Jump to content

Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Monkbot (talk | contribs)
m Task 18 (cosmetic): eval 24 templates: del empty params (6×); hyphenate params (20×);
Line 1: Line 1:
{{Macroeconomics sidebar}}
{{Macroeconomics sidebar}}
The '''Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model''', or '''Ramsey growth model''', is a [[Neoclassical economics|neoclassical]] model of [[economic growth]] based primarily on the work of [[Frank P. Ramsey]],<ref>{{cite journal |first=Frank P. |last=Ramsey |title=A Mathematical Theory of Saving |journal=[[Economic Journal]] |volume=38 |issue=152 |year=1928 |pages=543–559 |doi= 10.2307/2224098|jstor=2224098 }}</ref> with significant extensions by [[David Cass]] and [[Tjalling Koopmans]].<ref>{{cite journal |first=David |last=Cass |title=Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation |journal=[[Review of Economic Studies]] |volume=32 |issue=3 |year=1965 |pages=233–240 |jstor=2295827 |doi=10.2307/2295827 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Koopmans |first=T. C. |year=1965 |chapter=On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth |title=The Economic Approach to Development Planning |location=Chicago |publisher=Rand McNally |pages=225–287 |isbn= }}</ref> The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the [[Solow–Swan model]] in that the choice of [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]] is explicitly [[Microfoundations|microfounded]] at a point in time and so endogenizes the [[saving|savings rate]]. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run [[steady state]]. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is [[Pareto efficiency|Pareto optimal]] or [[Pareto efficiency|Pareto efficient]].<ref group="note">This result is due not just to the endogeneity of the saving rate but also because of the infinite nature of the planning horizon of the agents in the model; it does not hold in other models with endogenous saving rates but more complex intergenerational dynamics, for example, in [[Paul Samuelson|Samuelson's]] or [[Peter Diamond|Diamond's]] [[overlapping generations model]]s.</ref>
The '''Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model''', or '''Ramsey growth model''', is a [[Neoclassical economics|neoclassical]] model of [[economic growth]] based primarily on the work of [[Frank P. Ramsey]],<ref>{{cite journal |first=Frank P. |last=Ramsey |title=A Mathematical Theory of Saving |journal=[[Economic Journal]] |volume=38 |issue=152 |year=1928 |pages=543–559 |doi= 10.2307/2224098|jstor=2224098 }}</ref> with significant extensions by [[David Cass]] and [[Tjalling Koopmans]].<ref>{{cite journal |first=David |last=Cass |title=Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation |journal=[[Review of Economic Studies]] |volume=32 |issue=3 |year=1965 |pages=233–240 |jstor=2295827 |doi=10.2307/2295827 }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |last=Koopmans |first=T. C. |year=1965 |chapter=On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth |title=The Economic Approach to Development Planning |location=Chicago |publisher=Rand McNally |pages=225–287 }}</ref> The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the [[Solow–Swan model]] in that the choice of [[Consumption (economics)|consumption]] is explicitly [[Microfoundations|microfounded]] at a point in time and so endogenizes the [[saving|savings rate]]. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run [[steady state]]. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is [[Pareto efficiency|Pareto optimal]] or [[Pareto efficiency|Pareto efficient]].<ref group="note">This result is due not just to the endogeneity of the saving rate but also because of the infinite nature of the planning horizon of the agents in the model; it does not hold in other models with endogenous saving rates but more complex intergenerational dynamics, for example, in [[Paul Samuelson|Samuelson's]] or [[Peter Diamond|Diamond's]] [[overlapping generations model]]s.</ref>


