]]) of [[List of United States Senators from Virginia|Virginia]], and Representative [[Henry B. Steagall]] (D) of [[Alabama's 3rd congressional district|Alabama]].<ref name="Frontline">{{cite web |url=http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/shows/wallstreet/weill/demise.html |title=Frontline: The Wall Street Fix: Mr. Weill Goes to Washington: The Long Demise of Glass–Steagall |accessdate=2008-10-08 |work=www.pbs.org |publisher=[[PBS]] |date=2003-05-08 }}</ref> The term Glass–Steagall Act, however, is most often used to refer to four provisions of the Banking Act of 1933 that limited commercial bank securities activities and affiliations between commercial banks and securities firms.<ref name="name" /> This article deals with that limited meaning of the Glass–Steagall Act. A separate article describes the entire [[Banking Act of 1933]].
The '''Glass–Steagall Act''' is a term often applied to the entire [[Banking Act of 1933]], after its Congressional sponsors, Senator [[Carter Glass]] ([[Democratic Party (United States)|D]]) of [[List of United States Senators from Virginia|Virginia]], and Representative [[Henry B. Steagall]] (D) of [[Alabama's 3rd congressional district|Alabama]].<ref name="Frontline">{{cite web |url=http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/shows/wallstreet/weill/demise.html |title=Frontline: The Wall Street Fix: Mr. Weill Goes to Washington: The Long Demise of Glass–Steagall |accessdate=2008-10-08 |work=www.pbs.org |publisher=[[PBS]] |date=2003-05-08 }}</ref> The term Glass–Steagall Act, however, is most often used to refer to four provisions of the Banking Act of 1933 that limited commercial bank securities activities and affiliations between commercial banks and securities firms.<ref name="name" /> This article deals with that limited meaning of the Glass–Steagall Act. A separate article describes the entire [[Banking Act of 1933]].


Starting in the early 1960s federal banking regulators interpreted provisions of the Glass–Steagall Act to permit commercial banks and especially commercial bank affiliates to engage in an expanding list and volume of securities activities.<ref name="uphold" /> By the time the affiliation restrictions in the Glass–Steagall Act were repealed through the [[Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act]] of 1999 (GLBA), many commentators argued Glass–Steagall was already “dead.”<ref name="dead" /> Most notably, [[Citibank]]’s 1998 affiliation with [[Salomon Smith Barney]], one of the largest US securities firms, was permitted under the Federal Reserve Board’s then existing interpretation of the Glass–Steagall Act.<ref name="Citi" /> President [[Bill Clinton]] publicly declared "the Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate."<ref>{{cite web |http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/business-economy-financial-crisis/money-power-wall-street/transcript-19/ |title=Money, power, and Wall Street: Transcript, Part 4, (quoted as "The Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate—") |publisher=[[PBS]]|date=April 24 and May 1, 2012; encore performance July 3, 2012|accessdate=October 8, 2012}} {{Citation|title=Transcript of Clinton remarks at Financial Modernization bill signing|publisher=[[U.S. Newswire]] |location=Washington, D.C.|date=November 12, 1999}} (“It is true that the Glass-Steagall law is no longer appropriate to the economy in which we lived. It worked pretty well for the industrial economy, which was highly organized, much more centralized and much more nationalized than the one in which we operate today. But the world is very different.”)</ref>
Starting in the early 1960s federal banking regulators interpreted provisions of the Glass–Steagall Act to permit commercial banks and especially commercial bank affiliates to engage in an expanding list and volume of securities activities.<ref name="uphold" /> By the time the affiliation restrictions in the Glass–Steagall Act were repealed through the [[Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act]] of 1999 (GLBA), many commentators argued Glass–Steagall was already “dead.”<ref name="dead" /> Most notably, [[Citibank]]’s 1998 affiliation with [[Salomon Smith Barney]], one of the largest US securities firms, was permitted under the [[Federal Reserve Board]]’s then existing interpretation of the Glass–Steagall Act.<ref name="Citi" /> President [[Bill Clinton]] publicly declared "the Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate."<ref>{{cite web |http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/business-economy-financial-crisis/money-power-wall-street/transcript-19/ |title=Money, power, and Wall Street: Transcript, Part 4, (quoted as "The Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate—") |publisher=[[PBS]]|date=April 24 and May 1, 2012; encore performance July 3, 2012|accessdate=October 8, 2012}} {{Citation|title=Transcript of Clinton remarks at Financial Modernization bill signing|publisher=[[U.S. Newswire]] |location=Washington, D.C.|date=November 12, 1999}} (“It is true that the Glass-Steagall law is no longer appropriate to the economy in which we lived. It worked pretty well for the industrial economy, which was highly organized, much more centralized and much more nationalized than the one in which we operate today. But the world is very different.”)</ref>
Many commentators have stated that the GLBA’s repeal of the affiliation restrictions of the Glass–Steagall Act was an important cause of the [[late-2000s financial crisis]].<ref>{{cite web | url=http://www.usc.edu/org/InsightBusiness/ib/articles/articlescontent/08_4%20Adrianna%20Smith.html | title =The Overlooked Culprit in the Credit Crisis | publisher =usc.edu}}</ref><ref name="Kuttner" /><ref name="Stiglitz" /> Some critics of that repeal argue it permitted Wall Street investment banking firms to gamble with their depositors' money that was held in affiliated commercial banks.<ref>{{Citation| title=Sold Out: How Wall Street and Washington Betrayed America | publisher =[[Consumer Education Foundation]]| date =March 2009 | url=http://www.wallstreetwatch.org/reports/sold_out.pdf}}</ref> Others have argued that the activities linked to the financial crisis were not prohibited (or, in most cases, even regulated) by the Glass–Steagall Act.<ref name="W&M" /> Commentators, including former President Clinton in 2008 and the [[American Bankers Association]] in January 2010, have also argued that the ability of commercial banking firms to acquire securities firms (and of securities firms to convert into bank holding companies) helped mitigate the financial crisis.<ref name="mitigate" />
Many commentators have stated that the GLBA’s repeal of the affiliation restrictions of the Glass–Steagall Act was an important cause of the [[late-2000s financial crisis]].<ref>{{cite web | url=http://www.usc.edu/org/InsightBusiness/ib/articles/articlescontent/08_4%20Adrianna%20Smith.html | title =The Overlooked Culprit in the Credit Crisis | publisher =usc.edu}}</ref><ref name="Kuttner" /><ref name="Stiglitz" /> Some critics of that repeal argue it permitted Wall Street investment banking firms to gamble with their depositors' money that was held in affiliated commercial banks.<ref>{{Citation| title=Sold Out: How Wall Street and Washington Betrayed America | publisher =[[Consumer Education Foundation]]| date =March 2009 | url=http://www.wallstreetwatch.org/reports/sold_out.pdf}}</ref> Others have argued that the activities linked to the financial crisis were not prohibited (or, in most cases, even regulated) by the Glass–Steagall Act.<ref name="W&M" /> Commentators, including former President Clinton in 2008 and the [[American Bankers Association]] in January 2010, have also argued that the ability of commercial banking firms to acquire securities firms (and of securities firms to convert into bank holding companies) helped mitigate the financial crisis.<ref name="mitigate" />



Revision as of 06:41, 7 February 2013

The Glass–Steagall Act is a term often applied to the entire Banking Act of 1933, after its Congressional sponsors, Senator Carter Glass (D) of Virginia, and Representative Henry B. Steagall (D) of Alabama.[1] The term Glass–Steagall Act, however, is most often used to refer to four provisions of the Banking Act of 1933 that limited commercial bank securities activities and affiliations between commercial banks and securities firms.[2] This article deals with that limited meaning of the Glass–Steagall Act. A separate article describes the entire Banking Act of 1933.

Starting in the early 1960s federal banking regulators interpreted provisions of the Glass–Steagall Act to permit commercial banks and especially commercial bank affiliates to engage in an expanding list and volume of securities activities.[3] By the time the affiliation restrictions in the Glass–Steagall Act were repealed through the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act of 1999 (GLBA), many commentators argued Glass–Steagall was already “dead.”[4] Most notably, Citibank’s 1998 affiliation with Salomon Smith Barney, one of the largest US securities firms, was permitted under the Federal Reserve Board’s then existing interpretation of the Glass–Steagall Act.[5] President Bill Clinton publicly declared "the Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate."[6] Many commentators have stated that the GLBA’s repeal of the affiliation restrictions of the Glass–Steagall Act was an important cause of the late-2000s financial crisis.[7][8][9] Some critics of that repeal argue it permitted Wall Street investment banking firms to gamble with their depositors' money that was held in affiliated commercial banks.[10] Others have argued that the activities linked to the financial crisis were not prohibited (or, in most cases, even regulated) by the Glass–Steagall Act.[11] Commentators, including former President Clinton in 2008 and the American Bankers Association in January 2010, have also argued that the ability of commercial banking firms to acquire securities firms (and of securities firms to convert into bank holding companies) helped mitigate the financial crisis.[12]

Name confusion: 1932 and 1933 Glass–Steagall Acts

Sen. Carter Glass (DVa.) and Rep. Henry B. Steagall (DAla.-3), the co-sponsors of the Glass–Steagall Act.

Two separate United States laws are known as the Glass–Steagall Act. Both bills were sponsored by Democratic Senator Carter Glass of Lynchburg, Virginia, a former Secretary of the Treasury, and Democratic Congressman Henry B. Steagall of Alabama, Chairman of the House Committee on Banking and Currency.

The Glass–Steagall Act of 1932 authorized Federal Reserve Banks to (1) lend to five or more Federal Reserve System member banks on a group basis or to any individual member bank with capital stock of $5 million or less against any satisfactory collateral, not only “eligible paper,” and (2) issue Federal Reserve Bank Notes (i.e., paper currency) backed by US government securities when a shortage of “eligible paper” held by Federal Reserve banks would have required such currency to be backed by gold.[13] The Federal Reserve Board explained that the special lending to Federal Reserve member banks permitted by the 1932 Glass–Steagall Act would only be permitted in “unusual and temporary circumstances.”[14]

The entire Banking Act of 1933 (the 1933 Banking Act), which is described in a separate article, is also often referred to as the Glass–Steagall Act.[15] Over time, however, the term Glass–Steagall Act came to be used most often to refer to four provisions of the 1933 Banking Act that separated commercial banking from investment banking.[2] Congressional efforts to “repeal the Glass–Steagall Act” referred to those four provisions (and then usually to only the two provisions that restricted affiliations between commercial banks and securities firms).[16] Those efforts culminated in the 1999 Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act (GLBA), which repealed the two provisions restricting affiliations between banks and securities firms.[17]

Legislative history of the Glass–Steagall Act

The article on the 1933 Banking Act describes the legislative history of that Act, including the Glass–Steagall provisions separating commercial and investment banking. As described in that article, between 1930 and 1932 Senator Carter Glass (D-VA) introduced several versions of a bill (known in each version as the Glass bill) to regulate or prohibit the combination of commercial and investment banking and to establish other reforms (except deposit insurance) similar to the final provisions of the 1933 Banking Act.[18] On January 25, 1933, during the lame duck session of Congress following the 1932 elections, the Senate passed a version of the Glass bill that would have required commercial banks to eliminate their securities affiliates.[19] The final Glass–Steagall provisions contained in the 1933 Banking Act reduced from five years to one year the period in which commercial banks were required to eliminate such affiliations.[20] Although the deposit insurance provisions of the 1933 Banking Act were very controversial, and drew veto threats from President Franklin Delano Roosevelt, President Roosevelt supported the Glass–Steagall provisions separating commercial and investment banking, and Representative Steagall included those provisions in his House bill that differed from Senator Glass’s Senate bill primarily in its deposit insurance provisions.[21]

As described in the 1933 Banking Act article, many accounts of the Act identify the Pecora Investigation as important in leading to the Act, particularly its Glass–Steagall provisions, becoming law.[22] While supporters of the Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking cite the Pecora Investigation as supporting that separation,[23] Glass–Steagall critics have argued that the evidence from the Pecora Investigation did not support the separation of commercial and investment banking.[24]

The Glass–Steagall provisions separating commercial and investment banking

The Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking was in four sections of the 1933 Banking Act (sections 16, 20, 21, and 32).[2]

Section 16

Section 16 prohibited national banks from purchasing or selling securities except for a customer’s account (i.e., as a customer’s agent) unless the securities were purchased for the bank’s account as “investment securities” identified by the Comptroller of the Currency as permitted national bank investments. Section 16 also prohibited national banks from underwriting or distributing securities.[25]

Section 16, however, permitted national banks to buy, sell, underwrite, and distribute US government and general obligation state and local government securities. Such securities became known as “bank-eligible securities.”[25]

Section 5(c) of the 1933 Banking Act (sometimes referred to as the fifth Glass–Steagall provision) applied Section 16’s rules to Federal Reserve System member state chartered banks.[26]

Section 20

Section 20 prohibited any member bank of the Federal Reserve System (whether a state chartered or national bank) from being affiliated with a company that “engaged principally” in “the issue, flotation, underwriting, public sale, or distribution” of securities.[27]

Section 21

Section 21 prohibited any company or person from taking deposits if it was in the business of “issuing, underwriting, selling, or distributing” securities.[28]

Section 32

Section 32 prohibited any Federal Reserve System member bank from having any officer or director in common with a company “engaged primarily” in the business of “purchasing, selling, or negotiating” securities, unless the Federal Reserve Board granted an exemption.[29]

1935 clarifying amendments

Sections 16 and 21 contradicted each other. The Banking Act of 1935 “clarified” that Section 21 would not prevent a deposit taking company from engaging in any of the securities underwriting and dealing activities permitted by Section 16. It also amended Section 16 to permit a bank to purchase stocks, not only debt securities, for a customer’s account.[30]

The Banking Act of 1935 amended Section 32 to make it consistent with Section 20 and to prevent a securities company and bank from having any employee (not only any officer) in common. With the amendment, both Sections 20 and 32 applied to companies engaged in the “issue, flotation, underwriting, public sale, or distribution” of securities.[31]

Prohibitions apply to dealing in and underwriting or distributing securities

The Glass–Steagall Act was primarily directed at restricting banks and their affiliates underwriting or distributing securities. Senator Glass, Representative Steagall, Ferdinand Pecora, and others claimed banks had abused this activity to sell customers (including correspondent banks) high risk securities.[32] As particular “conflicts of interest,” they alleged bank affiliates had underwritten corporate and foreign government bonds to repay loans made by their affiliated banks or, in the opposite direction, banks had lent to or otherwise supported corporations that used the bank’s affiliate to underwrite their bonds.[33]

Sections 16 and 5(c) meant no member bank of the Federal Reserve System could underwrite or distribute corporate or other non-governmental bonds.[25] Sections 20 and 32 meant such a bank could not own (directly or through the same bank holding company) a company “engaged primarily in” such underwriting or other securities activities nor have any director or employee that was also a director or employee of such a company.[34]

Senator Glass, Representative Steagall, and others claimed banks had made too many loans for securities speculation and too many direct bank investments in securities.[35] As described in the article on the Banking Act of 1933, non-“Glass–Steagall” provisions of the 1933 Banking Act restricted those activities.[36] Among the Glass–Steagall provisions, Sections 16 and 5(c) prevented a Federal Reserve member bank from investing in equity securities[37] or from “dealing” in debt securities as a market maker or otherwise.[38] Section 16 permitted national banks (and Section 5(c) permitted state member banks) to purchase for their own accounts “marketable” debt securities that were “investment securities” approved by the Comptroller of the Currency. The Comptroller interpreted this to mean marketable securities rated “investment grade” by the rating agencies or, if not rated, a security that is the “credit equivalent.”[38]

Even before Glass–Steagall, however, national banks had been prohibited from investing in equity securities and could only purchase as investments debt securities approved by the Comptroller. Section 16’s major change was (through the Comptroller’s interpretation) to limit the investments to “investment grade” debt and to repeal the McFadden Act permission for national banks to act as “dealers” in buying and selling debt securities. Section 5(c) applied these national bank restrictions to state chartered banks that were members of the Federal Reserve System.[39]

The Comptroller ruled national banks could “trade” investment securities they had purchased, based on a bank’s power to sell its assets, so long as this trading did not cause the bank to be a “dealer.” Section 16 itself required banks to purchase only “marketable” securities, so that it contemplated (and required) that the securities be traded in a liquid market. The Office of the Comptroller, like the Securities and Exchange Commission, distinguished between a “trader” and a “dealer.” A “trader” buys and sells securities “opportunistically” based on when it thinks prices are low or high. A “dealer” buys and sells securities with customers to provide “liquidity” or otherwise provides buy and sell prices “on a continuous basis” as a market maker or otherwise.[40] The Comptroller of the Currency, therefore, ruled that Section 16 permitted national banks to engage in “proprietary trading” of “investment securities” for which it could not act as a “dealer.”[41] Thus, Glass–Steagall permitted “banks to invest in and trade securities to a significant extent” and did not restrict trading by bank affiliates, although the Bank Holding Company Act did restrict investments by bank affiliates.[42]

None of these prohibitions applied to “bank-eligible securities” (i.e., US government and state general obligation securities). Banks were free to underwrite, distribute, and deal in such securities.[25]

Glass–Steagall “loopholes”

Except for Section 21, Glass–Steagall only covered Federal Reserve member commercial banks

As explained in the article on the Banking Act of 1933, if the 1933 Banking Act had not been amended, it would have required all federally insured banks to become members of the Federal Reserve System.[43] Instead, because that requirement was removed through later legislation, the United States retained a dual banking system in which a large number of state chartered banks remained outside the Federal Reserve System.[44] This meant they were also outside the restrictions of Sections 16, 20, and 32 of the Glass–Steagall Act.[45] As described below, this became important in the 1980s when commentators worried large commercial banks would leave the Federal Reserve System to avoid Glass–Steagall’s affiliation restrictions.[46]

Although Section 21 of the Glass–Steagall Act was directed at preventing securities firms (particularly traditional private partnerships such as J.P. Morgan & Co.) from accepting deposits, it prevented any firm that accepted deposits from underwriting or dealing in securities (other than “bank-eligible securities” after the 1935 Banking Act’s “clarification”). This meant Section 21, unlike the rest of Glass–Steagall, applied to savings and loans and other “thrifts,” state nonmember banks, and any other firm or individual in the business of taking deposits.[28] This prevented such “depository institutions” from being securities firms. It did not prevent securities firms, such as Merrill Lynch, from owning separate subsidiaries that were thrifts or state chartered, non-Federal Reserve member banks.[47] As described below, this became important when securities firms used “unitary thrifts” and “nonbank banks” to avoid both Glass–Steagall affiliation restrictions and holding company laws that generally limited bank holding companies to banking businesses[48] and savings and loan holding companies to thrift businesses.[49]

Different treatment of bank and affiliate activities

Section 21 was not the only Glass–Steagall provision that treated differently what a company could do directly and what it could do through a subsidiary or other affiliate. As described in the Banking Act of 1933 article, Senator Glass and other proponents of separating commercial banks from investment banking attacked the artificiality of distinguishing between banks and their securities affiliates.[50] Sections 20[27] and 32[29] of the Glass–Steagall Act, however, distinguished between what a bank could do directly and what an affiliated company could do.[51]

No bank covered by Section 16’s prohibitions could buy, sell, underwrite, or distribute any security except as specifically permitted by Section 16.[25] Under Section 21, no securities firm (understood as a firm “in the business” of underwriting, distributing, or dealing in securities) could accept any deposit.[28]

Glass–Steagall’s affiliation provisions did not contain such absolute prohibitions. Section 20 only prohibited a bank from affiliating with a firm “engaged principally” in underwriting, distributing, or dealing in securities.[27] Under Section 32, a bank could not share employees or directors with a company “primarily engaged” in underwriting, distributing, or dealing in securities.[29]

This difference (which would later be termed a “loophole”) provided the justification for the “long demise of Glass–Steagall” through regulatory actions that largely negated the practical significance of Sections 20 and 32 before they were repealed by the GLBA.[1] The fact Sections 16, 20, and 32 only restricted Federal Reserve member banks was another feature that made the Glass–Steagall Act less than “comprehensive” and, in the words of a 1987 commentator, provided “opportunities for banking institutions and their lawyers to explore (or, perhaps more accurately, to exploit).”[52]

Glass–Steagall developments from 1935 to 1991

Commercial banks withdrew from the depressed securities markets of the early 1930s even before the Glass–Steagall prohibitions on securities underwriting and dealing became effective.[53] Those prohibitions, however were controversial. A 1934 study of commercial bank affiliate underwriting of securities in the 1920s found such underwriting was not better than the underwriting by firms that were not affiliated with banks. That study disputed Glass–Steagall critics who suggested securities markets had been harmed by prohibiting commercial bank involvement.[54] A 1942 study also found that commercial bank affiliate underwriting was not better (or worse) than nonbank affiliate underwriting, but concluded this meant it was a “myth” commercial bank securities affiliates had taken advantage of bank customers to sell “worthless securities.”[55]

