Asset pricing: Difference between revisions
No edit summary |
|||
Line 129: | Line 129: | ||
***[[Rational_pricing #Arbitrage free pricing|#Arbitrage free pricing]] |
***[[Rational_pricing #Arbitrage free pricing|#Arbitrage free pricing]] |
||
***[[Rational pricing #Risk neutral valuation|#Risk neutral valuation]] |
***[[Rational pricing #Risk neutral valuation|#Risk neutral valuation]] |
||
**[[Black–Scholes model]] |
|||
**[[Contingent claim analysis]] |
**[[Contingent claim analysis]] |
||
**[[Brownian model of financial markets]] |
**[[Brownian model of financial markets]] |
Revision as of 08:07, 18 November 2018
Regime Asset class |
Equilibrium pricing |
Risk neutral pricing |
---|---|---|
Equities (and foreign exchange and commodities (and interest rates) for risk neutral pricing) |
||
Bonds, other interest rate instruments |
- For the corporate finance usage, see Valuation (finance).
In financial economics, asset pricing refers to a formal treatment and development of two main pricing principles,[1] with the resultant models, outlined below. "Investment theory", which is near synonymous, encompasses the body of knowledge used to support the decision-making process of choosing investments.[2]
The first principle: general equilibrium asset pricing where prices are determined through market pricing by supply and demand. Here asset prices jointly satisfy the requirement that the quantities of each asset supplied and the quantities demanded must be equal at that price - so called market clearing. These models are born out of modern portfolio theory, with the Capital Asset Pricing Model as the prototypical result.
The second: rational pricing where (usually) derivative prices are calculated such that they are arbitrage-free with respect to more fundamental (equilibrium determined) securities prices; for an overview of the logic, see Rational pricing #Pricing derivatives. The classical model here is Black–Scholes which describes the dynamics of a market including derivatives (with its option pricing formula); leading more generally to Martingale pricing, as well as the aside models.
These principles are interrelated through the Fundamental theorem of asset pricing. Here, "in the absence of arbitrage, the market imposes a probability distribution, called a risk-neutral or equilibrium measure, on the set of possible market scenarios, and... this probability measure determines market prices via discounted expectation". [3] Correspondingly, this essentially means that one may make financial decisions, using the risk neutral probability distribution returning observed (equilibrium) prices. See Financial economics #Arbitrage-free pricing and equilibrium.
Both sets of models are extended to more complex phenomena and situations, and asset pricing then overlaps with mathematical finance. Here, corresponding to the above distinction, an important difference is that these use different probabilities: respectively, the real-world (or actuarial) probability, denoted by "P", and the risk-neutral (or arbitrage-pricing) probability, denoted by "Q". For an overview of the development of the CAPM and Black-Scholes, see Financial economics #Uncertainty; for the more advanced approaches, see #Extensions.
See also
References
- ^ John H. Cochrane (2005). Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press. ISBN 0691121370.
- ^ William N. Goetzmann (2000). An Introduction to Investment Theory (hypertext). Yale School of Management
- ^ Steven Lalley. The Fundamental Theorem of Asset Pricing (course notes). University of Chicago.