Originally Ramsey set out the model as a [[social planner]]'s problem of maximizing levels of consumption over successive generations.<ref>{{cite book |first=David A. |last=Collard |chapter=Ramsey, saving and the generations |title=Generations of Economists |location=London |publisher=Routledge |year=2011 |chapterurl={{Google books |plainurl=yes |id=B4MG8XzM3qYC |page=256 }} |isbn=978-0-415-56541-7 |pages=256–273 }}</ref> Only later was a model adopted by Cass and Koopmans as a description of a decentralized dynamic economy with a [[representative agent]]. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model aims only at explaining long-run economic growth rather than business cycle fluctuations, and does not include any sources of disturbances like market imperfections, heterogeneity among households, or exogenous [[Shock (economics)|shocks]]. Subsequent researchers therefore extended the model, allowing for government-purchases shocks, variations in employment, and other sources of disturbances, which is known as [[real business cycle theory]].
Originally Ramsey set out the model as a [[social planner]]'s problem of maximizing levels of consumption over successive generations.<ref>{{cite book |first=David A. |last=Collard |chapter=Ramsey, saving and the generations |title=Generations of Economists |location=London |publisher=Routledge |year=2011 |chapter-url={{Google books |plainurl=yes |id=B4MG8XzM3qYC |page=256 }} |isbn=978-0-415-56541-7 |pages=256–273 }}</ref> Only later was a model adopted by Cass and Koopmans as a description of a decentralized dynamic economy with a [[representative agent]]. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model aims only at explaining long-run economic growth rather than business cycle fluctuations, and does not include any sources of disturbances like market imperfections, heterogeneity among households, or exogenous [[Shock (economics)|shocks]]. Subsequent researchers therefore extended the model, allowing for government-purchases shocks, variations in employment, and other sources of disturbances, which is known as [[real business cycle theory]].


==Mathematical description==
==Mathematical description==
Line 18: Line 18:
where an initial non-zero capital stock <math>k(0) = k_{0} > 0</math> is given. The solution to this problem, usually found by using a [[Hamiltonian (control theory)|Hamiltonian function]],<ref group="note">The Hamiltonian for the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans problem is
where an initial non-zero capital stock <math>k(0) = k_{0} > 0</math> is given. The solution to this problem, usually found by using a [[Hamiltonian (control theory)|Hamiltonian function]],<ref group="note">The Hamiltonian for the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans problem is
:<math>H = e^{-\rho t} u(c) + \mu \left[ f(k) - (n + \delta) k - c \right]</math>
:<math>H = e^{-\rho t} u(c) + \mu \left[ f(k) - (n + \delta) k - c \right]</math>
where <math>\mu</math> is the [[Costate equation|costate variable]] usually economically interpreted as the [[shadow price]]. Because the terminal value of <math>k</math> is free but may not be negative, a [[Transversality (mathematics)|transversality condition]] <math>\lim_{t \to \infty} \mu \cdot k = 0</math> similar to the [[Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions|Karush–Kuhn–Tucker “complementary slackness” condition]] is required. From the first-order conditions for maximization of the Hamiltonian one can derive the equation of motion for consumption, see {{cite book |first=Brian S. |last=Ferguson |first2=G. C. |last2=Lim |title=Introduction to Dynamic Economic Models |location= |publisher=Manchester University Press |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-7190-4997-2 |pages=174–175 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/RmCAmgEACAAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA174 |postscript=none }}, or {{cite book |first=Giancarlo |last=Gandolfo |authorlink=Giancarlo Gandolfo |title=Economic Dynamics |location=Berlin |publisher=Springer |edition=3rd |year=1996 |isbn=978-3-540-60988-9 |pages=381–384 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/ZMwXi67nhHQC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA381 }}</ref><ref group="note">The problem can also be solved with classical [[calculus of variations]] methods, see {{cite book |first=G. |last=Hadley |first2=M. C. |last2=Kemp |title=Variational Methods in Economics |location=New York |publisher=Elsevier |year=1971 |isbn=978-0-444-10097-9 |pages=50–71 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/tqujBQAAQBAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA50 }}
where <math>\mu</math> is the [[Costate equation|costate variable]] usually economically interpreted as the [[shadow price]]. Because the terminal value of <math>k</math> is free but may not be negative, a [[Transversality (mathematics)|transversality condition]] <math>\lim_{t \to \infty} \mu \cdot k = 0</math> similar to the [[Karush–Kuhn–Tucker conditions|Karush–Kuhn–Tucker “complementary slackness” condition]] is required. From the first-order conditions for maximization of the Hamiltonian one can derive the equation of motion for consumption, see {{cite book |first=Brian S. |last=Ferguson |first2=G. C. |last2=Lim |title=Introduction to Dynamic Economic Models |publisher=Manchester University Press |year=1998 |isbn=978-0-7190-4997-2 |pages=174–175 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/RmCAmgEACAAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA174 |postscript=none }}, or {{cite book |first=Giancarlo |last=Gandolfo |author-link=Giancarlo Gandolfo |title=Economic Dynamics |location=Berlin |publisher=Springer |edition=3rd |year=1996 |isbn=978-3-540-60988-9 |pages=381–384 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/ZMwXi67nhHQC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA381 }}</ref><ref group="note">The problem can also be solved with classical [[calculus of variations]] methods, see {{cite book |first=G. |last=Hadley |first2=M. C. |last2=Kemp |title=Variational Methods in Economics |location=New York |publisher=Elsevier |year=1971 |isbn=978-0-444-10097-9 |pages=50–71 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/tqujBQAAQBAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA50 }}