Senator Glass’s “repeal” effort

In 1935 Senator Glass attempted to repeal the Glass–Steagall prohibition on commercial banks underwriting corporate securities. Glass stated Glass–Steagall had unduly damaged securities markets by prohibiting commercial bank underwriting of corporate securities.[56] The first Senate passed version of the Banking Act of 1935 included Glass’s revision to Section 16 of the Glass–Steagall Act to permit bank underwriting of corporate securities subject to limitations and regulations.[57]

President Roosevelt opposed this revision to Section 16 and wrote Glass that “the old abuses would come back if underwriting were restored in any shape, manner, or form.” In the conference committee that reconciled differences between the House and Senate passed versions of the Banking Act of 1935, Glass’s language amending Section 16 was removed.[58]

Comptroller Saxon’s Glass–Steagall interpretations

President John F. Kennedy’s appointee as Comptroller of the Currency, James J. Saxon, was the next public official to challenge seriously Glass–Steagall’s prohibitions. As the regulator of national banks, Saxon was concerned with the competitive position of commercial banks. In 1950 commercial banks held 52% of the assets of US financial institutions. By 1960 that share had declined to 38%. Saxon wanted to expand the powers of national banks.[59]

In 1963, the Saxon-led Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) issued a regulation permitting national banks to offer retail customers “commingled accounts” holding common stocks and other securities.[60] This amounted to permitting banks to offer mutual funds to retail customers.[61] Saxon also issued rulings that national banks could underwrite municipal revenue bonds.[62] Courts ruled that both of these actions violated Glass–Steagall.[63]

In rejecting bank sales of accounts that functioned like mutual funds, the Supreme Court explained in Investment Company Institute v. Camp that it would have given “deference” to the OCC’s judgment if the OCC had explained how such sales could avoid the conflicts of interest and other “subtle hazards” Glass–Steagall sought to prevent and that could arise when a bank offered a securities product to its retail customers.[64] Courts later applied this aspect of the Camp ruling to uphold interpretations of Glass–Steagall by federal banking regulators.[3] As in the Camp case, these interpretations by bank regulators were routinely challenged by the mutual fund industry through the Investment Company Institute or the securities industry through the Securities Industry Association as they sought to prevent competition from commercial banks.[65]

1966 to 1980 developments

Increasing competitive pressures for commercial banks

Regulation Q limits on interest rates for time deposits at commercial banks, authorized by the 1933 Banking Act, first became “effective” in 1966 when market interest rates exceeded those limits.[66] This produced the first of several “credit crunches” during the late 1960s and throughout the 1970s as depositors withdrew funds from banks to reinvest at higher market interest rates.[67] When this “disintermediation” limited the ability of banks to meet the borrowing requests of all their corporate customers, some commercial banks helped their “best customers” establish programs to borrow directly from the “capital markets” by issuing commercial paper.[68] Over time, commercial banks were increasingly left with lower credit quality, or more speculative, corporate borrowers that could not borrow directly from the “capital markets.”[69]

Eventually, even lower credit quality corporations and (indirectly through “securitization”) consumers were able to borrow from the capital markets as improvements in communication and information technology allowed investors to evaluate and invest in a broader range of borrowers.[70] Banks began to finance residential mortgages through securitization in the late 1970s.[71] During the 1980s banks and other lenders used securitizations to provide “capital markets” funding for a wide range of assets that previously had been financed by bank loans.[72] In losing “their preeminent status as expert intermediaries for the collection, processing, and analysis of information relating to extensions of credit”, banks were increasingly “bypassed” as traditional “depositors” invested in securities that replaced bank loans.[73]

In 1977 Merrill Lynch introduced a “cash management account” that allowed brokerage customers to write checks on funds held in a money market account or drawn from a “line of credit” Merrill provided.[74] The Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) had ruled that money market funds could “redeem” investor shares at a $1 stable “net asset value” despite daily fluctuations in the value of the securities held by the funds. This allowed money market funds to develop into “near money” as “investors” wrote checks (“redemption orders”) on these accounts much as “depositors” wrote checks on traditional checking accounts provided by commercial banks.[75]

Also in the 1970s savings and loans, which were not restricted by Glass–Steagall other than Section 21,[47] were permitted to offer “negotiable order of withdrawal accounts” (NOW accounts). As with money market accounts, these accounts functioned much like checking accounts in permitting a depositor to order payments from a “savings account.”[76]

Helen Garten concluded that the “traditional regulation” of commercial banks established by the 1933 Banking Act, including Glass–Steagall, failed when nonbanking firms and the “capital markets” were able to provide replacements for bank loans and deposits, thereby reducing the profitability of commercial banking.[77] While he agreed traditional bank regulation was unable to protect commercial banks from nonbank competition, Richard Vietor also noted that the economic and financial instability that began in the mid-1960s both slowed economic growth and savings (reducing the demand for and supply of credit) and induced financial innovations that undermined commercial banks.[78]

Hyman Minsky agreed financial instability had returned in 1966 and had only been constrained in the following 15 years through Federal Reserve Board engineered “credit crunches” to combat inflation followed by “lender of last resort” rescues of asset prices that produced new inflation. Minsky described ever worsening periods of inflation followed by unemployment as the cycle of rescues followed by credit crunches was repeated.[67] Minsky, however, supported traditional banking regulation[79] and advocated further controls of finance to “promote smaller and simpler organizations weighted more toward direct financing.”[80] Writing from a similar “neo-Keynesian perspective, Jan Kregel concluded that after World War II non-regulated financial companies, supported by regulatory actions, developed means to provide bank products (“liquidity and lending accommodation”) more cheaply than commercial banks through the “capital markets.”[81] Kregel argued this led banking regulators to eliminate Glass–Steagall restrictions to permit banks to “duplicate these structures” using the capital markets “until there was virtually no difference in the activities of FDIC-insured commercial banks and investment banks.”[82]

Comptroller Saxon had feared for the competitive viability of commercial banks in the early 1960s.[59] The “capital markets” developments in the 1970s increased the vulnerability of commercial banks to nonbank competitors. As described below, this competition would increase in the 1980s.[83]

Limited congressional and regulatory developments

In 1967 the Senate passed the first of several Senate passed bills that would have revised Glass–Steagall Section 16 to permit banks to underwrite municipal revenue bonds.[84] In 1974 the OCC authorized national banks to provide “automatic investment services,” which permitted bank customers to authorize regular withdrawals from a deposit account to purchase identified securities.[85] In 1977 the Federal Reserve Board staff concluded Glass–Steagall permitted banks to privately place commercial paper. In 1978 Bankers Trust began making such placements.[86] As described below, in 1978, the OCC authorized a national bank to privately place securities issued to sell residential mortgages in a securitization[87]

Commercial banks, however, were frustrated with the continuing restrictions imposed by Glass–Steagall and other banking laws.[88] After many of Comptroller Saxon’s decisions granting national banks greater powers had been challenged or overturned by courts, commercial banking firms had been able to expand their non-securities activities through the “one bank holding company.”[89] Because the Bank Holding Company Act only limited nonbanking activities of companies that owned two or more commercial banks, “one bank holding companies” could own interests in any type of company other than securities firms covered by Glass–Steagall Section 20. That “loophole” in the Bank Holding Company Act was closed by a 1970 amendment to apply the Act to any company that owned a commercial bank.[90] Commercial banking firm’s continuing desire for greater powers received support when Ronald Reagan became President and appointed banking regulators who shared an “attitude towards deregulation of the financial industry.”[91]

Reagan Administration developments

State non-member bank and nonbank bank “loopholes”

In 1982, under the chairmanship of William Isaac, the FDIC issued a “policy statement” that state chartered non-Federal Reserve member banks could establish subsidiaries to underwrite and deal in securities. Also in 1982 the OCC, under Comptroller C. Todd Conover, approved the mutual fund company Dreyfus Corporation and the retailer Sears establishing “nonbank bank” subsidiaries that were not covered by the Bank Holding Company Act. The Federal Reserve Board, led by Chairman Paul Volcker, asked Congress to overrule both the FDIC’s and the OCC’s actions through new legislation.[92]

The FDIC’s action confirmed that Glass–Steagall did not restrict affiliations between a state chartered non-Federal Reserve System member bank and securities firms, even when the bank was FDIC insured.[45] State laws differed in how they regulated affiliations between banks and securities firms.[93] In the 1970s, foreign banks had taken advantage of this in establishing branches in states that permitted such affiliations.[94] Although the International Banking Act of 1978 brought newly established foreign bank US branches under Glass–Steagall, foreign banks with existing US branches were “grandfathered” and permitted to retain their existing investments. Through this “loophole” Credit Suisse was able to own a controlling interest in First Boston, a leading US securities firm.[95]

After the FDIC’s action, commentators worried that large commercial banks would leave the Federal Reserve System (after first converting to a state charter if they were national banks) to free themselves from Glass–Steagall affiliation restrictions, as large commercial banks lobbied states to permit commercial bank investment banking activities.[46]

The OCC’s action relied on a “loophole” in the Bank Holding Company Act (BHCA) that meant a company only became a “bank holding company” supervised by the Federal Reserve Board if it owned a “bank” that made “commercial loans” (i.e., loans to businesses) and provided “demand deposits” (i.e., checking accounts). A “nonbank bank” could be established to provide checking accounts (but not commercial loans) or commercial loans (but not checking accounts). The company owning the nonbank bank would not be a bank holding company limited to activities “closely related to banking.” This permitted Sears, GE, and other commercial companies to own “nonbank banks.”[48]

Glass–Steagall’s affiliation restrictions applied if the nonbank bank was a national bank or otherwise a member of the Federal Reserve System. The OCC’s permission for Dreyfus to own a nationally chartered “nonbank bank” was based on the OCC’s conclusion that Dreyfus, as a mutual fund company, earned only a small amount of its revenue through underwriting and distributing shares in mutual funds. Two other securities firms, J. & W. Seligman & Co. and Prudential-Bache, established state chartered non-Federal Reserve System member banks to avoid Glass–Steagall restrictions on affiliations between member banks and securities firms.[96]

Legislative response

Although Paul Volcker and the Federal Reserve Board sought legislation overruling the FDIC and OCC actions, they agreed bank affiliates should have broader securities powers. They supported a bill sponsored by Senate Banking Committee Chairman Jake Garn (R-UT) that would have amended Glass–Steagall Section 20 to cover all FDIC insured banks and to permit bank affiliates to underwrite and deal in mutual funds, municipal revenue bonds, commercial paper, and mortgage-backed securities. On September 13, 1984, the Senate passed the Garn bill in an 89-5 vote, but the Democratic controlled House did not act on the bill.[97]

In 1987, however, the Senate (with a new Democratic Party majority) joined with the House in passing the Competitive Equality Banking Act of 1987 (CEBA). Although primarily dealing with the savings and loan crisis, CEBA also established a moratorium to March 1, 1988, on banking regulator actions to approve bank or affiliate securities activities, applied the affiliation restrictions of Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 to all FDIC insured banks during the moratorium, and eliminated the “nonbank bank” loophole for new FDIC insured banks (whether they took demand deposits or made commercial loans) except industrial loan companies. Existing “nonbank banks”, however, were “grandfathered” so that they could continue to operate without becoming subject to BHCA restrictions.[98]

The CEBA was intended to provide time for Congress (rather than banking regulators) to review and resolve the Glass–Steagall issues of bank securities activities. Senator William Proxmire (D-WI), the new Chairman of the Senate Banking Committee, took up this topic in 1987.[99]

International competitiveness debate

Wolfgang Reinicke argues that Glass–Steagall “repeal” gained unexpected Congressional support in 1987 because large banks successfully argued that Glass–Steagall prevented US banks from competing internationally.[100] With the argument changed from preserving the profitability of large commercial banks to preserving the “competitiveness” of US banks (and of the US economy), Senator Proxmire reversed his earlier opposition to Glass–Steagall reform.[101] Proxmire sponsored a bill that would have repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 and replaced those prohibitions with a system for regulating (and limiting the amount of) bank affiliate securities activities.[102] He declared Glass–Steagall a “protectionist dinosaur.”[103]

By 1985 commercial banks provided 26% of short term loans to large businesses compared to 59% in 1974. While banks cited such statistics to illustrate the “decline of commercial banking,” Reinicke argues the most influential factor in Congress favoring Glass–Steagall “repeal” was the decline of US banks in international rankings. In 1960 six of the ten largest banks were US based, by 1980 only two US based banks were in the top ten, and by 1989 none was in the top twenty five.[83]

In the late 1980s the United Kingdom and Canada ended their historic separations of commercial and investment banking.[104] Glass–Steagall critics scornfully noted only Japanese legislation imposed by Americans during the Occupation of Japan kept the United States from being alone in separating the two activities.[105]

As noted above, even in the United States seventeen foreign banks were free from this Glass–Steagall restriction because they had established state chartered branches before the International Banking Act of 1978 brought newly established foreign bank US branches under Glass–Steagall.[95] Similarly, because major foreign countries did not separate investment and commercial banking, US commercial banks could underwrite and deal in securities through branches outside the United States. Paul Volcker agreed that, “broadly speaking,” it made no sense that US commercial banks could underwrite securities in Europe but not in the United States.[106]

1987 status of Glass–Steagall debate

Throughout the 1980s and 1990s scholars published studies arguing that commercial bank affiliate underwriting during the 1920s was no worse, or was better, than underwriting by securities firms not affiliated with banks and that commercial banks were strengthened, not harmed, by securities affiliates.[107] More generally, researchers attacked the idea that “integrated financial services firms” had played a role in creating the Great Depression or the collapse of the US banking system in the 1930s.[108] If it was “debatable” whether Glass–Steagall was justified in the 1930s, it was easier to argue that Glass–Steagall served no legitimate purpose when the distinction between commercial and investment banking activities had been blurred by “market developments” since the 1960s.[109]

Along with the “nonbank bank” “loophole” from BHCA limitations, in the 1980s the “unitary thrift” “loophole” became prominent as a means for securities and commercial firms to provide banking (or “near banking”) products.[110] The Savings and Loan Holding Company Act (SLHCA) permitted any company to own a single savings and loan. Only companies that owned two or more savings and loan were limited to thrift related businesses.[49] Already in 1973 First Chicago Bank had identified Sears as its real competitor.[111]Citicorp CEO Walter Wriston reached the same conclusion later in the 1970s.[112] By 1982, using the “unitary thrift” and “nonbank bank” “loopholes,” Sears had built the “Sears Financial Network”, which combined “Super NOW” accounts and mortgage loans through a large California-based savings and loan, the Discover Card issued by a “nonbank bank” as a credit card, securities brokerage through Dean Witter Reynolds, home and auto insurance through Allstate, and real estate brokerage through Coldwell Banker.[113] By 1984, however, Walter Wriston concluded “the bank of the future already exists, and it’s called Merrill Lynch.”[114] In 1986 when major bank holding companies threatened to stop operating commercial banks in order to obtain the “competitive advantages” enjoyed by Sears and Merrill Lynch, FDIC Chairman William Seidman warned that could create “chaos.”[115]

In a 1987 “issue brief” the Congressional Research Service (CRS) summarized “some of” the major arguments

for preserving Glass–Steagall as:

  1. Conflicts of interest characterize the granting of credit (lending) and the use of credit (investing) by the same entity, which led to abuses that originally produced the Act.
  2. Depository institutions possess enormous financial power, by virtue of their control of other people’s money; its extent must be limited to ensure soundness and competition in the market for funds, whether loans or investments.
  3. Securities activities can be risky, leading to enormous losses. Such losses could threaten the integrity of deposits. In turn, the Government insures deposits and could be required to pay large sums if depository institutions were to collapse as the result of securities losses.
  4. Depository institutions are supposed to be managed to limit risk. Their managers thus may not be conditioned to operate prudently in more speculative securities businesses. An example is the crash of real estate investment trusts sponsored by bank holding companies a decade ago.

and against preserving Glass–Steagall as:

  1. Depository institutions now operate in “deregulated” financial markets in which distinctions between loans, securities, and deposits are not well drawn. They are losing market shares to securities firms that are not so strictly regulated, and to foreign financial institutions operating without much restriction from the Act.
  2. Conflicts of interest can be prevented by enforcing legislation against them, and by separating the lending and credit functions through forming distinctly separate subsidiaries of financial firms.
  3. The securities activities that depository institutions are seeking are both low-risk by their very nature, and would reduce the total risk of organizations offering them – by diversification.
  4. In much of the rest of the world, depository institutions operate simultaneously and successfully in both banking and securities markets. Lessons learned from their experience can be applied to our national financial structure and regulation.[116]

Reflecting the significance of the “international competitiveness” argument, a separate CRS Report stated banks were “losing historical market shares of their major activities to domestic and foreign competitors that are less restricted.”[117]

Separately, the General Accounting Office (GAO) submitted to a House subcommittee a report reviewing the benefits and risks of “Glass–Steagall repeal.” The report recommended a “phased approach” using a “holding company organizational structure” if Congress chose “repeal.” Noting Glass–Steagall had “already been eroded and the erosion is likely to continue in the future,” the GAO explained “coming to grips with the Glass–Steagall repeal question represents an opportunity to systematically and rationally address changes in the regulatory and legal structure that are needed to better address the realities of the marketplace.” The GAO warned that Congress’s failure to act was “potentially dangerous” in permitting a “continuation of the uneven integration of commercial and investment banking activities.”[118]

As Congress was considering the Proxmire Financial Modernization Act in 1988, the Commission of the European Communities proposed a “Second Banking Directive”[119] that became effective at the beginning of 1993 and provided for the combination of commercial and investment banking throughout the European Economic Community.[120] Whereas United States law sought to isolate banks from securities activities, the Second Directive represented the European Union’s conclusion that securities activities diversified bank risk, strengthening the earnings and stability of banks.[121]

The Senate passed the Proxmire Financial Modernization Act of 1988 in a 94-2 vote. The House did not pass a similar bill, largely because of opposition from Representative John Dingell (D-MI), chairman of the House Commerce and Energy Committee.[122]

Section 20 affiliates

In April 1987, the Federal Reserve Board had approved the bank holding companies Bankers Trust, Citicorp, and J.P. Morgan & Co. establishing subsidiaries (“Section 20 affiliates”) to underwrite and deal in residential mortgage-backed securities, municipal revenue bonds, and commercial paper. Glass–Steagall’s Section 20 prohibited a bank from affiliating with a firm “primarily engaged” in underwriting and dealing in securities. The Board decided this meant Section 20 permitted a bank affiliate to earn 5% of its revenue from underwriting and dealing in these types of securities that were not “bank-eligible securities,” subject to various restrictions including “firewalls” to separate a commercial bank from its Section 20 affiliate.[123] Three months later the Board added “asset-backed securities” backed by pools of credit card accounts or other “consumer finance assets” to the list of “bank-ineligible securities” a Section 20 affiliate could underwrite. Bank holding companies, not commercial banks directly, owned these Section 20 affiliates.[124]

In 1978 the Federal Reserve Board had authorized bank holding companies to establish securities affiliates that underwrote and dealt in government securities and other bank-eligible securities.[125] Federal Reserve Board Chairman Paul Volcker supported Congress amending Glass–Steagall to permit such affiliates to underwrite and deal in a limited amount of bank-ineligible securities, but not corporate securities.[126] In 1987, Volcker specifically noted (and approved the result) that this would mean only banks with large government securities activities would be able to have affiliates that would underwrite and deal in a significant volume of “bank-ineligible securities.”[127] A Section 20 affiliate with a large volume of government securities related revenue would be able to earn a significant amount of “bank-ineligible” revenue without having more than 5% of its overall revenue come from bank-ineligible activities.[128] Volcker disagreed, however, that the Board had authority to permit this without an amendment to the Glass–Steagall Act. Citing that concern, Volcker and fellow Federal Reserve Board Governor Wayne Angell dissented from the Section 20 affiliate orders.[129]

Senator Proxmire criticized the Federal Reserve Board’s Section 20 affiliate orders as defying Congressional control of Glass–Steagall. The Board’s orders meant Glass–Steagall did not prevent commercial banks from affiliating with securities firms underwriting and dealing in “bank-ineligible securities,” so long as the activity was “executed in a separate subsidiary and limited in amount.”[130]

After the Proxmire Financial Modernization Act of 1988 failed to become law, Senator Proxmire and a group of fellow Democratic senior House Banking Committee members (including future Committee Ranking Member John LaFalce (D-NY) and future Committee Chairman Barney Frank (D-MA)) wrote the Federal Reserve Board recommending it expand the underwriting powers of Section 20 affiliates.[131] Expressing sentiments that Representative James A. Leach (R-IA) repeated in 1996,[132] Proxmire declared “Congress has failed to do the job” and “[n]ow it’s time for the Fed to step in.”[133]

