Jump to content

Fiscal illusion: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Monkbot (talk | contribs)
m Overview: clean up; http->https or pr-URI, per VPP using AWB
Line 6: Line 6:
==Overview==
==Overview==


Fiscal illusion has been used to explain the [[flypaper effect]] often seen when a higher level of government provides a grant to a lower level of government. Here, instead of reducing taxes in order to pass on the benefits of the grant to local taxpayers, the grant-receiving body increases expenditures in order to expand local services in some way. Fiscal illusion is invoked as an explanation because the local taxpayers are under the mistaken perception that the grant is to local government and not, in fact, to them.
Fiscal illusion has been used to explain the [[flypaper effect]] often seen when a higher level of government provides a grant to a lower level of government. Here, instead of reducing taxes in order to pass on the benefits of the grant to local taxpayers, the grant-receiving body increases expenditures in order to expand local services in some way. Fiscal illusion is invoked as an explanation because the local taxpayers are under the mistaken perception that the grant is to local government and not, in fact, to them.


Another example of fiscal illusion can be seen in local property tax politics. Here renters, who do not pay local property taxes directly, may vote for an expansion of local government services. Fiscal illusion theory suggests they support this policy because its cost is masked by its roundabout nature (through an increase in their rent payments).{{citation needed|date=January 2011}}
Another example of fiscal illusion can be seen in local property tax politics. Here renters, who do not pay local property taxes directly, may vote for an expansion of local government services. Fiscal illusion theory suggests they support this policy because its cost is masked by its roundabout nature (through an increase in their rent payments).{{citation needed|date=January 2011}}
Line 15: Line 15:
Finally, another example of fiscal illusion may be seen in [[deficit spending]]. [[CATO Institute]] economist [[William Niskanen]] (2004), for instance, has noted that the "[[starve the beast]]" strategy popular among US conservatives wherein tax cuts now force a future reduction in federal government spending is empirically false. Instead, he has found that there is ‘a strong negative relation between the relative level of federal spending and tax revenues.’ Tax cuts and deficit spending, he argues, makes the cost of government appear to be cheaper than it otherwise would be.
Finally, another example of fiscal illusion may be seen in [[deficit spending]]. [[CATO Institute]] economist [[William Niskanen]] (2004), for instance, has noted that the "[[starve the beast]]" strategy popular among US conservatives wherein tax cuts now force a future reduction in federal government spending is empirically false. Instead, he has found that there is ‘a strong negative relation between the relative level of federal spending and tax revenues.’ Tax cuts and deficit spending, he argues, makes the cost of government appear to be cheaper than it otherwise would be.


Mourao (2008) attempts to quantify fiscal illusion [[empirical]]ly for almost 70 democracies since 1960.<ref>Mourao, Paulo (2008). "Towards a Puviani's Fiscal Illusion Index". Hacienda Publica Espanola. 4:187187, 49-86 http://ideas.repec.org/a/hpe/journl/y2008v187i4p49-86.html</ref>
Mourao (2008) attempts to quantify fiscal illusion [[empirical]]ly for almost 70 democracies since 1960.<ref>Mourao, Paulo (2008). "Towards a Puviani's Fiscal Illusion Index". Hacienda Publica Espanola. 4:187187, 49-86 https://ideas.repec.org/a/hpe/journl/y2008v187i4p49-86.html</ref>


== See also ==
== See also ==

Revision as of 16:09, 21 March 2015

Fiscal illusion is a public choice theory of government expenditure first developed by the Italian economist Amilcare Puviani in his 1903 book Teoria della illusione finanziaria (Theory of Financial Illusion (not yet translated into English, but translated into German in 1960 under the title Die Illusionen in der öffentlichen Finanzwirtschaft, Berlin: Dunker & Humblot, 1960)).[1][2] Fiscal illusion suggests that when government revenues are not completely transparent or are not fully perceived by taxpayers, then the cost of government is seen to be less expensive than it actually is. Since some or all taxpayers benefit from government expenditures from these unobserved or hidden revenues, the public's appetite for government expenditures increases, thus providing politicians incentive to expand the size of government.

Overview

Fiscal illusion has been used to explain the flypaper effect often seen when a higher level of government provides a grant to a lower level of government. Here, instead of reducing taxes in order to pass on the benefits of the grant to local taxpayers, the grant-receiving body increases expenditures in order to expand local services in some way. Fiscal illusion is invoked as an explanation because the local taxpayers are under the mistaken perception that the grant is to local government and not, in fact, to them.

Another example of fiscal illusion can be seen in local property tax politics. Here renters, who do not pay local property taxes directly, may vote for an expansion of local government services. Fiscal illusion theory suggests they support this policy because its cost is masked by its roundabout nature (through an increase in their rent payments).[citation needed]

In their book Democracy in Deficit (1977), James M. Buchanan and Richard E. Wagner suggest that the complicated nature of the U.S. tax system causes fiscal illusion and results in greater public expenditure than would be the case in an idealized system in which everyone is aware in detail of what their share of the costs of government is.[3]

Finally, another example of fiscal illusion may be seen in deficit spending. CATO Institute economist William Niskanen (2004), for instance, has noted that the "starve the beast" strategy popular among US conservatives wherein tax cuts now force a future reduction in federal government spending is empirically false. Instead, he has found that there is ‘a strong negative relation between the relative level of federal spending and tax revenues.’ Tax cuts and deficit spending, he argues, makes the cost of government appear to be cheaper than it otherwise would be.

Mourao (2008) attempts to quantify fiscal illusion empirically for almost 70 democracies since 1960.[4]

See also

References

  1. ^ Puviani, Amilcare (1897). "Teoria della illusione nelle entrate publiche". Perugia.
  2. ^ Puviani, Amilcare (1903). "Teoria della illusione Finanziaria". Palermo. German translation: Die Illusionen in der öffentlichen Finanzwirtschaft. {{cite journal}}: External link in |series= (help)
  3. ^ Buchanan, James M.; Wagner, Richard E. (1977). Democracy in Deficit: The Political Legacy of Lord Keynes. New York: Academic Press. ISBN 0-86597-227-3. Retrieved 2011-01-19.
  4. ^ Mourao, Paulo (2008). "Towards a Puviani's Fiscal Illusion Index". Hacienda Publica Espanola. 4:187187, 49-86 https://ideas.repec.org/a/hpe/journl/y2008v187i4p49-86.html

Additional sources

  • Mueller, Dennis C. (2003). Public Choice III. Cambridge University Press. pp. 221–222.
  • Niskanen, William (2002). ‘Starve the Beast’ Does Not Work. CATO Policy Report March/April 2004.