</ref> is a non-linear differential equation that describes the optimal evolution of consumption,
</ref> is a non-linear differential equation that describes the optimal evolution of consumption,
Line 36: Line 36:
Hence by the [[stable manifold theorem]], the equilibrium is a [[saddle point]] and there exists a unique stable arm, or “saddle path”, that converges on the equilibrium, indicated by the blue curve in the phase diagram. The system is called “saddle path stable” since all unstable trajectories are ruled out by the “no [[Ponzi scheme]]” condition:<ref>{{cite book |first=Terry L. |last=Roe |first2=Rodney B. W. |last2=Smith |first3=D. Sirin |last3=Saracoglu |title=Multisector Growth Models: Theory and Application |location=New York |publisher=Springer |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-387-77358-2 |page=48 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/-NzlllN-OAIC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA48 }}</ref>
Hence by the [[stable manifold theorem]], the equilibrium is a [[saddle point]] and there exists a unique stable arm, or “saddle path”, that converges on the equilibrium, indicated by the blue curve in the phase diagram. The system is called “saddle path stable” since all unstable trajectories are ruled out by the “no [[Ponzi scheme]]” condition:<ref>{{cite book |first=Terry L. |last=Roe |first2=Rodney B. W. |last2=Smith |first3=D. Sirin |last3=Saracoglu |title=Multisector Growth Models: Theory and Application |location=New York |publisher=Springer |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-387-77358-2 |page=48 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/-NzlllN-OAIC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA48 }}</ref>
:<math>\lim_{t \to \infty} k \cdot e^{- \int_{0}^{t} \left( f_{k} - n - \delta \right) \mathrm{d} s } \geq 0</math>
:<math>\lim_{t \to \infty} k \cdot e^{- \int_{0}^{t} \left( f_{k} - n - \delta \right) \mathrm{d} s } \geq 0</math>
implying that the [[present value]] of the capital stock cannot be negative.<ref group="note">It can be shown that the “no Ponzi scheme” condition follows from the transversality condition on the Hamiltonian, see {{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |authorlink1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |authorlink2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/jD3ASoSQJ-AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA91 |pages=91–92 }}</ref>
implying that the [[present value]] of the capital stock cannot be negative.<ref group="note">It can be shown that the “no Ponzi scheme” condition follows from the transversality condition on the Hamiltonian, see {{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |author-link1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |author-link2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 |url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/jD3ASoSQJ-AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA91 |pages=91–92 }}</ref>


{{clear}}
{{clear}}
Line 50: Line 50:
Over their lifetimes, neither Cass nor Koopmans ever suggested that their results characterizing optimal growth in the one-sector, continuous-time growth model were anything other than "simultaneous and independent". That the issue of priority ever became a discussion point was due only to the fact that in the published version of Koopmans' work, he cited the chapter from Cass' thesis that later became the ''RES'' paper. In his paper, Koopmans states in a footnote that Cass independently obtained conditions similar to what Koopmans finds, and that Cass also considers the limiting case where the discount rate goes to zero in his paper. For his part, Cass notes that "after the original version of this paper was completed, a very similar analysis by Koopmans came to our attention. We draw on his results in discussing the limiting case, where the effective social discount rate goes to zero". In the interview that Cass gave to ''Macroeconomic Dynamics'', he credits Koopmans with pointing him to Frank Ramsey's previous work, claiming to have been embarrassed not to have known of it, but says nothing to dispel the basic claim that his work and Koopmans' were in fact independent.
Over their lifetimes, neither Cass nor Koopmans ever suggested that their results characterizing optimal growth in the one-sector, continuous-time growth model were anything other than "simultaneous and independent". That the issue of priority ever became a discussion point was due only to the fact that in the published version of Koopmans' work, he cited the chapter from Cass' thesis that later became the ''RES'' paper. In his paper, Koopmans states in a footnote that Cass independently obtained conditions similar to what Koopmans finds, and that Cass also considers the limiting case where the discount rate goes to zero in his paper. For his part, Cass notes that "after the original version of this paper was completed, a very similar analysis by Koopmans came to our attention. We draw on his results in discussing the limiting case, where the effective social discount rate goes to zero". In the interview that Cass gave to ''Macroeconomic Dynamics'', he credits Koopmans with pointing him to Frank Ramsey's previous work, claiming to have been embarrassed not to have known of it, but says nothing to dispel the basic claim that his work and Koopmans' were in fact independent.