Following Senator Proxmire’s letter, in 1989 the Federal Reserve Board approved Section 20 affiliates underwriting corporate debt securities and increased from 5% to 10% the percentage of its revenue a Section 20 affiliate could earn from “bank-ineligible” activities. In 1990 the Board approved J.P. Morgan & Co. underwriting corporate stock. With the commercial (J.P. Morgan & Co.) and investment (Morgan Stanley) banking arms of the old “House of Morgan” both underwriting corporate bonds and stocks, Wolfgang Reinicke concluded the Federal Reserve Board order meant both firms now competed in “a single financial market offering both commercial and investment banking products,” which “Glass–Steagall sought to rule out.” Reinicke described this as “de facto repeal of Glass–Steagall.”[134]

No Federal Reserve Board order was necessary for Morgan Stanley to enter that “single financial market.” Glass–Steagall only prohibited investment banks from taking deposits, not from making commercial loans, and the prohibition on taking deposits had “been circumvented by the development of deposit equivalents”, such as the money market fund.[135] Glass–Steagall also did not prevent investment banks from affiliating with nonbank banks[48] or savings and loans.[49][136] Citing this competitive “inequality,” before the Federal Reserve Board approved any Section 20 affiliates, four large bank holding companies that eventually received Section 20 affiliate approvals (Chase, J.P. Morgan, Citicorp, and Bankers Trust) had threatened to give up their banking charters if they were not given greater securities powers.[137] Following the Federal Reserve Board’s approvals of Section 20 affiliates a commentator concluded that the Glass–Steagall “wall” between commercial banking and “the securities and investment business” was “porous” for commercial banks and “nonexistent to investment bankers and other nonbank entities.”[138]

Greenspan-led Federal Reserve Board

Alan Greenspan had replaced Paul Volcker as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board when Proxmire sent his 1988 letter recommending the Federal Reserve Board expand the underwriting powers of Section 20 affiliates. Greenspan testified to Congress in December 1987, that the Federal Reserve Board supported Glass–Steagall repeal.[139] Although Paul Volcker “had changed his position” on Glass–Steagall reform “considerably” during the 1980s, he was still “considered a conservative among the board members.” With Greenspan as Chairman, the Federal Reserve Board “spoke with one voice” in joining the FDIC and OCC in calling for Glass–Steagall repeal.[140]

By 1987 Glass–Steagall “repeal” had come to mean repeal of Sections 20 and 32. The Federal Reserve Board supported “repeal” of Glass–Steagall “insofar as it prevents bank holding companies from being affiliated with firms engaged in securities underwriting and dealing activities.”[141] The Board did not propose repeal of Glass Steagall Section 16 or 21. Bank holding companies, through separately capitalized subsidiaries, not commercial banks themselves directly, would exercise the new securities powers.[16]

Banks and bank holding companies had already gained important regulatory approvals for securities activities before Paul Volcker retired as Chairman of the Federal Reserve Board on August 11, 1987.[142] Aside from the Board’s authorizations for Section 20 affiliates and for bank private placements of commercial paper, by 1987 federal banking regulators had authorized banks or their affiliates to (1) sponsor closed end investment companies,[143] (2) sponsor mutual funds sold to customers in individual retirement accounts,[144] (3) provide customers full service brokerage (i.e., advice and brokerage),[145] and (4) sell bank assets through “securitizations.”[146]

In 1982 E. Gerald Corrigan, president of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis and a close Volcker colleague, published an influential essay titled “Are banks special?” in which he argued banks should be subject to special restrictions on affiliations because they enjoy special benefits (e.g., deposit insurance and Federal Reserve Bank loan facilities) and have special responsibilities (e.g., operating the payment system and influencing the money supply). The essay rejected the argument that it is “futile and unnecessary” to distinguish among the various types of companies in the “financial services industry.”[147]

While Paul Volcker’s January 1984, testimony to Congress repeated that banks are “special” in performing “a unique and critical role in the financial system and the economy,” he still testified in support of bank affiliates underwriting securities other than corporate bonds.[126] In its 1986 Annual Report the Volcker led Federal Reserve Board recommended that Congress permit bank holding companies to underwrite municipal revenue bonds, mortgage-backed securities, commercial paper, and mutual funds and that Congress “undertake hearings or other studies in the area of corporate underwriting.”[148] As described above, in the 1930s Glass–Steagall advocates had alleged that bank affiliate underwriting of corporate bonds created “conflicts of interest.”[33]

In early 1987 E. Gerald Corrigan, then president of the Federal Reserve Bank of New York, recommended a legislative “overhaul” to permit “financial holding companies” that would “in time” provide banking, securities, and insurance services (as authorized by the GLBA 12 years later).[149] In 1990 Corrigan testified to Congress that he rejected the “status quo” and recommended allowing banks into the “securities business” through financial service holding companies.[150]

In 1991 Paul Volcker testified to Congress in support of the Bush Administration proposal to repeal Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[151] Volcker rejected the Bush Administration proposal to permit affiliations between banks and commercial firms (i.e., non-financial firms) and added that legislation to allow banks greater insurance powers “could be put off until a later date.”[152]

1991 Congressional action and “firewalls”

Paul Volcker gave his 1991 testimony as Congress considered repealing Glass–Steagall sections 20 and 32 as part of a broader Bush Administration proposal to reform financial regulation.[153] In reaction to “market developments” and regulatory and judicial decisions that had “homogenized” commercial and investment banking, Representative Edward J. Markey (D-MA) had written a 1990 article arguing “Congress must amend Glass–Steagall.”[154] As chairman of a subcommittee of the House Commerce and Energy Committee, Markey had joined with Committee Chairman Dingell in opposing the 1988 Proxmire Financial Modernization Act. In 1990, however, Markey stated Glass–Steagall had “lost much of its effectiveness” through market, regulatory, and judicial developments that were “tantamount to an ill-coordinated, incremental repeal” of Glass–Steagall. To correct this “disharmony” Markey proposed replacing Glass–Steagall’s “prohibitions” with “regulation.”[155] After the House Banking Committee approved a bill repealing Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, Representative Dingell again stopped House action. He reached agreement with Banking Committee Chairman Henry B. Gonzalez (D-TX) to insert into the bill “firewalls” that banks claimed would prevent real competition between banks and securities firms.[156] The banking industry strongly opposed the bill in that form, and the House rejected it. The House debate revealed that Congress might agree on repealing Sections 20 and 32 while being divided on how bank affiliations with securities firms should be regulated.[157]

1980s and 1990s bank product developments

Throughout the 1980s and 1990s, as Congress considered whether to “repeal” Glass–Steagall, commercial banks and their affiliates engaged in activities that commentators later linked to the late-2000s financial crisis.[158]

Securitization, CDOs, and “subprime” credit

In 1978 Bank of America issued the first residential mortgage-backed security that securitized residential mortgages not guaranteed by a government-sponsored enterprise (“private label RMBS”).[71] Also in 1978, the OCC approved a national bank, such as Bank of America, issuing pass-through certificates representing interests in residential mortgages and distributing such mortgage-backed securities to investors in a private placement.[87] In 1987 the OCC ruled that Security Pacific Bank could “sell” assets through “securitizations” that transferred “cash flows” from those assets to investors and also distribute in a registered public offering the residential mortgage-backed securities issued in the securitization.[159] This permitted commercial banks to acquire assets for “sale” through securitizations under what later became termed the “originate to distribute” model of banking.[160]

The OCC ruled that a national bank’s power to sell its assets meant a national bank could sell a pool of assets in a securitization, and even distribute the securities that represented the sale, as part of the “business of banking.”[161] This meant national banks could underwrite and distribute securities representing such sales, even though Glass–Steagall would generally prohibit a national bank underwriting or distributing non-governmental securities (i.e., non-“bank-eligible” securities).[162] The federal courts upheld the OCC’s approval of Security Pacific’s securitization activities, with the Supreme Court refusing in 1990 to review a 1989 Second Circuit decision sustaining the OCC’s action. In arguing that the GLBA’s “repeal” of Glass–Steagall played no role in the late-2000s financial crisis, Melanie Fein notes courts had confirmed by 1990 the power of banks to securitize their assets under Glass–Steagall.[163]

The Second Circuit stated banks had been securitizing their assets for “ten years” before the OCC’s 1987 approval of Security Pacific’s securitization.[164] As noted above, the OCC had approved such activity in 1978.[87] Jan Kregel argues that the OCC’s interpretation of the “incidental powers” of national banks “ultimately eviscerated Glass–Steagall.”[128]

Continental Illinois Bank is often credited with issuing the first collateralized debt obligation (CDO) when, in 1987, it issued securities representing interests in a pool of “leveraged loans.”[165]

By the late 1980s Citibank had become a major provider of “subprime” mortgages and credit cards.[166] Arthur Wilmarth argued that the ability to securitize such credits encouraged banks to extend more “subprime” credit.[167] Wilmarth reported that during the 1990s credit card loans increased at a faster pace for lower-income households than higher-income households and that subprime mortgage loan volume quadrupled from 1993–99, before the GLBA became effective in 2000.[168] In 1995 Wilmarth noted that commercial bank mortgage lenders differed from nonbank lenders in retaining “a significant portion of their mortgage loans” rather than securitizing the entire exposure.[169] Wilmarth also shared the bank regulator concern that commercial banks sold their “best assets” in securitizations and retained their riskiest assets.[170]

ABCP conduits and SIVs

In the early 1980s commercial banks established asset backed commercial paper conduits (ABCP conduits) to finance corporate customer receivables. The ABCP conduit purchased receivables from the bank customer and issued asset-backed commercial paper to finance that purchase. The bank “advising” the ABCP conduit provided loan commitments and “credit enhancements” that supported repayment of the commercial paper. Because the ABCP conduit was owned by a third party unrelated to the bank, it was not an affiliate of the bank.[171] Through ABCP conduits banks could earn “fee income” and meet “customers’ needs for credit” without “the need to maintain the amount of capital that would be required if loans were extended directly” to those customers.[172]

By the late 1980s Citibank had established ABCP conduits to buy securities. Such conduits became known as structured investment vehicles (SIVs).[173] The SIV’s “arbitrage” opportunity was to earn the difference between the interest earned on the securities it purchased and the interest it paid on the ABCP and other securities it issued to fund those purchases.[174]

OTC derivatives, including credit default swaps

In the early 1980s commercial banks began entering into interest rate and currency exchange “swaps” with customers. This “over-the-counter derivatives” market grew dramatically throughout the 1980s and 1990s.[175]

In 1996 the OCC issued “guidelines” for national bank use of “credit default swaps” and other “credit derivatives.” Banks entered into “credit default swaps” to protect against defaults on loans. Banks later entered into such swaps to protect against defaults on securities. Banks acted both as “dealers” in providing such protection (or speculative “exposure”) to customers and as “hedgers” or “speculators” to cover (or create) their own exposures to such risks.[176]

Commercial banks became the largest dealers in swaps and other over-the-counter derivatives. Banking regulators ruled that swaps (including credit default swaps) were part of the “business of banking,” not “securities” under the Glass–Steagall Act.[177]

Commercial banks entered into swaps that replicated part or all of the economics of actual securities. Regulators eventually ruled banks could even buy and sell equity securities to “hedge” this activity.[177] Jan Kregel argues the OCC’s approval of bank derivatives activities under bank “incidental powers” constituted a “complete reversal of the original intention of preventing banks from dealing in securities on their own account.”[128]

Glass–Steagall developments from 1995 to Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act

Leach and Rubin support for Glass–Steagall “repeal”; need to address “market realities”

On January 4, 1995, the new Chairman of the House Banking Committee, Representative James A. Leach (R-IA), introduced a bill to repeal Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[178] After being confirmed as Treasury Secretary Robert Rubin announced on February 28, 1995, that the Clinton Administration supported such Glass–Steagall repeal.[179] Repeating themes from the 1980s, Leach stated Glass–Steagall was “out of synch with reality”[180] and Rubin argued “it is now time for the laws to reflect changes in the world’s financial system.”[179]

Leach and Rubin expressed a widely shared view that Glass–Steagall was “obsolete” or “outdated.”[181] As described above, Senator Proxmire[103] and Representative Markey[155] (despite their long-time support for Glass–Steagall) had earlier expressed the same conclusion. With his reputation for being “conservative” on expanded bank activities,[140] former Federal Reserve Board Chairman Paul Volcker remained an influential commentator on legislative proposals to permit such activities.[182] Volcker continued to testify to Congress in opposition to permitting banks to affiliate with commercial companies and in favor of repealing Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 as part of “rationalizing” bank involvement in securities markets.[183] Supporting the Leach and Rubin arguments, Volcker testified that Congressional inaction had forced banking regulators and the courts to play “catch-up” with market developments by “sometimes stretching established interpretations of law beyond recognition.”[184] In 1997 Volcker testified this meant the “Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking is now almost gone” and that this “accommodation and adaptation has been necessary and desirable.”[185] He stated, however, that the “ad hoc approach” had created “uneven results” that created “almost endless squabbling in the courts” and an “increasingly advantageous position competitively” for “some sectors of the financial service industry and particular institutions.”[185] Similar to the GAO in 1988[118] and Representative Markey in 1990[155] Volcker asked that Congress “provide clear and decisive leadership that reflects not parochial pleadings but the national interest.”[185]

Reflecting the regulatory developments Volcker noted, the commercial and investment banking industries largely reversed their traditional Glass–Steagall positions. Throughout the 1990s (and particularly in 1996), commercial banking firms became content with the regulatory situation Volcker described. They feared “financial modernization” legislation might bring an unwelcome change.[186] Securities firms came to view Glass–Steagall more as a barrier to expanding their own commercial banking activities than as protection from commercial bank competition. The securities industry became an advocate for “financial modernization” that would open a “two way street” for securities firms to enter commercial banking.[187]

Status of arguments from 1980s

While the need to create a legal framework for existing bank securities activities became a dominant theme for the “financial modernization” legislation supported by Leach, Rubin, Volcker, and others, after the GLBA repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 in 1999, commentators identified four main arguments for repeal: (1) increased economies of scale and scope, (2) reduced risk through diversification of activities, (3) greater convenience and lower cost for consumers, and (4) improved ability of U.S. financial firms to compete with foreign firms.[188]

By 1995, however, some of these concerns (which had been identified by the Congressional Research Service in 1987[116]) seemed less important. As Japanese banks declined and U.S.-based banks were more profitable, “international competitiveness” did not seem to be a pressing issue.[189] International rankings of banks by size also seemed less important when, as Alan Greenspan later noted, “Federal Reserve research had been unable to find economies of scale in banking beyond a modest size.”[190] Still, advocates of “financial modernization” continued to point to the combination of commercial and investment banking in nearly all other countries as an argument for “modernization”, including Glass–Steagall “repeal.”[191]

Similarly, the failure of the Sears Financial Network and other nonbank “financial supermarkets” that had seemed to threaten commercial banks in the 1980s undermined the argument that financial conglomerates would be more efficient than “specialized” financial firms.[192] Critics questioned the “diversification benefits” of combining commercial and investment banking activities. Some questioned whether the higher variability of returns in investment banking would stabilize commercial banking firms through “negative correlation” (i.e., cyclical downturns in commercial and investment banking occurring at different times) or instead increase the probability of the overall banking firm failing.[193][194] Others questioned whether any theoretical benefits in holding a passive “investment portfolio” combining commercial and investment banking would be lost in managing the actual combination of such activities.[195] Critics also argued that specialized, highly competitive commercial and investment banking firms were more efficient in competitive global markets.[196]

Starting in the late 1980s, John H. Boyd, a staff member of the Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, consistently questioned the value of size and product diversification in banking.[193][197] In 1999, as Congress was considering legislation that became the GLBA, he published an essay arguing that the “moral hazard” created by deposit insurance, too big to fail (TBTF) considerations, and other governmental support for banking should be resolved before commercial banking firms could be given “universal banking” powers.[198] Although Boyd’s 1999 essay was directed at “universal banking” that permitted commercial banks to own equity interests in non-financial firms (i.e., “commercial firms”), the essay was interpreted more broadly to mean that “expanding bank powers, by, for example, allowing nonbank firms to affiliate with banks, prior to undertaking reforms limiting TBTF-like coverage for uninsured bank creditors is putting the ‘cart before the horse.’”[199]

Despite these arguments, advocates of “financial modernization” predicted consumers and businesses would enjoy cost savings and greater convenience in receiving financial services from integrated “financial services firms.”[200]

After the GLBA repealed Sections 20 and 32, commentators also noted the importance of scholarly attacks on the historic justifications for Glass–Steagall as supporting repeal efforts.[201] Throughout the 1990s, scholars continued to produce empirical studies concluding that commercial bank affiliate underwriting before Glass–Steagall had not demonstrated the “conflicts of interest” and other defects claimed by Glass–Steagall proponents.[202] By the late 1990s a “remarkably broad academic consensus” existed that Glass–Steagall had been “thoroughly discredited.”[203]

Although he rejected this scholarship, Martin Mayer wrote in 1997 that since the late 1980s it had been “clear” that continuing the Glass–Steagall prohibitions was only “permitting a handful of large investment houses and hedge funds to charge monopoly rents for their services without protecting corporate America, investors, or the banks.”[204]Hyman Minsky, who disputed the benefits of “universal banking,” wrote in 1995 testimony prepared for Congress that “repeal of the Glass–Steagall Act, in itself, would neither benefit nor harm the economy of the United States to any significant extent.”[205] In 1974 Mayer had quoted Minsky as stating a 1971 presidential commission (the “Hunt Commission”) was repeating the errors of history when it proposed relaxing Glass–Steagall and other legislation from the 1930s.[206]

With banking commentators such as Mayer and Minsky no longer opposing Glass–Steagall repeal, consumer and community development advocates became the most prominent critics of repeal and of financial “modernization” in general. Helen Garten argued that bank regulation became dominated by “consumer” issues, which produced “a largely unregulated, sophisticated wholesale market and a highly regulated, retail consumer market.”[207] In the 1980s Representative Fernand St. Germain (D-RI), as chairman of the House Banking Committee, sought to tie any Glass–Steagall reform to requirements for free or reduced cost banking services for the elderly and poor.[208] Democratic Representatives and Senators made similar appeals in the 1990s.[209] During Congressional hearings to consider the various Leach bills to repeal Sections 20 and 32, consumer and community development advocates warned against the concentration of “economic power” that would result from permitting “financial conglomerates” and argued that any repeal of Sections 20 and 32 should mandate greater consumer protections, particularly free or low cost consumer services, and greater community reinvestment requirements.[210][211]

Failed 1995 Leach bill; expansion of Section 20 affiliate activities; merger of Travelers and Citicorp

By 1995 the ability of banks to sell insurance was more controversial than Glass–Steagall “repeal.” Representative Leach tried to avoid conflict with the insurance industry by producing a limited “modernization” bill that repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, but did not change the regulation of bank insurance activities.[212] Leach’s efforts to separate insurance from securities powers failed when the insurance agent lobby insisted any banking law reform include limits on bank sales of insurance.[213]

Similar to Senator Proxmire in 1988,[133] Representative Leach responded to the House’s inaction on his Glass–Steagall “repeal” bill by writing the Federal Reserve Board in June 1996 encouraging it to increase the limit on Section 20 affiliate bank-ineligible revenue.[132] When the Federal Reserve Board increased the limit to 25% in December 1996, the Board noted the Securities Industry Association (SIA) had complained this would mean even the largest Wall Street securities firms could affiliate with commercial banks.[214]

The SIA’s prediction proved accurate two years later when the Federal Reserve Board applied the 25% bank-ineligible revenue test in approving Salomon Smith Barney (SSB) becoming an affiliate of Citibank through the merger of Travelers and Citicorp to form the Citigroup bank holding company. The Board noted that, although SSB was one of the largest US securities firms, less than 25% of its revenue was “bank-ineligible.”[215] Citigroup could only continue to own the Travelers insurance underwriting business for two (or, with Board approval, five) years unless the Bank Holding Company Act was amended (as it was through the GLBA) to permit affiliations between banks and underwriters of property, casualty, and life insurance. Citigroup’s ownership of SSB, however, was permitted without any law change under the Federal Reserve Board’s existing Section 20 affiliate rules.[5]

In 2003, Charles Geisst, a Glass–Steagall supporter, told Frontline the Federal Reserve Board’s Section 20 orders meant the Federal Reserve “got rid of the Glass–Steagall Act.”[216] Former Federal Reserve Board Vice-Chairman Alan Blinder agreed the 1996 action increasing “bank-ineligible” revenue limits was “tacit repeal” of Glass–Steagall, but argued “that the market had practically repealed Glass–Steagall, anyway.”[217]

Shortly after approving the merger of Citicorp and Travelers, the Federal Reserve Board announced its intention to eliminate the 28 “firewalls” that required separation of Section 20 affiliates from their affiliated bank and to replace them with “operating standards” based on 8 of the firewalls. The change permitted banks to lend to fund purchases of, and otherwise provide credit support to, securities underwritten by their Section 20 affiliates.[218] This left Federal Reserve Act Sections 23A (which originated in the 1933 Banking Act and regulated extensions of credit between a bank and any nonbank affiliate) and 23B (which required all transactions between a bank and its nonbank affiliates to be on “arms-length” market terms) as the primary restrictions on banks providing credit to Section 20 affiliates or to securities underwritten by those affiliates.[219] Sections 23A and B remained the primary restrictions on commercial banks extending credit to securities affiliates, or to securities underwritten by such affiliates, after the GLBA repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[220]

1997-98 legislative developments: commercial affiliations and Community Reinvestment Act

In 1997 Representative Leach again sponsored a bill to repeal Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32. At first the main controversy was whether to permit limited affiliations between commercial firms and commercial banks.[221] Securities firms (and other financial services firms) complained that unless they could retain their affiliations with commercial firms (which the Bank Holding Company Act forbid for a commercial bank), they would not be able to compete equally with commercial banks.[222] The Clinton Administration proposed that Congress either permit a small “basket” of commercial revenue for bank holding companies or that it retain the “unitary thrift loophole” that permitted a commercial firm to own a single savings and loan.[223] Representative Leach, House Banking Committee Ranking Member Henry Gonzalez (D-TX), and former Federal Reserve Board Chairman Paul Volcker opposed such commercial affiliations.[224]

Meanwhile, in 1997 Congressional Quarterly reported Senate Banking Committee Chairman Al D’Amato (R-NY) rejected Treasury Department pressure to produce a financial modernization bill because banking firms (such as Citicorp) were satisfied with the competitive advantages they had received from regulatory actions and were not really interested in legislative reforms.[225] Reflecting the process Paul Volcker had described,[185] as financial reform legislation was considered throughout 1997 and early 1998, Congressional Quarterly reported how different interests groups blocked legislation and sought regulatory advantages.[226]

The “compromise bill” the House Republican leadership sought to bring to a vote in March 1998, was opposed by the commercial banking industry as favoring the securities and insurance industries.[227] The House Republican leadership withdrew the bill in response to the banking industry opposition, but vowed to bring it back when Congress returned from recess.[228] Commentators describe the April 6, 1998, merger announcement between Travelers and Citicorp as the catalyst for the House passing that bill by a single vote (214-213) on May 13, 1998.[229] Citicorp, which had opposed the bill in March, changed its position to support the bill along with the few other large commercial banking firms that had supported it in March for improving their ability to compete with “foreign banks.”[230]

The Clinton Administration issued a veto threat for the House passed bill, in part because the bill would eliminate “the longstanding right of unitary thrift holding companies to engage in any lawful business,” but primarily because the bill required national banks to conduct expanded activities through holding company subsidiaries rather than the bank “operating subsidiaries” authorized by the OCC in 1996.[231]

On September 11, 1998, the Senate Banking Committee approved a bipartisan bill with unanimous Democratic member support that, like the House-passed bill, would have repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[232] The bill was blocked from Senate consideration by the Committee’s two dissenting members (Phil Gramm (R-TX) and Richard Shelby (R-AL)), who argued it expanded the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA). Four Democratic senators (Byron Dorgan (D-ND), Russell Feingold (D-WI), Barbara Mikulski (D-MD), and Paul Wellstone (D-MN)) stated they opposed the bill for its repeal of Sections 20 and 32.[210][233]

1999 Gramm–Leach–Bliley Act

In 1999 the main issues confronting the new Leach bill to repeal Sections 20 and 32 were (1) whether bank subsidiaries (“operating subsidiaries”) or only nonbank owned affiliates could exercise new securities and other powers and (2) how the CRA would apply to the new “financial holding companies” that would have such expanded powers.[234] The Clinton Administration agreed with Representative Leach in supporting “the continued separation of banking and commerce.”[235]

The Senate Banking Committee approved in a straight party line 11-9 vote a bill (S. 900) sponsored by Senator Gramm that would have repealed Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 and that did not contain the CRA provisions in the Committee’s 1998 bill. The nine dissenting Democratic Senators, along with Senate Minority Leader Thomas Daschle(D-SD), proposed as an alternative (S. 753) the text of the 1998 Committee bill with its CRA provisions and the repeal of Sections 20 and 32, modified to provide greater permission for “operating subsidiaries” as requested by the Treasury Department.[236] Through a partisan 54-44 vote on May 6, 1999 (with Senator Fritz Hollings (D-SC) providing the only Democratic Senator vote in support), the Senate passed S. 900. The day before, Senate Republicans defeated (in a 54-43 vote) a Democratic sponsored amendment to S. 900 that would have substituted the text of S. 753 (also providing for the repeal of Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32).[237]

On July 1, 1999, the House of Representatives passed (in a bipartisan 343-86 vote) a bill (H.R. 10) that repealed Sections 20 and 32. The Clinton Administration issued a statement supporting H.R. 10 because (unlike the Senate passed S. 900) it accepted the bill’s CRA and operating subsidiary provisions.[238]

On October 13, 1999, the Federal Reserve and Treasury Department agreed that direct subsidiaries of national banks (“financial subsidiaries”) could conduct securities activities, but that bank holding companies would need to engage in merchant banking, insurance, and real estate development activities through holding company, not bank, subsidiaries.[239] On October 22, 1999, Senator Gramm and the Clinton Administration agreed a bank holding company could only become a “financial holding company” (and thereby enjoy the new authority to affiliate with insurance and securities firms) if all its bank subsidiaries had at least a “satisfactory” CRA rating.[240]

After these compromises, a joint Senate and House Conference Committee reported out a final version of S. 900 that was passed on November 4, 1999, by the House in a vote of 362-57 and by the Senate in a vote of 90-8. President Clinton signed the bill into law on November 12, 1999, as the Gramm–Leach–Bliley Financial Modernization Act of 1999 (GLBA).[241]

The GLBA repealed Sections 20 and 32 of the Glass–Steagall Act, not Sections 16 and 21.[17] The GLBA also amended Section 16 to permit “well capitalized” commercial banks to underwrite municipal revenue bonds (i.e., non-general obligation bonds),[242] as first approved by the Senate in 1967.[84] Otherwise, Sections 16 and 21 remained in effect regulating the direct securities activities of banks and prohibiting securities firms from taking deposits.[17]

After March 11, 2000, bank holding companies could expand their securities and insurance activities by becoming “financial holding companies.”[243]

Commentator response to Section 20 and 32 repeal

President Bill Clinton’s signing statement for the GLBA summarized the established argument for repealing Glass–Steagall Section’s 20 and 32 in stating that this change, and the GLBA’s amendments to the Bank Holding Company Act, would “enhance the stability of our financial services system” by permitting financial firms to “diversify their product offerings and thus their sources of revenue” and make financial firms “better equipped to compete in global financial markets.”[244]

With Salomon Smith Barney already operating as a Section 20 affiliate of Citibank under existing law, commentators did not find much significance in the GLBA’s repeal of Sections 20 and 32. Many commentators noted those sections “were dead” before the GLBA.[4]

The GLBA’s amendment to the Bank Holding Company Act to permit banks to affiliate with insurance underwriting companies was a new power. Under a 1982 amendment to the Bank Holding Company Act bank affiliates had been prohibited from underwriting most forms of insurance.[245] Because the GLBA permitted banks to affiliate with insurance underwriters, Citigroup was able to retain ownership of the Travelers insurance underwriting business.[5] Overall, however, commentators viewed the GLBA “as ratifying and extending changes that had already been made, rather than as revolutionary.”[246] At least one commentator found the entire GLBA “unnecessary” for banks and suggested the OCC had the authority to grant national banks all the insurance underwriting powers permitted to affiliates through the GLBA.[247]

As John Boyd had earlier,[197] Minneapolis Federal Reserve Bank president Gary Stern and Arthur Wilmarth warned that the GLBA’s permission for broader combinations of banking, securities, and insurance activities could increase the “too big to fail” problem.[248]

Financial industry developments after repeal of Sections 20 and 32

Citigroup gives up insurance underwriting

The GLBA permitted Citigroup to retain the Travelers property, casualty, and life insurance underwriting businesses beyond the five-year “divestiture” period the Federal Reserve Board could have permitted under the pre-GLBA form of the BHCA.[5] Before that five-year period elapsed, however, Citigroup spun off the Travelers property and casualty insurance business to Citigroup’s shareholders.[249] In 2005 Citigroup sold to Metropolitan Life the Travelers life insurance business.[250] Commentators noted that Citigroup was left with selling insurance underwritten by third parties, a business it could have conducted without the GLBA.[251]

Banking, insurance, and securities industries remain structurally unchanged

In November 2003 the Federal Reserve Board and the Treasury Department issued to Congress a report (Joint Report) on the activities of the “financial holding companies” (FHCs) authorized by the GLBA and the effect of mergers or acquisitions by FHCs on market concentration in the financial services industry.[252] According to the Joint Report, 12% of all bank holding companies had qualified as financial holding companies to exercise the new powers provided by the GLBA, and those companies held 78% of all bank holding company assets.[253] 40 of the 45 bank holding companies with Section 20 affiliates before 2000 had qualified as financial holding companies, and their securities related assets had nearly doubled.[254] The great majority of this increase was at non-U.S. based banks. Such foreign banking companies had acquired several medium sized securities firms (such as UBS acquiring Paine Webber and Credit Suisse acquiring Donaldson, Lufkin & Jenrette).[255]

Despite these increases in securities activities by bank holding companies that qualified as financial holding companies, the Joint Report found that concentration levels among securities underwriting and dealing firms had not changed significantly since 1999.[256] Ranked by capital levels, none of the four largest securities dealing and underwriting firms was affiliated with a financial holding company.[257] Although the market share of financial holding companies among the 25 largest securities firms had increased by 5.7 percentage points from that held in 1999 before the GLBA became effective, all of the increase came from foreign banks increasing their U.S. securities operations.[257] The combined market share of the five largest U.S. based financial holding companies declined by 1 percentage point from 1999–2003, with the largest, Citigroup, experiencing a 2.4 percentage point reduction from 1999–2003.[257] Of the 45 bank holding companies that had operated Section 20 affiliates before the GLBA, 40 had qualified as financial holding companies, 2 conducted securities underwriting and dealing through direct bank subsidiaries (i.e., “financial subsidiaries”), and 3 continued to operate Section 20 affiliates subject to pre-GLBA rules.[258]

In a speech delivered shortly before the Joint Report was released, Federal Reserve Board Vice Chairman Roger Ferguson stated that the Federal Reserve had “not been able to uncover any evidence that the overall market structure of the [banking, insurance, and securities] segments of the financial services industry has substantially changed” since the GLBA.[259] Early in 2004, the Financial Times reported that “financial supermarkets” were failing around the world, as both diversification and larger size failed to increase profitability.[260] The Congressional Research Service noted that after the GLBA became law the financial services markets in the United States “had not really integrated” as mergers and consolidations occurred “largely within sectors” without the expected “wholesale integration in financial services.”[261]

At a July 13, 2004, Senate Banking Committee hearing on the effects of the GLBA five years after passage, the Legislative Director of the Consumer Federation cited Roger Ferguson’s 2003 speech and stated the “extravagant promises” of universal banking had “proven to be mostly hype.” He noted that advocates of repealing Sections 20 and 32 had said “[b]anks, securities firms, and insurance companies would merge into financial services supermarkets” and, after five years, some mergers had occurred “but mostly within the banking industry, not across sectors.”[262] Within the banking industry, Federal Reserve Board Chairman Alan Greenspan testified to Congress in 2004 that commercial bank consolidation had “slowed sharply in the past five years.”[263]

At the five-year anniversary of the GLBA in November 2004, the American Banker quoted then retiring Comptroller of the Currency John D. Hawke, Jr. and former FDIC Chairman William Seidman as stating the GLBA had been less significant than expected in not bringing about the combinations of banking, insurance, and investment banking. Hawke described the GLBA provisions permitting such combinations as “pretty much a dead letter.”[264] Although the article noted other commentators expected this would change in 2005, a May 24, 2005, American Banker article proclaimed 2005 the “year of divestiture” as “many observers” described Citigroup’s sale of the Travelers life and annuity insurance business as “a nail in the coffin of financial services convergence.”[250]

In 2005 the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank’s staff issued a study finding that after five years the GLBA’s effects “have been modest” and the new law “simply made it easier for organizations to continue to engage in the activities they had already undertaken.”[265]

Competition between commercial banking and investment banking firms

Commentators pointed to the Enron, WorldCom, and other corporate scandals of the early 2000s as exposing the dangers of uniting commercial and investment banking.[266] More broadly, Arthur Wilmarth questioned whether those scandals and the “stock market bubble” of the late-1990s were linked to the growing role of commercial banks in the securities markets during the 1990s.[267] As Wilmarth’s article indicated, the identified bank or bank affiliate activities linked to the Enron and World Com corporate scandals began in 1996 (or earlier) and most occurred before March 11, 2000, when bank holding companies could first use the new securities powers the GLBA provided to “financial holding companies.”[268]

In the 1990s investment banks complained that commercial banking firms with Section 20 affiliates had coerced customers into hiring the Section 20 affiliate to underwrite securities in order to receive loans from the affiliated bank, which would have violated the “anti-tying” provisions of the Bank Holding Company Act. In 1997 the GAO issued a report reviewing those claims.[269] After the GLBA became law, investment banks continued to claim such illegal “tying” was being practiced. In 2003 the GAO issued another report reviewing those claims.[270]

Partly because of the “tying” issue many commentators expected investment banking firms would need to convert into bank holding companies (and qualify as financial holding companies) to compete with commercial bank affiliated securities firms.[271] No major investment bank, however, became a bank holding company until 2008 in the midst of the late-2000s financial crisis. Then all five major “free standing” investment banks (i.e., those not part of a bank holding company)[272] entered bankruptcy proceedings (Lehman Brothers), were acquired by bank holding companies (Bear Stearns by JP Morgan Chase and Merrill Lynch by Bank of America), or became bank holding companies by converting their industrial loan companies (“nonbank banks”) into a national (Morgan Stanley) or state chartered Federal Reserve member bank (Goldman Sachs).[273]

At the July 13, 2004, Senate Banking Committee hearing on the GLBA’s effects, the Securities Industry Association representative explained securities firms had not taken advantage of the GLBA’s “financial holding company” powers because that would have required them to end affiliations with commercial firms by 2009.[274] GLBA critics had complained that the law had prevented insurance and securities firms from truly entering the banking business by making a “faulty” distinction between commercial and financial activities.[275]

The Consumer Federation of America and other commentators suggested securities firms had avoided becoming “financial holding companies” because they wanted to avoid Federal Reserve supervision as bank holding companies.[276] The SEC (through its Chairman Arthur Levitt) had supported efforts to permit securities firms to engage in non-FDIC insured banking activities without the Federal Reserve’s “intrusive banking-style oversight” of the “overall holding company.”[277] After the GLBA became law, securities firms continued (and expanded) their deposit and lending activities through the “unitary thrifts” and “nonbank banks” (particularly industrial loan companies) they had used before the GLBA to avoid regulation as bank holding companies.[278] Alan Greenspan later noted securities firms only took on the “embrace” of Federal Reserve Board supervision as bank holding companies (and financial holding companies) after the financial crisis climaxed in September 2008.[279]

Melanie Fein has described how the consolidation of the banking and securities industries occurred in the 1990s, particularly after the Federal Reserve Board’s actions in 1996 and 1997 increasing Section 20 “bank-ineligible” revenue limits and removing “firewalls.”[280] Fein stated that “[a]lthough the Gramm-Leach-Blily Act was expected to trigger a cascade of new consolidation proposals, no major mergers of banks and securities firms occurred in the years immediately following” and that the “consolidation trend resumed abruptly in 2008 as a result of the financial crisis” leading to all the large investment banks being acquired by, or converting into, bank holding companies.[281] Fein noted the lack of consolidation activity after 1999 and before September 2008 was “perhaps because much of the consolidation had occurred prior to the Act.”[282]

Commentators cite only three major financial firms from outside the banking industry (the discount broker Charles Schwab, the insurance company Met Life, and the mutual fund company Franklin Resources) for qualifying as financial holding companies after the GLBA became effective and before the late-2000s financial crisis.[283]

In 2011 the European Central Bank published a working paper that concluded commercial bank Section 20 affiliate underwriting of corporate bonds in the 1990s had been of lower quality than the underwriting of non-commercial bank affiliated securities firms.[284] The authors suggest the most likely explanation was that commercial bank affiliates “had to be initially more aggressive than investment bank houses in order to gain market share, and in pursuing this objective they might have loosened their credit standards excessively.”[285] The working paper only examined corporate bonds underwritten from 1991 through 1999, a period before the GLBA permitted financial holding companies.[286]

Glass–Steagall “repeal” and the financial crisis

Robert Kuttner, Joseph Stiglitz, Elizabeth Warren, Robert Weissman, Richard D. Wolff and others have tied Glass–Steagall repeal to the late-2000s financial crisis. Kuttner acknowledged “de facto enroads” before Glass–Steagall “repeal” but argued the GLBA’s “repeal” had permitted “super-banks” to “re-enact the same kinds of structural conflicts of interest that were endemic in the 1920s,” which he characterized as “lending to speculators, packaging and securitizing credits and then selling them off, wholesale or retail, and extracting fees at every step along the way.”[8] Stiglitz argued “the most important consequence of Glass–Steagall repeal” was in changing the culture of commercial banking so that the “bigger risk” culture of investment banking “came out on top.”[9] He also argued the GLBA “created ever larger banks that were too big to be allowed to fail,” which “provided incentives for excessive risk taking.”[287] Warren explained Glass–Steagall had kept banks from doing “crazy things.” She credited FDIC insurance, the Glass–Steagall separation of investment banking, and SEC regulations as providing “50 years without a crisis” and argued that crises returned in the 1980s with the “pulling away of the threads” of regulation.[288] Weissman agrees with Stiglitz that the “most important effect” of Glass–Steagall “repeal” was to “change the culture of commercial banking to emulate Wall Street's high-risk speculative betting approach.”[289]

Lawrence White and Jerry Markham rejected these claims and argued that products linked to the financial crisis were not regulated by Glass–Steagall or were available from commercial banks or their affiliates before the GLBA repealed Glass–Steagall sections 20 and 32.[11]Alan Blinder wrote in 2009 that he had “yet to hear a good answer” to the question “what bad practices would have been prevented if Glass–Steagall was still on the books?” Blinder argued that “disgraceful” mortgage underwriting standards “did not rely on any new GLB powers,” that “free-standing investment banks” not the “banking-securities conglomerates” permitted by the GLBA were the major producers of “dodgy MBS,” and that he could not “see how this crisis would have been any milder if GLB had never passed.”[290] Similarly, Melanie Fein has written that the financial crisis “was not a result of the GLBA” and that the “GLBA did not authorize any securities activities that were the cause of the financial crisis.”[291] Fein noted “[s]ecuritization was not an activity authorized by the GLBA but instead had been held by the courts in 1990 to be part of the business of banking rather than an activity proscribed by the Glass–Steagall Act.”[163] As described above, in 1978 the OCC approved a national bank securitizing residential mortgages.[87]

Carl Felsenfeld and David L. Glass wrote that “[t]he public—which for this purpose includes most of the members of Congress” does not understand that the investment banks and other “shadow banking” firms that experienced “runs” precipitating the financial crisis (i.e., AIG, Bear Stearns, Lehman Brothers, and Merrill Lynch) never became “financial holding companies” under the GLBA and, therefore, never exercised any new powers available through Glass–Steagall “repeal.”[292] They joined Jonathan R. Macey and Peter J. Wallison in noting many GLBA critics do not understand that Glass–Steagall’s restrictions on banks (i.e., Sections 16 and 21) remained in effect and that the GLBA only repealed the affiliation provisions in Sections 20 and 32.[293] The American Bankers Association, former President William J. Clinton, and others have argued that the GLBA permission for affiliations between securities and commercial banking firms “helped to mitigate” or “softened” the financial crisis by permitting bank holding companies to acquire troubled securities firms or such troubled firms to convert into bank holding companies.[12]

Martin Mayer argued there were “three reasonable arguments” for tying Glass–Steagall repeal to the financial crisis: (1) it invited banks to enter risks they did not understand; (2) it created “network integration” that increased contagion; and (3) it joined the incompatible businesses of commercial and investment banking. Mayer, however, then described banking developments in the 1970s and 1980s that had already established these conditions before the GLBA repealed Sections 20 and 32.[294] Mayer’s 1974 book The Bankers detailed the “revolution in banking” that followed Citibank establishing a liquid secondary market in “negotiable certificates of deposit” in 1961. This new “liability management” permitted banks to fund their activities through the “capital markets,” like nonbank lenders in the “shadow banking market,” rather than through the traditional regulated bank deposit market envisioned by the 1933 Banking Act.[295] In 1973 Sherman J. Maisel wrote of his time on the Federal Reserve Board and described how “[t]he banking system today is far different from what it was even in 1960” as “formerly little used instruments” were used in the “money markets” and “turned out to be extremely volatile.”[296]

In describing the “transformation of the U.S. financial services industry” from 1975-2000 (i.e., from after the “revolution in banking” described by Mayer in 1974 to the effective date of the GLBA), Arthur Wilmarth described how during the 1990s, despite remaining bank holding companies, J.P. Morgan & Co. and Bankers Trust “built financial profiles similar to securities firms with a heavy emphasis on trading and investments.”[297] In 1993, Helen Garten described the transformation of the same companies into “wholesale banks” similar to European “universal banks.”[298]

Jan Kregel agrees that “multifunction” banks are a source for financial crises, but he argues the “basic principles” of Glass–Steagall “were eviscerated even before” the GLBA.[299] Kregel describes Glass–Steagall as creating a “monopoly that was doomed to fail” because after World War II nonbanks were permitted to use “capital market activities” to duplicate more cheaply the deposit and commercial loan products for which Glass–Steagall had sought to provide a bank monopoly.[300]

While accepting that under Glass–Steagall financial firms could still have “made, sold, and securitized risky mortgages, all the while fueling a massive housing bubble and building a highly leveraged, Ponzi-like pyramid of derivatives on top,” the New Rules Project concludes that commentators who deny the GLBA played a role in the financial crisis “fail to recognize the significance of 1999 as the pivotal policy-making moment leading up to the crash.” The Project argues 1999 was Congress’s opportunity to reject 25 years of “deregulation” and “confront the changing financial system by reaffirming the importance of effective structural safeguards, such as the Glass–Steagall Act's firewall and market share caps to limit the size of banks; bringing shadow banks into the regulatory framework; and developing new rules to control the dangers inherent in derivatives and other engineered financial products.”[301]

Raj Date and Michael Konczal similarly argued that the GLBA did not create the financial crisis but that the implicit “logical premises” of the GLBA, which included a belief that “non-depository ‘shadow banks’ should continue to compete in the banking business,” “enabled the financial crisis” and “may well have hastened it.”[302]

Proposed reenactment

During the 2009 House of Representatives consideration of H.R. 4173, the bill that became the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, Representative Maurice Hinchey (D-NY) proposed an amendment to the bill that would have reenacted Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32 and also prohibited bank insurance activities. The amendment was not voted on by the House.[303]

On December 16, 2009, Senators John McCain (R-AZ) and Maria Cantwell (D-WA) introduced in the Senate the “Banking Integrity Act of 2009” (S.2886), which would have reinstated Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, but was not voted on by the Senate.[303][304]

Before the Senate acted on its version of what became the Dodd-Frank Act, the Congressional Research Service issued a report describing securities activities banks and their affiliates had conducted before the GLBA. The Report stated Glass–Steagall had “imperfectly separated, to a certain degree” commercial and investment banking and described the extensive securities activities the Federal Reserve Board had authorized for “Section 20 affiliates” since the 1980s.[305]

The Obama Administration has been criticized for opposing Glass–Steagall reenactment.[303][306] In 2009, Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner testified to the Joint Economic Committee that he opposed reenacting Glass–Steagall and that he did not believe “the end of Glass–Steagall played a significant role” in causing the financial crisis.[307]

On April 12, 2011, Representative Marcy Kaptur (D-OH) introduced in the House the “Return to Prudent Banking Act of 2011” (H.R. 1489), which would (1) amend the Federal Deposit Insurance Act to add prohibitions on FDIC insured bank affiliations instead of reenacting the affiliation restrictions in Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32, (2) direct federal banking regulators and courts to interpret these affiliation provisions and Glass–Steagall Sections 16 and 21 in accordance with the Supreme Court decision in Camp,[64] and (3) repeal various GLBA changes to the Bank Holding Company Act.[308]

On July 7, 2011, Representative Maurice D. Hinchey (D-NY) introduced in the House the “Glass–Steagall Restoration Act of 2011” (H.R. 2451), which would reinstate Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[309]

Volcker rule ban on proprietary trading as Glass–Steagall lite

The Dodd-Frank Act included the Volcker Rule, which among other things limited proprietary trading by banks and their affiliates.[310] This proprietary trading ban will generally prevent commercial banks and their affiliates from acquiring non-governmental securities with the intention of selling those securities for a profit in the “near term.”[311] Some have described the Volcker Rule, particularly its proprietary trading ban,[312] as “Glass–Steagall lite.”[313]

As described above, Glass–Steagall restricted commercial bank “dealing” in, not “trading” of, non-government securities the bank was permitted to purchase as “investment securities.”[41] After the GLBA became law, Glass–Steagall Section 16 continued to restrict bank securities purchases. The GLBA, however, expanded the list of “bank-eligible” securities to permit banks to buy, underwrite, and deal in municipal revenue bonds, not only “full faith and credit” government bonds.[242]

The Volcker Rule permits “market making” and other “dealer” activities in non-government securities as services for customers.[314] Glass–Steagall Section 16 prohibits banks from being a “market maker” or otherwise “dealing” in non-government (i.e., “bank-ineligible”) securities.[38] Glass–Steagall Section 16 permits a bank to purchase and sell (i.e., permits “trading”) for a bank’s own account non-government securities that the OCC approves as “investment securities.”[41] The Volcker Rule will prohibit such “proprietary trading” of non-government securities.[315]

Before and after the late-2000s financial crisis, banking regulators worried that banks were incorrectly reporting non-traded assets as held in their “trading account” because of lower regulatory capital requirements for assets held in a “trading account.”[316] Under the Volcker Rule, U.S. banking regulators have proposed that banks and their affiliates be prohibited from holding any asset (other than government securities and other listed exceptions) as a “trading position.”[317]

Senators Jeff Merkley (D-OR) and Carl Levin (D-MI) have written that “proprietary trading losses” played “a central role in bringing the financial system to its knees.” They wrote that the Volcker Rule’s proprietary trading ban contained in statutory language they proposed is a “modern Glass–Steagall” because Glass–Steagall was both “over-inclusive” (in prohibiting some “truly client-oriented activities that could be managed by developments in securities and banking law”) and “under-inclusive” in failing to cover derivatives trading.[318]

In 2002, Arthur Wilmarth wrote that from 1990-1997 the nine U.S. banks with the greatest securities activities held more than 20% of their assets as trading assets.[297] By 1997, 40% of J.P. Morgan’s revenue was from trading.[319] A 1995 study by the federal banking regulators of commercial bank trading activity from June 30, 1984, to June 30, 1994, concluded that “trading activities are an increasingly important source of revenue for banks” and that “[n]otwithstanding the numerous press reports that focus on negative events, the major commercial banks have experienced long-term success in serving customers and generating revenues with these activities.” In reporting the study results, the American Banker described “proprietary trading” as “basically securities trading not connected to customer-related bank activities“ and summarized the study as finding that “proprietary trading has been getting a bad rap.”[320]

Paul Volcker supported the Volcker Rule prohibition on proprietary trading as part of bringing commercial banks back to “concentrating on continuing customer interest.”[321] As described above, Volcker had long testified to Congress in support of repealing Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32.[126][151][183][322] In 2010 he explained that he understood Glass–Steagall as preventing banks from being principally engaged in underwriting and dealing in corporate securities. Volcker stated that with securitization and other developments he believes it is a proper bank function to underwrite corporate securities “as serving a legitimate customer need.” He, therefore, did not believe “repeal of Glass–Steagall was terrible” but that Congress “should have thought about what they replace it with.” Volcker’s criticism was that Congress “didn’t replace it with other restrictions.”[323]

Separate from its proprietary trading ban, the Volcker Rule restricts bank and affiliate sponsorship and ownership of hedge funds and private equity funds.[313] The GLBA amended the Bank Holding Company Act to permit “merchant banking” investments by bank affiliates subject to various restrictions.[324] It also authorized the Treasury Department and Federal Reserve Board to permit such merchant banking activities by direct bank subsidiaries (“financial subsidiaries”) after five years, but they have not provided such permission.[325] This was not a Glass–Steagall change but a change to the Bank Holding Company Act, which previously limited the size of investments bank affiliates could make in a company engaged in activities not “closely related to banking.”[326] Such merchant banking investments may be made through private equity funds.[327] The Volcker Rule will affect the ability of bank affiliates to make such investments.[328]

”Ring fencing” proposal in United Kingdom as Glass–Steagall substitute

The Independent Commission on Banking’s (ICB) proposal to “ring fence” retail and small business commercial banking from investment banking in the United Kingdom[329] has been described as comparable to the Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking.[330] The proposal seeks to isolate the “retail banking” functions of a banking firm within a separate corporation that would not be affected by the failure of the overall firm so long as the “ring fenced” retail bank itself remained solvent.[331]

Bank of England Governor Mervyn King expressed concern the European Commission could block implementation of the ICB proposal as a violation of Commission standards.[332] Although Michel Barnier, European Union internal market Commissioner, proposed limits on capital requirements for banks that could have hindered the UK ringfencing proposal and indicated support for the French and German position against breaking up banking groups, in November 2011 he announced an “expert commission” would “study the mandatory separation of risky investment banking activities from traditional retail lenders.”[333] On October 2, 2012, the committee appointed to study the issue recommended a form of “ring fencing” similar to the proposal in the United Kingdom.[334]

Glass–Steagall and “firewalls”

Congressional and bank regulator efforts to “repeal”, “reform” or apply Glass–Steagall were based on isolating a commercial banking firm’s expanded securities activities in a separately capitalized bank affiliate.[156][218] Much of the debate concerned whether such affiliates could be owned by a bank (as with “operating subsidiaries” in the 1990s) or would be bank holding company subsidiaries outside the chain of bank ownership.[239][335] In either case, “firewalls” were intended to isolate the bank from the affiliate.[336]

Banking regulators and commentators debated whether “firewalls” could truly separate a bank from its affiliate in a crisis and often cited the early 1980s’ statement by then Citicorp CEO Walter Wriston that “it is inconceivable that any major bank would walk away from any subsidiary of its holding company.”[337] Alan Greenspan and Paul Volcker testified to Congress that firewalls so strong that they truly separated different businesses would eliminate the benefits of combining the two activities.[338] Both testified that in a crisis the owners of the overall firm would inevitably find ways to use the assets of any solvent part of the firm to assist the troubled part.[338] Thus, “firewalls” sufficient to prevent a bank from assisting its affiliate would eliminate the purpose of the combination, but “workable” firewalls would be insufficient to prevent such assistance. Both Volcker and Greenspan proposed that the solution was adequate supervision, including sufficient capital and other requirements.[338]

In 1998 and 1999 Greenspan testified to Congress in opposition to the Clinton Administration proposal to permit national bank subsidiaries to engage in expanded securities and other activities. He argued such direct bank subsidiary activities would be “financed by the sovereign credit of the United States” through the “federal safety net” for banks, despite the Treasury Department’s assurance that “firewalls” between the bank and its operating subsidiary would prevent the expansion of the “federal safety net.”[339]

As described above, Gary Stern, Arthur Wilmarth, and others questioned whether either operating subsidiaries or separate holding company affiliates could be isolated from an affiliated bank in a financial crisis and feared that the “too big to fail” doctrine gave competitive benefits to banking firms entering the securities or insurance business through either structure.[248] Greenspan did not deny that the government might act to “manage an orderly liquidation” of a large financial “intermediary” in a crisis, but he suggested that only insured creditors would be fully repaid, that shareholders would be unprotected, and that uninsured creditors would receive less than full payment through a discount or “haircut.”[340] Commentators pointed to the 1990 failure of Drexel Burnham Lambert as suggesting “too-big-to-fail” considerations need not force a government rescue of creditors to a failing investment bank or other nonbank,[341] although Greenspan had pointed to that experience as questioning the ability of firewalls to isolate one part of a financial firm from the rest.[338]

After the late-2000s financial crisis commentators noted that the Federal Reserve Board used its power to grant exemptions from Federal Reserve Act Section 23A (part of the 1933 Banking Act and the “principle statutory” firewall between banks and their affiliates) to permit banks to “rescue” various affiliates or bank sponsored participants in the “shadow banking system” as part of a general effort to restore liquidity in financial markets.[342] Section 23A generally prevented banks from funding securities purchases by their affiliates before the financial crisis (i.e., prevented the affiliates from “using insured deposits to purchase risky investments”) by “limiting the ability of depository institutions to transfer to affiliates the subsidy arising from the institutions’ access to the federal safety net,” but the Federal Reserve Board’s exemptions allowed banks to shift the risk of such investments from the shadow banking market to FDIC insured banks during the crisis.[343] The Federal Reserve Board’s General Counsel has defended these actions by arguing that all the Section 23A exemptions required that bank funding be “fully collateralized” on a daily basis, so that the bank was “very much protected,” and that in the end the exemptions did not prove very “useful.”[344]

The ICB proposes to erect a barrier between the “ring-fenced bank” and its “wider corporate group” that will permit banking regulators to isolate the ring-fenced bank “from the rest of the group in a matter of days and continue the provision of its services without providing solvency support.”[345]

Limited purpose banking and narrow banking

Laurence Kotlikoff was disappointed the ICB did not adopt the “limited purpose banking” he proposed to the ICB.[346][347] This would require a bank to operate like a mutual fund in repaying “deposits” based on the current market value of the bank’s assets. Kotlikoff argues there will always be financial crises if banks lend deposits but are required to repay the full amount of those deposits “on demand.”[348] Kotlikoff would only permit a bank (i.e., mutual fund) to promise payment of deposits at “par” (i.e., $1 for every $1 deposited) if the bank (i.e., mutual fund) held 100% of all deposits in cash as a trustee.[347][349]

As Kotlikoff notes, in 1987 Robert Litan proposed “narrow banking.”[350] Litan suggested commercial banking firms be freed from Glass–Steagall limits (and other activity restrictions) so long as they isolated FDIC insured deposits in a “narrow bank” that was only permitted to invest those deposits in “safe securities” approved by the FDIC.[351] In 1995 Arthur Wilmarth proposed applying Litan’s “narrow bank” proposal to U.S. banks (“global banks”) that had become heavily involved in “capital markets” activities through “Section 20 affiliates,” derivatives, and other activities.[352] Under Wilmarth’s proposal (which he repeated in 2001 after the GLBA became law[353]) only banks that limited their activities to taking deposits and making commercial loans would be permitted to make commercial loans with FDIC insured deposits.[354] Wilmarth expected only “community banks” specialized in making consumer and small business loans would continue to operate as such traditional banks.[355] The large “global banks” would fund their lending through the capital markets just like investment banks and other “shadow banking” lenders.[356]

Wholesale financial institutions

In 1997 the Clinton Administration proposed that “wholesale financial institutions” (known as “woofies”) be authorized to be members of the Federal Reserve System but not “banks” under the Bank Holding Company Act because they would own non-FDIC insured banks that would only take deposits of $100,000 or more.[357] Whereas “narrow banks” would be FDIC insured, but only invest in FDIC approved “safe securities,” “woofies” would be free to lend, purchase securities, and make other investments, because they would not hold any FDIC insured deposits. The proposal was intended to permit securities firms to continue to maintain ownership of commercial firms while gaining access to the Federal Reserve’s “payment system” and “discount window”, so long as the firm did not take FDIC insured deposits.[358]

“Woofies” were not authorized by the GLBA because of a dispute between Senator Phil Gramm and the Clinton Administration over the application of the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) to “woofies.” In their October 1999 compromise on CRA provisions in the GLBA,[240] the Clinton Administration agreed with Gramm that CRA would not apply to woofies so long as only a company that did not then own any FDIC insured depository institution would be permitted to qualify as a “wholesale financial institution.”[359] The Clinton Administration wanted this restriction to prevent existing bank holding companies from disposing of their FDIC insured banks to qualify as “woofies,” which could reduce the deposit base subject to CRA requirements.[360] When Chase and J.P. Morgan lobbied to change the final legislation to permit them to become woofies, they complained only Goldman Sachs and “a few others” could qualify as a woofie.[359][360] When negotiators decided they could not resolve the dispute, permission for woofies was eliminated from the final GLBA.[359][360]

“Woofies” were similar to the “global bank” structure suggested by Arthur Wilmarth because they would not use FDIC insured deposits to make commercial loans. They would, however, be subject to Federal Reserve supervision unlike lenders in the unsupervised “shadow banking” system. Because woofies would have had access to the Federal Reserve discount window and payments service, critics (including the Independent Bankers Association of America and Paul Volcker) opposed woofies (and a similar 1996 proposal by Representative James A. Leach) for providing unfair competition to banks.[361] Although October 1999 press reports suggested bank holding companies were interested in becoming woofies,[359][360] the New York Times reported in July 1999 that banking and securities firms had lost interest in becoming woofies.[362]

Shadow banking

The ICB Report rejected “narrow banking” in part because it would lead to more credit (and all credit during times of stress) being provided by a “less regulated sector.”[363] In 1993 Jane D'Arista and Tom Schlesinger noted that the “parallel banking system” had grown because it did not incur the regulatory costs of commercial banks.[364] They proposed to equalize the cost by establishing “uniform regulation” of banks and the lenders and investors in the parallel banking system.[365] As with Kotlikoff’s “limited purpose banking” proposal, only investment pools funded 100% from equity interests would remain unregulated as banks.[366] Although D’Arista and Schlesinger acknowledged the regulation of banks and of the parallel banking system would end up only being “comparable,” their goal was to eliminate so far as possible the competitive advantages of the “parallel” or “shadow” banking market.[367]

Many commentators have argued that the failure to regulate the shadow banking market was a primary cause of the financial crisis.[302][368] There is general agreement that the crisis emerged in the shadow banking markets not in the traditional banking market.[369] As described above, Helen Garten had identified the “consumerization” of banking regulation as producing “a largely unregulated, sophisticated wholesale market,”[207] which created the risk of the “underproduction of regulation” of that market.[370]

Laurence Kotlikoff’s “limited purpose banking” proposal rejects bank regulation (based on rules and supervision to ensure “safety and soundness”) and replaces it with a prohibition on any company operating like a traditional “bank.” All limited liability financial companies (not only today’s “banks”) that receive money from the public for investment or “lending” and that issue promises to pay amounts in the future (whether as insurance companies, hedge funds, securities firms, or otherwise) could only issue obligations to repay amounts equal to the value of their assets.[347][371] All “depositors” in or “lenders” to such companies would become “investors” (as in a mutual fund) with the right to receive the full return on the investments made by the companies (minus fees) and obligated to bear the full loss on those investments.[347][372]

Thomas Hoenig rejects both “limited purpose banking” and the proposal to regulate shadow banking as part of the banking system. Hoenig argues it is not necessary to regulate “shadow banking system” lenders as banks if those lenders are prohibited from issuing liabilities that function like bank demand deposits. He suggests that requiring money market funds to redeem shares at the funds’ fluctuating daily net asset values would prevent those funds from functioning like bank checking accounts and that eliminating special Bankruptcy Code treatment for repurchase agreements would delay repayment of those transactions in a bankruptcy and thereby end their treatment as “cash equivalents” when the “repo” was funding illiquid, long term securities. By limiting the ability of “shadow banks” to compete with traditional banks in creating “money-like” instruments, Hoenig hopes to better assure that the safety net is not ultimately called upon to “bail them [i.e., shadow banks such as Bear Stearns and AIG during the financial crisis] out in a crisis.” He proposes to deal with actual commercial banks by imposing “Glass–Steagall-type boundaries” so that banks “that have access to the safety net should be restricted to certain core activities that the safety net was intended to protect—making loans and taking deposits—and related activities consistent with the presence of the safety net.”[373]

Glass–Steagall role in reform proposals in Europe and North America

Although the UK's ICB and the commentators presenting the proposals described above to modify banks or banking regulation address issues beyond the scope of the Glass–Steagall separation of commercial and investment banking, each specifically examines Glass–Steagall. The ICB stated Glass–Steagall had been “undermined in part by the development of derivatives.”[374] The ICB also argued that the development before 1999 of “the world’s leading investment banks out of the US despite Glass–Steagall in place at the time” should caution against assuming the “activity restrictions” it recommended in its “ringfencing” proposal would hinder UK investment banks from competing internationally.[375]

Boston University economist Laurence J. Kotlikoff suggests commercial banks only became involved with CDOs, SIVs, and other “risky products” after Glass–Steagall was “repealed,” but he rejects Glass–Steagall reinstatement (after suggesting Paul Volcker favors it) as a “non-starter” because it would give the “nonbank/shadow bank/investment bank industry” a “competitive advantage” without requiring it to pay for the “implicit” “lender-of-last-resort” protection it receives from the government.[376] Robert Litan and Arthur Wilmarth presented their “narrow bank” proposals as a basis for eliminating Glass–Steagall (and other) restrictions on bank affiliates.[377] Writing in 1993, Jane D’Artista and Tom Schlesinger noted that “the ongoing integration of financial industry activities makes it increasingly difficult to separate banking and securities operations meaningfully” but rejected Glass–Steagall repeal because “the separation of banking and securities functions is a proven, least-cost method of preventing the problems of one financial sector from spilling over into the other” (which they stated was “most recently demonstrated in the October 1987 market crash.”)[378]

During the Senate debate of the bill that became the Dodd-Frank Act, Thomas Hoenig wrote Senators Maria Cantwell and John McCain (the co-sponsors of legislation to reinstate Glass–Steagall Sections 20 and 32) supporting a “substantive debate” on “the unintended consequences of leaving investment banking commingled with commercial banking” and reiterating that he had “long supported” reinstating “Glass–Steagall-type laws” to separate “higher risk, often more leveraged, activities of investment banks” from commercial banking. Hoenig agreed with Paul Volcker, however, that “financial market developments” had caused underwriting corporate bonds (the prohibition of which Volcker described as the purpose of Glass–Steagall[323]), and also underwriting of corporate equity, revenue bonds, and “high quality asset-backed securities,” to be “natural extensions of commercial banking.” Instead of reinstating Glass–Steagall prohibitions on such underwriting, Hoenig proposed restoring “the principles underlying the separation of commercial and investment banking firms.”[379]

In Mainland Europe, some scholars have suggested Glass–Steagall should be a model for any in-depth reform of bank regulation[380]: notably in France where SFAF and World Pensions Council (WPC) banking experts have argued that "a new Glass–Steagall Act" should be viewed within the broader context of separation of powers in European Union law.[381]

This perspective has gained ground after the unraveling of the Libor scandal in July 2012, with mainstream opinion leaders such as the Financial Times editorialists calling for the adoption of an EU-wide "Glass Steagall II".[382]

On July 25, 2012, former Citigroup Chairman and CEO Sandy Weill, considered one of the driving forces behind the considerable financial deregulation and “mega-mergers” of the 1990s, surprised financial analysts in Europe and North American by “calling for splitting up the commercial banks from the investment banks. In effect, he says: bring back the Glass–Steagall Act of 1933 which led to half a century, free of financial crises.”[383]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ a b "Frontline: The Wall Street Fix: Mr. Weill Goes to Washington: The Long Demise of Glass–Steagall". www.pbs.org. PBS. 2003-05-08. Retrieved 2008-10-08.
  2. ^ a b c CRS 2010a, pp. 1 and 5. Wilmarth 1990, p. 1161.
  3. ^ a b CRS 2010a, p. 10
  4. ^ a b Wilmarth 2002, pp. 220 and 222. Macey 2000, pp. 691-692 and 716-718. Lockner and Hansche 2000, p. 37.
  5. ^ a b c d Simpson Thacher 1998, pp. 1-6. Lockner and Hansche 2000, p. 37. Macey 2000, p. 718.
  6. ^ "Money, power, and Wall Street: Transcript, Part 4, (quoted as "The Glass–Steagall law is no longer appropriate—")". PBS. April 24 and May 1, 2012; encore performance July 3, 2012. {{cite web}}: |access-date= requires |url= (help); Check date values in: |date= (help); Missing or empty |url= (help); Text "http://www.pbs.org/wgbh/pages/frontline/business-economy-financial-crisis/money-power-wall-street/transcript-19/" ignored (help) Transcript of Clinton remarks at Financial Modernization bill signing, Washington, D.C.: U.S. Newswire, November 12, 1999 (“It is true that the Glass-Steagall law is no longer appropriate to the economy in which we lived. It worked pretty well for the industrial economy, which was highly organized, much more centralized and much more nationalized than the one in which we operate today. But the world is very different.”)
  7. ^ "The Overlooked Culprit in the Credit Crisis". usc.edu.
  8. ^ a b Kuttner, Robert (October 2, 2007), "The Alarming Parallels Between 1929 and 2007", The American Prospect: 2, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  9. ^ a b Stiglitz, Joseph E. (January 2009), "Capitalist Fools" (PDF), Vanity Fair: 2, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  10. ^ Sold Out: How Wall Street and Washington Betrayed America (PDF), Consumer Education Foundation, March 2009
  11. ^ a b White, Lawrence J. (2010), "The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act of 1999: A Bridge Too Far? Or Not Far Enough?" (PDF), Suffolk University Law Review, 43 (4): 938 and 943–946, retrieved February 20, 2012. Markham, Jerry W. (2010), "The Subprime Crisis—A Test Match For The Bankers: Glass–Steagall vs. Gramm-Leach-Bliley" (PDF), University of Pennsylvania Journal of Business Law, 12 (4): 1092–1134, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  12. ^ a b Gramm-Leach-Bliley Did Not Cause the Financial Crisis (PDF), American Bankers Association, January 2010, retrieved July 13, 2012. Who Caused the Economic Crisis?, FactCheck.org, October 1, 2008, retrieved February 20, 2012 Bartiromo, Maria (September 23, 2008), "Bill Clinton on the banking crisis, McCain, and Hillary", Bloomberg Businessweek Magazine, retrieved October 11, 2012
  13. ^ Friedman and Schwartz 1963 , p. 321 and pp. 399-406. Patrick 1993, pp. 71-77.
  14. ^ Federal Reserve Board (1932), "Review of the Month: The Glass–Steagall bill", Federal Reserve Bulletin, 73 (3): 141–142 and 180–181, retrieved March 16, 2012. Each form of special lending to Federal Reserve member banks required approval from at least five members of the Federal Reserve Board. Group lending could be made to fewer than five (but not fewer than two) member banks if the borrowing banks had deposit liabilities equal to at least 10% of the deposits liabilities of member banks in their Federal Reserve district. The special lending to individual member banks could be made only in “exceptional and exigent circumstances.” Both forms of lending were based on the borrowing member banks not having sufficient "eligible assets" to borrow on normal terms.
  15. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 560.
  16. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, pp. 104-105. Greenspan 1987, pp. 3 and 15-22. FRB 1998.
  17. ^ a b c Macey 2000, p. 716. Wilmarth 2002, p. 219, fn. 5.
  18. ^ Kennedy 1973, pp. 50-53 and 203-204. Perkins 1971, pp. 497-505.
  19. ^ Kennedy 1973, pp. 72-73.
  20. ^ Patrick 1993, pp. 172-174. Kelly III 1985, p. 54, fn. 171. Perkins 1971, p. 524.
  21. ^ Patrick 1993, pp. 168-172. Burns 1974, pp. 41-42 and 79. Kennedy 1973, pp. 212-219.
  22. ^ Kennedy 1973, pp. 103-128 and 204-205. Burns 1974, p 78.
  23. ^ Perino 2010
  24. ^ Bentson 1990, pp. 47-89. Cleveland and Huertas 1985, pp. 172-187.
  25. ^ a b c d e CRS 2010a, pp. 5–6. Fein 2011, §4.03[A].
  26. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 564, fn. 24.
  27. ^ a b c CRS 2010a, p. 6. Fein 2011, §4.03[C].
  28. ^ a b c CRS 2010a, pp. 6–7. Fein 2011, §4.03[B].
  29. ^ a b c CRS 2010a, p. 7. Fein 2011, §4.03[D].
  30. ^ Malloy 2011, § 9.02[B], pp. 9-37. "Glass–Steagall Act-A history of its legislative origins and regulatory construction (adapted from a press release of the Honorable James E. Smith, Comptroller of the Currency)", Banking Law Journal, 37 (1): 42–43, 1975. Patrick 1993, p. 251.
  31. ^ Kress, Harold James (1935), "The Banking Act of 1935", Michigan Law Review, 34 (2): 180. "Summary of certain provisions of Title I, and section-by-section summary of Title II and III, The Banking Act of 1935", Circular No. 1582, Federal Reserve Bank of New York, p. 10 (Section 307), August 30, 1935, retrieved February 23, 2012.
  32. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 565. Pecora 1939, pp. 82-104.
  33. ^ a b Benston 1990, pp. 44-45.
  34. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 560, fn. 8.
  35. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 565.
  36. ^ FRBNY 1933 pp. 1 (Section 3(a)), 4 (Section 7), 8 (Section 11(a)). Rodkey 1934, p. 893. Willis 1935, pp. 705-711.
  37. ^ CRS 2010a, p. 5. Fein 2011, § 4.03[A], pp. 4-8 to 4-9
  38. ^ a b c Fein 2011, § 7.06[A], p. 7-90. CRS 2010a, p. 5. Cite error: The named reference "dealer" was defined multiple times with different content (see the help page).
  39. ^ Peach 1941, pp. 38-43. Malloy 2011, § 9.02[A], p. 9-21. CRS 2010a, pp. 3 and 5–6.
  40. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.04[C], pp. 4-29 to 4-30 and § 7.06[A], pp. 7-90 to 7-91. Capatides 1992, VI. F. “Securities Trading Activities Pursuant to Investment Powers,” pp. 200-204.
  41. ^ a b c Fein 2011, § 4.04[C], p. 4-30 and § 7.06[A], pp. 7-90 to 7-91. Capatides 1992, p. 201.
  42. ^ Fein 2011, § 7.01 INTRODUCTION, p. 7-5.
  43. ^ FDIC 1983, chapter 3, pp. 44 and 47-53.
  44. ^ Wilmarth 1990, p. 1137.
  45. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, pp. 65-66. Saba, Peter (1986), "Regulation of State Nonmember Insured Banks' Securities Activities: A Model for the Repeal of Glass–Steagall?", Harvard Journal on Legislation, 23 (1): 220–222, retrieved February 12, 2012. Shull and White 1998, p. 7.
  46. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, pp. 66-68 and 75.
  47. ^ a b Eaton 1995, pp. 1202-1207. Benston 1990, p. 9.
  48. ^ a b c Financial Services: Information on Nonbank Banks (PDF), Fact Sheet for Members of Congress, United States General Accounting Office, March 1986, retrieved February 11, 2012. Gart, Alan (1985), Banks, Thrifts, and Insurance Companies: Surviving the 1980s, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books, pp. 1 and 51–83, ISBN 0-669-09374-2. CRS 2005, p. CRS-4.
  49. ^ a b c Historical Framework For Regulation of Activities of Unitary Savings and Loan Holding Companies, Office of Thrift Supervision, 1998, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  50. ^ Perkins 1971, pp. 503-504 and 517-522. Peach 1941, pp. 66-70.
  51. ^ FRB 1987, p. 475 (“Congress drew a clear distinction between member banks and their affiliates in the Glass–Steagall Act.”) Benston 1990, pp. 7-9.
  52. ^ Norton, Joseph Jude (1987), "Up Against "The Wall": Glass–Steagall and the Dilemma of a Deregulated ("Reregulated") Banking Environment", The Business Lawyer, 42 (February): 328
  53. ^ Garten 1989, pp. 515-516. Hendrickson 2001, p. 860. Peach 1941, p. 160.
  54. ^ Moore, Terris (1934), "Security Affiliate versus Private Investment Banker—A Study in Security Organization", Harvard Business Review, 12 (July): 478–484
  55. ^ Edwards, George W. (1942), "The Myth of the Security Affiliate", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 37 (June): 225–232, JSTOR 2279217
  56. ^ Edward, George W. (1938), The Evolution of Finance Capitalism, New York: A. M. Kelley (published 1967 (reprint of the 1938 edition published by Longmans, Green & Co., Inc, New York)), pp. 296–297, LCCN 66-22622, OCLC 169277 {{citation}}: Check date values in: |publication-date= (help). Wilmarth 2008, p. 590.
  57. ^ Burns 1974, pp. 170-171. Patrick 1993, pp. 265-266. Wilmarth 2008, pp. 590-591.
  58. ^ Burns 1974, pp. 170-171. Perkins 1971, p. 269.
  59. ^ a b White 1992, p. 7.
  60. ^ Pitt and Williams 1983, p. 142. Investment Company Institute v. Camp, 401 U.S. 617, pp. 621-622 (for OCC actions) (1971). Retrieved February 18, 2012.
  61. ^ Langevoort 1987, pp. 688-690. CRS 2010a, pp. 8–10.
  62. ^ Office of the Comptroller of the Currency: A Short History (PDF), Comptroller of the Currency, Administrator of National Banks, US Department of Treasury, 2011, p. 22, retrieved February 11, 2012. White 1992, p. 13.
  63. ^ White 1992, pp. 13 and 15. Reinicke 1995, p. 31.
  64. ^ a b CRS 2010a, pp. 8–9.
  65. ^ Macey 2000, p. 717. Reinicke 1995, p. 31
  66. ^ Friedman, Benjamin M. (1975), "Regulation Q and the Commercial Loan Market in the 1960s", Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 7 (3): 277–296, JSTOR 1991623.
  67. ^ a b Minsky 1982, pp. xii-xiv.
  68. ^ Abken, Peter A. (1981), "Commercial Paper" (PDF), Economic Review (March/April), Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond: 14, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  69. ^ Garten 1989, pp. 522-524. Wilmarth 1990, pp. 1147-1148.
  70. ^ Wilmarth 1990, pp. 1142-1143.
  71. ^ a b Welshimer, Mark J. (1997), "Securitization: Has It Matured?", in Effros, Robert C. (ed.), Current Legal Issues Affecting Central Banks, vol. 4, Washington, D.C.: International Monetary Fund, pp. 488 and 493, ISBN 978-1-55775-503-2, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  72. ^ Macey, Jonathan R. (1993), "The Inevitability of Universal Banking", Brooklyn Journal of International Law, 19 (1): 206–211, retrieved February 26, 2012. Kregel 2010a, p. 7.
  73. ^ Wilmarth 1990, pp. 1142-1144.
  74. ^ Mayer 1984, pp. 34-45.
  75. ^ Cook, Timothy Q.; Duffield, Jeremy G. (1998), "Chapter 12: Money Market Mutual Funds and other Short-Term Investment Pools" (PDF), Instruments of the Money Market, Federal Reserve Bank of Richmond, pp. 164–167, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  76. ^ Kaplan, Alan J. (1973), "The Negotiable Order of Withdrawal (NOW) Account: 'Checking Accounts' for Savings Banks?", Boston College Law Review, 14 (3): 471–500, retrieved February 11, 2012. Litan 1987, p. 34. Burnett, John, A Short History of NOW and MMDA Accounts, BankersOnline, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  77. ^ Garten 1989, pp. 508-509 and 521-525. Garten 1991, pp. 8-14.
  78. ^ Vietor 1987, pp. 33-39.
  79. ^ Mayer 1974, pp. 523 and 531-535.
  80. ^ Minsky 1982, p. 201
  81. ^ Kregel 2010b, p. 66 (Section 3.10 "The regulatory dynamic of innovation and protection").
  82. ^ Kregel 2010b, pp. 66–67.
  83. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, pp. 91-92, 95, and 115-116.
  84. ^ a b Gimlin, J. S. (July 17, 1968), "Banking Innovations", CQ Researcher, CQ Press, pp. 11–12 (“Rivalry of Investment and Commercial Bankers”), retrieved February 11, 2012 {{citation}}: More than one of |work= and |periodical= specified (help). Reinicke 1995, p. 59.
  85. ^ SEC 1994, p. 9. Keefe, Arthur John (1974), "Your friendly one-stop financial shopping centers", American Bar Association Journal, 60: 744.
  86. ^ Pitt and Williams 1983, pp. 154-155.
  87. ^ a b c d Timeline of Bank Securities Activities (PDF), United States Securities and Exchange Commission, Office of Legislative Affairs, June 24, 1994, p. 11, retrieved February 11, 2012
  88. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 57-58.
  89. ^ Shull and White 1998, p. 5.
  90. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 30-31. Shull and White 1998, pp. 5-6.
  91. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 61.
  92. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 65-70.
  93. ^ "State Regulation of Banks in an Era of Deregulation" (PDF), Commission Report A-110, Advisory Commission on Intergovernmental Relations, pp. 19–20, September 1988, retrieved February 11, 2012. Shull and White 1998, p. 7.
  94. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 91 and 95. Pitt and Williams 1983, p. 167.
  95. ^ a b Capatides 1992, p. 7, fn. 12.
  96. ^ Langevoort 1987, pp. 709-712.
  97. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 76-77. FRB 1998, p. 1.
  98. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 96. CRS 2005, pp. CRS-4 to CRS-5. Kurucza et al. 1988, pp. 1112 and 1119.
  99. ^ Kurucza et al. 1988, p. 1107. Reinicke 1995, pp. 96-99.
  100. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 84-85 and 91-101
  101. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 98-100.
  102. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 99-100 and 105-109. FRB 1998, p. 2 ( Part II, S. 1886).
  103. ^ a b White 1992, p. 53.
  104. ^ Ferrar, Peter J. (1990), "International Trends in the Combination of Banking, Securities, and Commerce" (PDF), Cato Journal, 10 (2): 330 (UK) and 333 (Canada), retrieved February 11, 2012. Reinicke 1995, pp. 92 (for the U.K.’s Big Bang) and 95 (for broader global “deregulation”).
  105. ^ Macey, Jonathan R.; Litt, David G.; Miller, Geoffrey P.; Rubin, Edward L. (1990), "Politics, Bureaucracies, and Financial Markets: Bank Entry into Commercial Paper Underwriting in the United States and Japan", University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 139: 379–380, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  106. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 92, 95, and 101. GAO 1988, pp. 31–35.
  107. ^ Benston 1990, pp. 32-34. White, Eugene Nelson (1986), "Before the Glass–Steagall Act: An analysis of the investment banking activities of national banks", Explorations in Economic History, 23 (1): 33–55. Kroszner, Randall S.; Rajan, Raghuram G. (July 1993), "Is the Glass–Steagall Act Justified? A Study of the U.S. Experience with Universal Banking before 1933" (PDF), American Economic Review (forthcoming): 1–33, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  108. ^ Vietor 1987, pp. 38-39.
  109. ^ Garten 1989, p. 512-513. Macey, Jonathan R. (1984), "Special Interest Groups Legislation and the Judicial Function: The Dilemma of Glass–Steagall", Emory Law Journal, 33 (1): 1–40, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  110. ^ Eaton 1995, pp. 1202-1210.
  111. ^ Mayer 1974, p. 535.
  112. ^ Mayer 1984, p. 49.
  113. ^ Mayer 1984, pp. 49-52. Shull and White 1998, p. 6.
  114. ^ Vietor 1987, p. 49.
  115. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 93. Gruber, William (October 29, 1986), "150 Banks may be on Brink, Result of Competition: Fdic Boss", Chicago Tribune, retrieved February 10, 2012.
  116. ^ a b Jackson, William D. (1987), "Glass–Steagall Act: Commercial vs. Investment Banking" (PDF), Congressional Research Issue Brief, no. IB 87061, retrieved February 10, 2012.
  117. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 98 (quoting CRS Report No. 87-725E).
  118. ^ a b GAO 1988, pp. 2–5.
  119. ^ Gruson, Michael; Nikowitz, Werner (1989), "The Second Banking Directive of the European Economic Community and Its Importance for Non-EEC Banks", Fordham International Law Journal, 12 (2): 205–241, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  120. ^ Jeannot 1999, pp. 1733, fn. 98 (on effective date), and 1736-1738 (on securities powers). Barth, James R.; Nolle, Daniel E.; Rice, Tara (1997), "Commercial Banking Structure, Regulation, and Performance: An International Comparison" (PDF), 97-6, OCC Working Paper, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, pp. 14–15, retrieved February 11, 2012.
  121. ^ Jeannot 1999, pp. 1737-1738.
  122. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp.105-111.
  123. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 103-104. FRB Manual, Section 3600.21.2.
  124. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 103-104. FRB Manual, Section 3600.21.3.
  125. ^ Fein 2011, § 1.04[A], p. 1-14. SEC 1994, pp. 10–11.
  126. ^ a b c Reinicke 1995, pp. 71 (for opposition to underwriting corporate bonds), 74 and 76. Volcker, Paul (January 16, 1984), Statement before the Committee on Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, pp. 2–3 and 7–8, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  127. ^ FRB 1987, pp. 505-506. Reinicke 1995, p. 103.
  128. ^ a b c Kregel 2010a, p. 11.
  129. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 103-4. FRB 1987, pp. 505-506.
  130. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 103.
  131. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 110-111.
  132. ^ a b Fein 2011, § 1.06[F], p. 1-39. Taylor, Andrew (August 3, 1996), "BANKING: Fed suggests expanding securities operations", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2174.
  133. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, p. 110.
  134. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 114 and 124-125.
  135. ^ Eaton 1995, pp. 1189 and 1201-1202.
  136. ^ Eaton 1995, pp. 1202-1203.
  137. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 93.
  138. ^ Eaton 1995, p. 1219.
  139. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 104. Greenspan 1987, p. 3.
  140. ^ a b Reinicke 1995, p. 104.
  141. ^ Greenspan 1987, p. 3.
  142. ^ Membership of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, 1914-Present, The Federal Reserve Board, p. 6 (Chairman from August 6, 1979-August 11, 1987), retrieved February 20, 2012.
  143. ^ Fein 2011, § 1.04, pp. 1-9 to 1-12. SEC 1994, pp. 8–9.
  144. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.05[C][4]. SEC 1994, p. 13.
  145. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.05[C][5]. SEC 1994, p. 21.
  146. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.05[C][8]. SEC 1994, p. 21.
  147. ^ Reinicke 1995, p. 69. "Are Banks Special", Annual Report, Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis, January1982, retrieved February 12, 2012 {{citation}}: Check date values in: |date= (help).
  148. ^ 73rd Annual Report, 1986, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, May 18, 1987, p. 177, retrieved February 12, 2012. Reinicke 1995, p. 97.
  149. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 93 and 97-98.
  150. ^ Corrigan (May 3, 1990), "Reforming the US Financial System: an International Perspective" (PDF), Quarterly Review (Spring), Federal Reserve Bank of New York: 9–10, retrieved February 12, 2012 {{citation}}: More than one of |work= and |journal= specified (help). Reinicke 1995, pp. 117 and 119.
  151. ^ a b Garrson, Robert M. (May 9, 1991), "Volcker: Public Must Re-Fund Bank Insurance", American Banker
  152. ^ "Volker Sees Taxpayer Bailout of Bank Fund Finance: The former Fed Chief told a Senate panel that banks can't afford to pay much more into the fund that insures their deposits", Los Angeles Times, May 9, 1991.
  153. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 120-124
  154. ^ Markey 1990.
  155. ^ a b c Markey 1990, pp. 457-458 and 474-475.
  156. ^ a b Fisher, Keith R. (1992), "Reweaving the Safety Net: Bank Diversification into Securities and Insurance Activities", Wake Forest Law Review, 27 (1): 231–247, retrieved February 25, 2012. "Banking Reform, Deformed (editorial)", New York Times, p. A26, October 31, 1991.
  157. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 122-124. Hendrickson 2001, pp. 862-864 (finding the same reason in 1988 and 1991).
  158. ^ FCIC 2011, pp. 38–51 and 67–155. Kotlikoff 2010, p. 151 (suggesting commercial bank CDO and SIV activities began after the 1999 GLBA).
  159. ^ Capatides 1992, pp. 98-105. Fein 2011, § 4.05[C][15], pp. 4-61 to 4-63.
  160. ^ Allen, Franklin; Santomero, Anthony M. (1998), "The theory of financial intermediation", Journal of Banking and Finance, 21 (10): 1464 and 1470–1473, JSTOR 1991623 {{citation}}: |access-date= requires |url= (help).
  161. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.05[C] [15], p. 4-62. Capatides 1992, pp. 99-101.
  162. ^ Fein 2011, § 4.05[C] [15], p. 4-62.
  163. ^ a b Fein 2011, § 1.02, p. 1-7.
  164. ^ Securities Industry Association v. Robert L. Clarke, 885 F.2d 1034, 1041 (for “ten years”) (2d. Cir. 1989).
  165. ^ Capatides 1992, p. 102. Kohler, Kenneth (1998), Collateralized Loan Obligations: A Powerful New Portfolio Management Tool for Banks, Mayer, Brown & Platt, p. 20, fn. 3, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  166. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 57-59. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 401-402.
  167. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 55-59. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 403-407.
  168. ^ Wilmarth 2002, pp. 392-393.
  169. ^ Wilmarth 1995, p. 56.
  170. ^ Wilmarth 2002, pp. 406-407.
  171. ^ Kavanaugh, Boemio & Edwards, Jr. 1992, pp. 109-112. Stojanovic, Dusan; Vaughn, Mark D. (1998), "The commercial paper market: who's minding the shop?", The Regional Economist (April), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis, retrieved February 12, 2012
  172. ^ Kavanaugh, Boemio & Edwards, Jr. 1992, p. 107.
  173. ^ Sandstrom, Randall (2007), "Chapter 2: Structured Investment Vehicles" (PDF), The International Comparative Legal Guide to: Securitisation 2007, Global Legal Group, p. 5, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  174. ^ Bate, Swasi; Bushwiller, Stephany; Rutan, Everett (February 3, 2003), The Fundamentals of Asset Backed Commercial Paper (PDF), Moody’s Investor Service, p. 8, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  175. ^ Jickling, Mark (January 29, 2003), "The Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000: Derivatives Regulation Reconsidered" (PDF), Congressional Research Service Report, no. RL30434, Congressional Research Service, pp. 4–5, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  176. ^ "Guidelines for national banks: credit derivatives", Bulletin, no. OCC-1996-43, Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, August 12, 1996, retrieved February 12, 2012. Partnoy, Frank; Skeel, David A. (2006), "The Promise and Perils of Credit Derivatives", Paper 125, Scholarship at Penn Law, retrieved February 12, 2012.
  177. ^ a b CRS 2010a, pp. 11–12. Omarova, Saule T. (2009), "The Quiet Metamorphosis: How Derivatives Changed the 'Business of Banking'", University of Miami Law Review, 63 (4): 1069–1072 and 1077–1082, SSRN 1491767. Gunther, Jeffrey W.; Siems, Thomas F. (2003), "Debunking derivatives delirium", Southwest Economy (2), Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas, retrieved February 12, 2012
  178. ^ Taylor, Andrew (May 13, 1995), "BANKING: Committee approves 'narrow' Glass–Steagall rewrite", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1308.
  179. ^ a b Glater, Jonathan D. (February 28, 1995), "Rubin urges changes in U.S. banking laws; Treasury chief would end curbs on competition", Washington Post, p. C.01.
  180. ^ Taylor, Andrew (April 29, 1995), "BANKING: Jim Leach gently rocking the boat", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1162.
  181. ^ Hendrickson 2001, p. 879. Wilmarth 2008, pp. 561-562. NRP 2012 (“Throughout the debate, Glass–Steagall was derided as an old-fashioned law out of step with modern finance”).
  182. ^ de Senerpont Domas, Olaf (April 6, 1995), "Volcker Plays Down Usefulness of Firewalls in Remarks to Panel", American Banker. (“Mr. Volcker, who still carries considerable weight on Capitol Hill”). "Financial Services Modernization", Segment 3 of Hearings before Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Consumer Credit, Committee on Banking and Financial Services, United States House of Representatives, pp. 252–254, February 25, 1997, retrieved February 13, 2012. SBC 1998, p. 7.
  183. ^ a b Canan, Martha M. (April 6, 1995), "Leach Pushes Back Debate on Bank Reform to May 9", Bond Buyer. Volcker 1997a (“I have argued this morning the logic and practical desirability of finally eliminating Glass–Steagall restrictions”).
  184. ^ Volcker 1997a.
  185. ^ a b c d Volcker 1997b.
  186. ^ Fein 2011, § 1.02, p. 1-6. Hendrickson 2001, pp. 867-869. FCIC 2011, p. 54.
  187. ^ Fein 2011, § 1.02, p. 1-6. Fisher 2001, p. 1302, fn. 6. Levitt 1998 (“A Competitive Two-Way Street”).
  188. ^ Wilmarth 2002, p. 223. Wilmarth, Jr., Arthur E. (2009), "The Dark Side of Universal Banking: Financial Conglomerates and the Origins of the Subprime Financial Crisis" (PDF), Connecticut Law Review, 41 (4): 973. Focarelli, Marques-Ibanez, Pozzolo 2011, pp. 6-7.
  189. ^ Mayer 1997, pp. 387-389 and 446-447.
  190. ^ Greenspan 2010, p. 33. Wilmarth 1995, pp. 14-26.
  191. ^ "Study Finds U.S. Restrictions on Bank Activities Out of Step With Other Leading Economic Powers" (PDF) (Press release). Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. March 24, 1997. Retrieved February 13, 2012.. Litan and Rauch 1998, pp. 88-92.
  192. ^ Wilmarth 2002, pp. 223-224, 284, and 425-428. Mayer 1997, pp. 23-24.
  193. ^ a b Kwan, Simon H.; Laderman, Elizabeth S. (1999), "On the Portfolio Effects of Financial Convergence—A Review of the Literature" (PDF), FRBSF Economic Review (2): 21–24, retrieved February 24, 2012
  194. ^ Garten 1993, pp. 164-166.
  195. ^ Garten 1993, pp. 163-164. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 439-440.
  196. ^ Garten 1993, p. 195. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 440-444.
  197. ^ a b Stern and Feldman 2004, p. 77. Reinicke 1995, p. 112, fn. 105.
  198. ^ Boyd, John H. (1999), "Expansion of commercial banking powers … or, universal banking is the cart, not the horse" (PDF), Journal of Banking and Finance, 23 (2–4): 655–662, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  199. ^ Stern and Feldman 2004, p. 77.
  200. ^ "Text as Prepared for Delivery: Treasury Secretary Robert E. Rubin, House Banking and Financial Services Committee" (Press release). United States Department of the Treasury. June 3, 1997. Retrieved February 13, 2012. Litan and Rauch 1998, pp. 88-92.
  201. ^ Wilmarth 2008, p. 562. Focarelli, Marques-Ibanez, Pozzolo 2011, pp. 6-7.
  202. ^ Mester, Loretta J. (1996), "Repealing Glass–Steagall: The Past Points the Way to the Future", Federal Reserve Bank of Philadelphia Business Review (July/August): 4–7, retrieved February 25, 2012. Barth et al. 2000, p.1.
  203. ^ Moss, David A. (2011), "Chapter 4: Reversing the Null: Regulation, Deregulation, and the Power of Ideas", in Rosenfeld, Gerald; Lorsch, Jay W.; Khurana, Rakesh (eds.), Challenges to Business in the Twenty-First Century (PDF), American Academy of Arts & Sciences, p. 45, fn. 20, retrieved February 12, 2012. Wilmarth 2008, p. 562. Calomiris, Charles W. (March 20, 1997), Prepared Testimony to Senate Banking, Housing and Urban Affairs Committee, Subcommittee on Financial Institutions and Regulatory Relief, p. 5 (answer to question #1), retrieved February 13, 2012.
  204. ^ Mayer 1997, p. 429.
  205. ^ Minsky, Hyman (March 1, 1995), Would Repeal of the Glass–Steagall Act Benefit the United States economy?: Statement prepared for Hearings on Repeal of Glass–Steagall Act, Committee on Banking and Financial Services, United States House of Representatives, p. 7, retrieved February 13, 2012. Minsky, Hyman (March 1, 1995), Reforming Banking in 1995: Repeal of the Glass Steagall Act, Some Basic Issues, p. 12, retrieved February 13, 2012.
  206. ^ Mayer 1974, pp. 521-524.
  207. ^ a b Garten 1999, p. 293.
  208. ^ Reinicke 1995, pp. 80 and 109.
  209. ^ McConnell, Bill (June 6, 1997), "Democrats Tie Reform to Consumer Protection", American Banker, p. 1. SBC 1998, pp. 57–58.
  210. ^ a b Lewis, Jake (November 1, 1998), "Financial Deregulation Fiasco: H.R. 10 and the Consequences of Financial Concentration", Multinational Monitor, 19 (11), retrieved February 24, 2012
  211. ^ Mattingly and Fallon 1998, pp. 66-69. Hosansky, David (June 21, 1997), "BANKING: Wall between financial services dealt first real blow in House", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1431–1433.
  212. ^ Taylor, Andrew (May 13, 1995), "BANKING: Committee approves 'narrow' Glass–Steagall rewrite", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1308.
  213. ^ Hendrickson 2001, pp. 865-866. Taylor, Andrew (July 29, 1995), "BANKING: Cleft between agents, big banks mires Glass–Steagall rewrite", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2249. Taylor, Andrew (March 2, 1996), "BANKING: despite its legislative victories insurance lobby may be losing war", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 540
  214. ^ Federal Reserve Board (December 20, 1996), Notice of Revenue Limit on Bank-Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities (PDF), p. 10, retrieved February 24, 2012. Lackritz, Marc E. (September 30, 1996), "Comments on the Releases entitled: "Revenue Limit on Bank-Ineligible Activities of Subsidiaries of Bank Holding Companies Engaged in Underwriting and Dealing in Securities" (Docket No. R-0841)", Comment Letter to Board of Governors of Federal Reserve System, Securities Industry Association, p. 3, retrieved February 13, 2012.
  215. ^ Federal Reserve Board (September 23, 1998), Order Approving Formation of a Bank Holding Company and Notice to Engage in Nonbanking Activities, Travelers Group Inc., New York, New York, Citicorp, New York, New York (PDF), pp. 65–66, retrieved February 24, 2012. Simpson Thacher 1998, p. 4.
  216. ^ "Interview: Charles Geisst". Hedrick Smith interview of Charles Geisst. PBS. February 5, 2003. Retrieved February 13, 2012.
  217. ^ "Interview: Alan Blinder". Hedrick Smith interview of Alan Blinder. PBS. February 13, 2003. Retrieved February 13, 2012.
  218. ^ a b Murphy, Brian D.; Haring, Sherri S. (1997), Removal of Three Section 20 Firewalls Enhances Opportunities for One-Stop Shopping in the Financial Services Industry, McGuire Woods LLP, retrieved February 13, 2012. Rodelli 1998, pp. 321-326.
  219. ^ Shull and White 1998, p. 8. Rodelli 1998, p. 335.
  220. ^ Omarova 2011. "Implementing the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act", Remarks by Governor Laurence H. Meyer before the American Law Institute and American Bar Association, Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Board, p. 4 (“23A and Firewalls”), retrieved February 13, 2012.
  221. ^ Fein 2011, § 1.06[F], pp. 1-40 to 1-41. Taylor, Andrew (June 7, 1997), "BANKING: Leach Pushes to Begin Markup of Financial Services Rewrite", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1305.
  222. ^ Mattingly and Fallon 1998, p. 34. Taylor, Andrew (April 19, 1997), "BANKING: Banks in No Hurry for Rewrite of Financial Services Law", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 898–900.
  223. ^ Taylor, Andrew (May 24, 1997), "BANKING: Under Treasury Plan, Congress to Decide Tough Issues", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1190. Taylor, Andrew (June 7, 1997), "BANKING: Leach Pushes to Begin Markup of Financial Services Rewrite", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1305.
  224. ^ Taylor, Andrew (June 21, 1997), "BANKING: Wall Between Financial Services Dealt First Feal Blow in House", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1431–1433. Volcker 1997a (“permitting banks or bank holding companies to extend their activities into commerce and industry -- contrary to Anglo-Saxon traditions of finance -- would be directly contrary” to “the need for strong structural protection against conflicts of interest in the provision of credit and undue concentration of resources.”)
  225. ^ Taylor, Andrew (April 19, 1997), "BANKING: Banks in No Hurry for Rewrite of Financial Services Law", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 898–900.
  226. ^ Hosansky, David (September 27, 1997), "BANKING: Paralyzed Congress on Sidelines in Financial Services Evolution", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2292–2296. Hosansky, David (October 25, 1997), "REGULATION: Banking Lobby Flays Rewrite of Financial Services Law", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2588. Hosansky, David (April 18, 1998), "The Art of Business Lobbying Finding Profit in Regulation", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 957–972
  227. ^ Hendrickson 2001, pp. 868-869. Nitschke, Lori (March 14, 1998), "BANKING: House Deal Offers Bit of Hope For Glass–Steagall Overhaul", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 647.
  228. ^ Nitschke, Lori (April 4, 1998), "BANKING: House Floor Says 'No Thanks' to Financial Services Bill", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 864.
  229. ^ Hendrickson 2001, p. 869. Fein 2011, § 1.06[G], p. 1-42. Nitschke, Lori (May 16, 1998), "BANKING &FINANCE: Financial Services Bill Squeaks By in House", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1301.
  230. ^ Nitschke, Lori (April 11, 1998), "SECURITIES INDUSTRY: Huge Financial Services Merger Puts Pressure on Hill to Lead", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 937 (Citicorp change). Nitschke, Lori (April 4, 1998), "BANKING: House Floor Says 'No Thanks' to Financial Services Bill", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 864 (for improving ability to compete with “foreign banks”).
  231. ^ Hendrickson 2001, p. 869. Wagner, Constance (2000), "Structuring the Financial Services Conglomerates of the Future: Does the Choice of Corporate Form to House New Financial Activities of National Banks Matter?", Annual Review of Banking Law, 19: 382–383, SSRN 1907844. Clinton, William J. (March 30, 1998), Statement of Administration Policy: H.R. 10-Financial Services Act of 1998, The American Presidency Project, retrieved February 14, 2012.
  232. ^ Nitschke, Lori (September 12, 1998), "BANKING: Financial Services Overhaul Bill Makes Progress in Senate with Nudge From Industry", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2411. SBC 1998, pp. 3, 6, 19, and (for Democratic member statement) 53-58.
  233. ^ Nitschke, Lori (October 10, 1998), "BANKING: Financial Services Overhaul Appears to Die in Senate, a Victim of Friendly Fire", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2733.
  234. ^ Phil FRB 1999, p. 1.
  235. ^ Clinton, William J. (July 1, 1999), Statement of Administration Policy: H.R. 10-Financial Services Act of 1999, The American Presidency Project, retrieved February 14, 2012.
  236. ^ Parks, Daniel J; Nitschke, Lori (March 6, 1999), "BANKING: Clash Over Community Reinvestment Threatens Senate Financial Services Bill", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 548–549. United States Senate, Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs (April 28, 1999), Report of the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, to accompany S. 900, together with Additional Views (PDF), Government Printing Ofice, pp. 3 and 54, retrieved February 25, 2012{{citation}}: CS1 maint: multiple names: authors list (link). S. 753, 106th Congress, First Session, p. 7, Section 101.
  237. ^ Parks, Daniel J. (May 8, 1999), "BANKING: Senate Passes Banking Overhaul Bill Vulnerable to a Clinton Veto; House Version Divides Committees", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1081–1082. Amendment No. 302, Congressional Record, S4682 (May 4, 1999), Section 101, p. S4683. Senate debate and vote on Amendment No. 302, Congressional Record, S. 4736-4743 (May 5, 1999).
  238. ^ Parks, Daniel J. (July 10, 1999), "BANKING: Financial Services Overhaul Sees Home Stretch at Last", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1675–1677. Hambley, Winthrop P. (September 19999), "The Great Debate-What will become of financial modernization", Community Investments, 11 (2), Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco: 1–3, retrieved February 16, 2012 {{citation}}: Check date values in: |date= (help). Clinton, William J. (July 1, 1999), Statement of Administration Policy: H.R. 10-Financial Services Act of 1999, The American Presidency Project, retrieved February 16, 2012.
  239. ^ a b Phil FRB 1999, pp. 1-2.
  240. ^ a b Phil FRB 1999, pp. 1-2. Parks, Daniel J. (October 23, 1999), "BANKING: Financial Services Bill in the Final Stretch", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2498–2503.
  241. ^ Parks, Daniel J. (November 6, 1999), "BANKING: Financial Services Overhaul Bill Clears After Final Skirmishing Over Community Reinvestment", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 2654. Wells, F. Jean; Jackson, William D. (1999), "Major Financial Services Legislation, The Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act (P. L. 106-102): An Overview" (PDF), Congressional Research Service Report, no. RL30375, p. CRS-10, retrieved February 26, 2012.
  242. ^ a b C&B 1999, p. 12. "Supervisory guidance relating to a change to permissible securities activities of state member banks", SR 01-13, Washington, D.C.: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, p. 1, May 14, 2001, retrieved February 16, 2012.
  243. ^ C&B 1999, p. 33. Joint Report 2003, p. 6.
  244. ^ Clinton, William J. (November 12, 1999), "Statement on Signing the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act", Public Papers of the Presidents, The American Presidency Project, retrieved February 16, 2012. Wilmarth 2002, p. 223.
  245. ^ Felsenfeld, Carl; Bilali, Genci (2003), "Business Divisions From The Perspective Of The U.S. Banking System" (PDF), Houston Business and Tax Law Journal, 68: 87, retrieved February 16, 2012. Joint Report 2003, p. 11.
  246. ^ Barth et al. 2000, p. 196.
  247. ^ Fisher 2001, pp. 1337-1367.
  248. ^ a b Stern 2000. Stern and Feldman 2004, p. 77. Wilmarth 2001, p. 22. Wilmarth 2002, pp. 224-225.
  249. ^ Roberts, Sally (December 23, 2001), Travelers doesn’t fit Citigroup umbrella: Early promise of convergence not realized, Business Insurance, retrieved February 16, 2012.
  250. ^ a b Rieker, Matthias (May 24, 2005), "2005 shaping up to be big year for divestitures", American Banker, p. 3A, retrieved February 16, 2012.
  251. ^ Heyward 2005, p. 1.
  252. ^ Joint Report 2003, p. 2.
  253. ^ Joint Report 2003, p. 5.
  254. ^ Joint Report 1999, p. 9.
  255. ^ Joint Report 2003, pp. 9–10.
  256. ^ Joint Report 2003, pp. 34–37. Rehm, Barbara A. (November 19, 2003), "IN BRIEF: Fed: Concentration Stable since GLB", American Banker.
  257. ^ a b c Joint Report 2003, p. 35.
  258. ^ Joint Report 2003, p. 8, fn. 15.
  259. ^ Ferguson, Jr., Roger (October 8, 2003), Remarks at the Futures of Financial Services Conference, University of Massachusetts, "The future of financial services--revisited", p. 4, retrieved February 17, 2012.
  260. ^ Pretzlik, Charles (January 6, 2004), "The Myth of the Mega-Bank: After the Failures of Diversification, Wary Lenders Scale Back their Global Ambitions Trying to Create Financial Supermarkets has Not always Paid Off", Financial Times {{citation}}: |first1= missing |last1= (help); Unknown parameter |lastt1= ignored (help).
  261. ^ Cobb, Carolyn (April 26, 2004), "Insurance Regulation after the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act" (PDF), Congressional Research Service Report, no. RS 21827, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  262. ^ SBC 2004, p. 6.
  263. ^ Greenspan, Alan (April 20, 2004), "The state of the banking industry," Testimony Before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, United States Senate, p. 8, retrieved February 17, 2012.
  264. ^ Anason, Dean (November 15, 2004), "Much Business Unfinished as GLBA Turns Five", American Banker, p. 1 {{citation}}: |first1= missing |last1= (help); Unknown parameter |lastt1= ignored (help).
  265. ^ Harshman, Ellen; Yeager, Fred C.; Yeager, Timothy J. (2005), "The Door Is Open, but Banks Are Slow To Enter Insurance and Investment Arenas", The Regional Economist (October), Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis: 14, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  266. ^ "Interview: Scott Cleland". Hedrick Smith interview of Scott Cleland. PBS. January 21, 2003. Retrieved February 19, 2012. SBC 2004, pp. 54–56.
  267. ^ Wilmarth 2008, pp. 559 and 562-563.
  268. ^ Fanto, James A. (2004), "Subtle Hazards Revisited: The Corruption of a Financial Holding Company by a Corporate Client's Inner Circle", Brooklyn Law Review, 70 (1): 18–28, SSRN 622161. Wilmarth 2008, pp. 563-564 and 614.
  269. ^ BANK OVERSIGHT: Few Cases of Tying Have Been Detected (PDF), Report to Congressional Committees, United States General Accounting Office, May 1997, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  270. ^ BANK TYING: Additional Steps Needed to Ensure Effective Enforcement of Tying Prohibitions (PDF), Report to Chairman and Ranking Minority Member, Committee on Financial Services, House of Representatives, United States General Accounting Office, October 2003, retrieved February 19, 2012. Mitchell, Clyde (October 31, 2003), "Study Should Wrap Up Tying", American Banker.
  271. ^ Brown, Jr., J. Robert (1995), "The "Great Fall': The Consequences of Repealing the Glass–Steagall Act", Stanford Journal of Law, Business, and Finance, 2 (1): 132–142 and 145, SSRN 961634. Eaton 1995, pp. 1188-1189 and 1214-1219. Macey 2000, p. 694.
  272. ^ Coffee, Jr., John C. (December 5, 2008), "Analyzing the Credit Crisis: Was the SEC Missing in Action?", New York Law Journal, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  273. ^ FCIC 2011, pp. 154 (summary), 290 (Bear), 339 (Lehman), 337 and 341 (Merrill) and 362–363 (Goldman and Morgan Stanley). Fein 2011, §1.09, p. 1-78.
  274. ^ SBC 2004, pp. 16 and 87.
  275. ^ Wallison, Peter J. (December 19, 2001), "The Failure of the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act", Remarks to Exchequer Club Luncheon, retrieved February 19, 2012. Wallison, Peter J. (November 13, 2001), "Why Has the Gramm-Leach-Bliley Act Failed", Introduction to AEI Event on Banking Reform, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  276. ^ SBC 2004, p. 53. Heyward 2005, pp. 4-6.
  277. ^ Levitt 1998 (“Market Discipline--not Safety and Soundness Regulation--for Securities Firms).
  278. ^ FCIC 2011, p. 55. SBC 2004, p. 53.
  279. ^ Greenspan 2010, p. 29, fn. 47.
  280. ^ Fein 2011, §1.09, pp. 1-77 to 1-78.
  281. ^ Fein 2011, §1.09, p. 1-78.
  282. ^ Fein §1.09, p. 1-78.
  283. ^ Fein 2011, §1.09[A], p. 1-80. Heyward 2005, p. 5. Joint Report 2003, p. 3. Wilmarth 2002, p. 223.
  284. ^ Focarelli, Marques-Ibanez, and Pozzolo 2011, pp. 7-8, 13-15, and 22-23.
  285. ^ Focarelli, Marques-Ibanez, and Pozzolo 2011, p. 23.
  286. ^ Focarelli, Marques-Ibanez, and Pozzolo 2011, pp. 13-14.
  287. ^ Stiglitz, Joseph E. (2010), Freefall: America, Free Markets, And The Sinking Of The World Economy, New York: W.W. Norton & Co., pp. 15 and 82–83, ISBN 0-393-07596-6.
  288. ^ "Elizabeth Warren Pt. 2 – The Daily Show with Jon Stewart – 4/15/2009 – Video Clip | Comedy Central". Thedailyshow.com. 2009-04-15. Retrieved 2012-01-08.
  289. ^ Weissman, Robert (November 12, 2009), Reflections on Glass–Steagall and Maniacal Deregultion, CommonDreams.org, retrieved February 26, 2012.
  290. ^ Blinder, Alan S. (October 23, 2009), "It's Broke, Let's Fix It: Rethinking Financial Regulation" (PDF), Prepared for Federal Reserve Bank of Boston conference, pp. 29–30, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  291. ^ Fein 2011, §1.02, p. 1-6.
  292. ^ Felsenfeld and Glass 2011, p. 362.
  293. ^ Felsenfeld and Glass 2011, p. 312. Wallison, Peter (November 2009), "Did the 'Repeal' of Glass–Steagall Have Any Role in the Financial Crisis? Not Guilty. Not Even Close" (PDF), Policy Brief 2009-PB-09, Networks Financial Institute at Indiana State University, pp. 3–7, retrieved February 20, 2012. Rugoff, Nicholas (February 4, 2010), "On Financial Regulation: An Interview with Jonathan Macey", The Politic, Yale University, p. 2 (“should Congress reenact Glass–Steagall type legislation?”), retrieved February 20, 2012
  294. ^ Mayer, Martin (November 2009), "Glass–Steagall in Our Future: How Straight, How Narrow?" (PDF), Policy Brief 2009-PB-07, Networks Financial Institute at Indiana State University, pp. 5–11, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  295. ^ Mayer 1974, pp. 192-197.
  296. ^ Maisel, Sherman J. (1973), Managing the Dollar, New York: W.W. Norton & Company, Inc., p. 20, ISBN 0-393-05494-2
  297. ^ a b Wilmarth 2002, p. 374.
  298. ^ Garten 1993, pp. 169-170 and 182-185.
  299. ^ Kregel 2010b, p. 67.
  300. ^ Kregel 2010a, pp. 8–9.
  301. ^ NRP 2012, p. 3 (“The Financial Crisis”).
  302. ^ a b Date, Raj; Konczal, Michael (March 2011), "Out of the Shadows: Creating a 21st Century Glass–Steagall", Make Markets Be Markets (PDF), Roosevelt Institute, p. 61, retrieved February 6, 2012Date and Konczal 2011, p. 61.
  303. ^ a b c Robert Scheer (2010-01-06). "McCain Gets It, Obama Doesn't". The Nation.
  304. ^ Bill Summary & Status, 111th Congress (2009-2010), S. 2866, CRS Summary, THOMAS Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  305. ^ CRS 2010a, pp. 1 and 13–15.
  306. ^ MacArthur, John R. (December 14, 2011), "President Obama Richly Deserves to Be Dumped", The Providence Journal, p. 2 (“the administration steadfastly opposes the restoration of the Glass–Steagall Act”), retrieved February 22, 2012.
  307. ^ Sloan, Stephen; Hopkins, Cheyenne (January 27, 2010), "Obama Plan Has Shades of Glass–Steagall Act", American Banker, p. 2 ("I would not support reinstating Glass–Steagall and I don't actually believe that the end of Glass–Steagall played a significant role in the cause of the crisis," Geithner told the Joint Economic Committee in November.), retrieved February 22, 2012. Financial Regulatory Reform: Protecting Taxpayers and the Economy, Hearing before the Joint Economic Committee, Congress of the United States (PDF), Government Printing Office, November 19, 2009, p. 19, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  308. ^ Cook, Merrill (July 20, 2011), "Support the Kaptur/Jones Prudent Banking Act of 2011, H.R. 1489", Standard Examiner, Ogden, Utah, p. 2, retrieved February 22, 2012. Bill Summary & Status, 112th Congress (2011-2012), H.R. 1489, CRS Summary, THOMAS Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012. Bill Text, 112th Congress (2011-2012), H.R. 1489.IH, THOMAS Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  309. ^ Bill Summary & Status, 112th Congress (2011-2012), H.R. 2451, CRS Summary, THOMAS Library of Congress, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  310. ^ Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010. Whitehead 2011, p. 47.
  311. ^ Whitehead 2011, p. 48. Chapman and Cutler LLP 2010, p. 1.
  312. ^ Watson, Bruce (October 12, 2011), Volcker Rule Made Simple: Banks Can't Gamble With Our Money (Probably), Daily Finance, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  313. ^ a b Glass–Steagall lite, The Economist, January 22, 2010, retrieved February 20, 2012. Copeland, Laurence (January 25, 2010), "Glass–Steagall Lite, brewed by Volcker, served by Obama", The Great Debate UK, Reuters, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  314. ^ Whitehead 2011, p. 50.
  315. ^ Whitehead 2011, pp. 48-49.
  316. ^ Rowe, David (March 2006), Regulatory arbitrage: back to basics (PDF), Risk Magazine, p. 66, retrieved February 20, 2012. Caresana, Annalisa (January 2009), Regulatory capital for banks’ trading activities set to increase to eliminate regulatory arbitrage between trading book and banking book, Technical Update, Adkins Matchett & Toy, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  317. ^ Norris, Floyd (October 14, 2011), "Bank Rules That Serve Two Masters", New York Times, p. B1, retrieved February 20, 2012.
  318. ^ Merkley, Jeff; Levin, Carl (2011), "The Dodd-Frank Act Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Conflicts of Interest: New Tools to Address Evolving Threats" (PDF), Harvard Journal of Legislation, 48 (2): 530 and 538–539, retrieved February 25, 2012.
  319. ^ Wilmarth 2002, p. 374, fn. 665.
  320. ^ de Senerpont Domas, Olaf (December 7, 1995), "Bank Trading Losses Minimal and Risks Limited, U.S. Says", American Banker, p. 24. Fein 2011, 7.06[A], p. 7-91. "Staff Paper Released On Trading Activities At Commercial Banks (NR 95-134)" (PDF) (Press release). Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and Federal Reserve Board. December 6, 1999. Retrieved February 19, 2012..
  321. ^ Dixon, Kim; Witkowski, Karey (March 30, 2010), Volcker: Proprietary trading not central to crisis, Reuters, retrieved February 19, 2012. Volcker, Paul (March 30, 2010), "Essential Elements of Financial Reform", Transcript of speech delivered at the Peterson Institute, retrieved February 19, 2012.
  322. ^ Volcker, Paul (September 10, 1998), "Boost for Banking", Washington Post, p. A21 ( Op-Ed).
  323. ^ a b Conference Proceedings, 19th Annual Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the State of the U.S. and World Economies, After the Crisis: Planning a New Financial Structure (PDF), Levy Economics Institute of Bard College, p. 113, retrieved February 20, 2012 {{citation}}: Unknown parameter |dates= ignored (help).
  324. ^ CRS 2010b, pp. 5–7. Fein 2011, §§ 8.01 and 8.02[D], p. 8-3 to 8-5.
  325. ^ CRS 2010b, p. 9, fn.60. Fein 2011, § 8.03[D], p. 8-12.
  326. ^ Lockner and Hansche 2000, p. 37.
  327. ^ CRS 2010b, pp. 6–8.
  328. ^ Fein 2011, § 7.08[G], pp. 7-119 to 7-126 and § 8.04, p. 8-15.
  329. ^ ICB 2011
  330. ^ Hutton, Will (August 31, 2011), "Banking reform: ringfencing is the only solution", The Guardian, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  331. ^ Goff, Sharlene (August 31, 2011), "Just the facts: the Vickers Report", Financial Times, retrieved February 21, 2012
  332. ^ Samuel, Juliet (November 4, 2011), "King: EU could veto Vickers", City A.M., retrieved February 21, 2012
  333. ^ Pignal, Stanley; Barker, Alex (November 22, 2011), "Barnier panel to study break up of EU banks", Financial Times, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  334. ^ "Expert report suggests Europe's banks ring-fence investment banking from retail banking", Washington Post, [Associated Press], October 2, 2012, retrieved October 9, 2012. Final Report (PDF), High-level Expert Group on reforming the structure of the EU banking sector, October 2, 2012, retrieved October 9, 2012
  335. ^ Wagner 2000, pp. 335-337 and 382-424. Fein 2011, §1.04[B] pp. 1-21 to 1-22.
  336. ^ Shull and White 1998, pp. 1, 8-10, and 14-17.
  337. ^ Shull and White 1998, p. 8. England, Catherine (1991), Governing Banking’s Future: Markets vs. Regulation, Boston: Kluwer Academic, p. 65, retrieved February 22, 2012. Wilmarth 2001, p. 22, fn. 37.
  338. ^ a b c d Shull and White 1998, pp. 8-9 (for Greenspan in 1990). Testimony by Alan Greenspan, Chairman, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, before the Committee on Banking, Housing & Urban Affairs, United States Senate, July 12, 1990, July 12, 1990, pp. 14–15, retrieved February 22, 2012. Rodelli 1998, p. 316, fn. 35 (for Volcker in 1995). Volcker 1997b, pp. 3-4 (“Firewalls”). Fein 2011, §1.04[B] p.1-22.
  339. ^ Wells, Rob (April 29, 1999), "Fed Chief Discourages New Bank Powers, Says Pending Bill Would Give Unfair Advantage", Bloomberg News. Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, before the Committee on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs, U.S. Senate, June 17, 1998, "H.R. 10, the Financial Services Act of 1998", Federal Reserve Board, June 17, 1998, pp. 10–13 (“Operating Subsidiaries vs. Holding Companies”), retrieved February 22, 2012. Testimony of Chairman Alan Greenspan, before the Subcommittee on Finance and Hazardous Materials, Committee on Commerce, U.S. House of Representatives, "H.R. 10 and financial modernization", Federal Reserve Board, April 28, 1999, pp. 1–6 (“Operating Subsidiaries”), retrieved February 22, 2012.
  340. ^ Stern 2000, p. 9. Remarks of Chairman Alan Greenspan at the 36th Annual Conference on Bank Structure and Competition of the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, "Banking evolution", Federal Reserve Board, May 4, 2000, p. 3, retrieved February 23, 2012.
  341. ^ Wilmarth 1995, p. 82.
  342. ^ Omarova 2011, pp. 1725-1756.
  343. ^ Omarova 2011, pp. 1689-1690, 1728, and 1734.
  344. ^ Alvarez, Scott (March 23, 2010), FCIC Interview of Scott Alvarez and Kieran Fallon (PDF), Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission, pp. 62–67, retrieved October 9, 2012
  345. ^ ICB 2011, pp. 235–236.
  346. ^ "Why the Vickers Report failed the UK and the World", Economists’ Forum, Financial Times, September 20, 2011, retrieved February 6, 2012.
  347. ^ a b c d Kotlikoff, Laurence (January 28, 2011), "Open letter to Sir John Vickers on his banking reform speech", Economists’ Forum, Financial Times, retrieved February 6, 2012
  348. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 84-89.
  349. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 123-124 and 131-132.
  350. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, p. 132.
  351. ^ Litan 1987, pp. 70-71 and 164-178..
  352. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 77-87.
  353. ^ Wilmarth 2001, pp. 73-81.
  354. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 81-83. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 80-81
  355. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 82-3. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 79-80.
  356. ^ Wilmarth 1995, pp. 86-87. Wilmarth 2001, pp. 80-81.
  357. ^ Pottinger, Matt (June 4, 1997), "Rubin Pitches Plan on Bank Deregulation", Chicago Tribune, p. 1. Hawke, Jr., John D. (June 3, 1997), Text as Prepared for Delivery: Treasury Undersecretary For Domestic Finance, John D. Hawke, House Banking and Financial Services, p. 3 (Wholesale Financial Institutions”), retrieved February 21, 2012. Taylor, Andrew (May 24, 1997), "BANKING: Under Treasury Plan, Congress to Decide Tough Issues", CQ Weekly, Washington, D.C.: 1190.
  358. ^ Levitt 1998 (“A Competitive Two-Way Street”). Wayne, Leslie (July 7, 1999), "Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law", New York Times, p. 2, retrieved February 21, 2012.
  359. ^ a b c d Day, Kathleen (October 28, 1999), "Wholesale Banks Cut from Overhaul Bill", Washington Post, p. E.02
  360. ^ a b c d Anason, Dean (October 28, 1999), "Capital Briefs: Wholesale Banking Cut from Reform Bill", American Banker, p. 2
  361. ^ "Statement of The Independent Bankers Association of America before the Committee on Banking and Financial Services, U.S. House of Representatives, on Financial Restructuring" (Press release). The Committee on Financial Services. May 7, 1997. p. 5 (“Wholesale Financial Institutions”). Retrieved February 22, 2012. de Senerpont Domas, Olaf (April 6, 1995), "Volcker Plays Down Usefulness of Firewalls in Remarks to Panel", American Banker, p. 2(“Why should this particular class of institution be free of federal deposit insurance when it will be competing side by side with banks that have to pay deposit insurance premiums?”)
  362. ^ Wayne, Leslie (July 7, 1999), "Push for Wholesale Banks stalls in Overhaul of Law", New York Times, p. 2, retrieved February 21, 2012
  363. ^ ICB 2011, Chapter 3.21, p. 44.
  364. ^ D’Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 11-14.
  365. ^ D’Arista and Schlesinger 1993, p. 32-38.
  366. ^ D’Arista and Schlesinger 1993, p. 34.
  367. ^ D’Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 36-37.
  368. ^ FCIC 2011, pp. xvii, xx, 27–37, 255, 414, and 469.
  369. ^ Gorton, Gary; Metrick, Andrew (October 18, 2010), Regulating the Shadow Banking System, pp. 15–16, SSRN 1676947. FCIC 2011, pp. 245, 275, 343, 427, 446, and 478.
  370. ^ Garten 1999, pp. 304-307.
  371. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 122-124.
  372. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, pp. 126 and 131-154.
  373. ^ Hoenig, Thomas (June 27, 2011), "Do SIFIs Have a Future" (PDF), Keynote remarks to “Dodd-Frank One Year On,” Pew Financial Reform Project and New York University Stern School of Business Conference, Washington, D.C.: Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, pp. 5 and 7–8, retrieved February 22, 2012.
  374. ^ ICB 2011, p. 36, fn. 1.
  375. ^ ICB 2011, p. 146.
  376. ^ Kotlikoff 2010, p. 151.
  377. ^ Litan 1987, pp. 164-178. Wilmarth 1995, pp. 80-82.
  378. ^ D’Arista and Schlesinger 1993, pp. 6-7.
  379. ^ Hoenig, Thomas (May 10, 2010), Letter to The Honorable Senator Maria Cantwell and The Honorable Senator John McCain, Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City http://www.kc.frb.org/SpeechBio/HoenigPDF/Cantwell.McCain.Letter.05.10.10.pdf, retrieved February 22, 2012 {{citation}}: Missing or empty |title= (help)
  380. ^ Template:Fr icon M Nicolas Firzli (Jan. 2010), Bank Regulation and Financial Orthodoxy: the Lessons from the Glass–Steagall Act (PDF), retrieved 2010-01-08{{citation}}: CS1 maint: numeric names: authors list (link). "see Ionescu Romeo, "Romania and Greece: Together or Alone", AJBM Vol. 4 (19), p. 4197, December 2010 [Quoting Q1 2010 article (in French) by M. Nicolas J. Firzli in Revue Analyse Financière]" (PDF). Retrieved 29 March 2011.
  381. ^ M. Nicolas J. Firzli quoted by Marie Lepesant (June 11, 2012). "Le Modèle des Banques Françaises en Question". Le Parisien Aujourd’hui en France. . Retrieved 12 June 2012.
  382. ^ Editorial, Page (July 3, 2012). "Restoring trust after Diamond". Financial Times. Retrieved 15 July 2012. quoting FT Editorial Page.
  383. ^ Denning, Steve (July 25, 2012). "Rethinking Capitalism: Sandy Weill Says Bring Back Glass–Steagall". Forbes. Retrieved 25 July 2012. Quoting interview on CNBC’s Squawk-Box.

References

Further reading