Spear and Young dispute this history, based upon a previously overlooked working paper version of Koopmans' paper,<ref>{{cite paper |last=Koopmans |first=Tjalling |title=On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth |work=Cowles Foundation Discussion paper 163 |date=December 1963 |url=http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/P/cd/d01b/d0163.pdf }}</ref> which was the basis for Koopmans' oft-cited presentation at a conference held by the [[Pontifical Academy of Sciences]] in October 1963.<ref>{{cite book |last=McKenzie |first=Lionel |authorlink=Lionel McKenzie |chapter=Some Early Conferences on Growth Theory |pages=3–18 |title=Essays in Economic Theory, Growth and Labor Markets |editor1-first=George |editor1-last=Bitros |editor2-first=Yannis |editor2-last=Katsoulacos |location=Cheltenham |publisher=Edward Elgar |year=2002 |isbn=978-1-84064-739-6 }}</ref> In this Cowles Discussion paper, there is an error. Koopmans claims in his main result that the Euler equations are both necessary and sufficient to characterize optimal trajectories in the model because any solutions to the Euler equations which do not converge to the optimal steady-state would hit either a zero consumption or zero capital boundary in finite time. This error was apparently presented at the Vatican conference, although at the time of Koopmans' presenting it, no participant commented on the problem. This can be inferred because the discussion after each paper presentation at the Vatican conference is preserved verbatim in the conference volume.
Spear and Young dispute this history, based upon a previously overlooked working paper version of Koopmans' paper,<ref>{{cite paper |last=Koopmans |first=Tjalling |title=On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth |work=Cowles Foundation Discussion paper 163 |date=December 1963 |url=http://cowles.econ.yale.edu/P/cd/d01b/d0163.pdf }}</ref> which was the basis for Koopmans' oft-cited presentation at a conference held by the [[Pontifical Academy of Sciences]] in October 1963.<ref>{{cite book |last=McKenzie |first=Lionel |author-link=Lionel McKenzie |chapter=Some Early Conferences on Growth Theory |pages=3–18 |title=Essays in Economic Theory, Growth and Labor Markets |editor1-first=George |editor1-last=Bitros |editor2-first=Yannis |editor2-last=Katsoulacos |location=Cheltenham |publisher=Edward Elgar |year=2002 |isbn=978-1-84064-739-6 }}</ref> In this Cowles Discussion paper, there is an error. Koopmans claims in his main result that the Euler equations are both necessary and sufficient to characterize optimal trajectories in the model because any solutions to the Euler equations which do not converge to the optimal steady-state would hit either a zero consumption or zero capital boundary in finite time. This error was apparently presented at the Vatican conference, although at the time of Koopmans' presenting it, no participant commented on the problem. This can be inferred because the discussion after each paper presentation at the Vatican conference is preserved verbatim in the conference volume.


In the Vatican volume discussion following the presentation of a paper by [[Edmond Malinvaud]], the issue does arise because of Malinvaud's explicit inclusion of a so-called "transversality condition" (which Malinvaud calls Condition I) in his paper. At the end of the presentation, Koopmans asks Malinvaud whether it is not the case that Condition I simply guarantees that solutions to the Euler equations that do not converge to the optimal steady-state hit a boundary in finite time. Malinvaud replies that this is not the case, and suggests that Koopmans look at the example with log utility functions and Cobb-Douglas production functions.
In the Vatican volume discussion following the presentation of a paper by [[Edmond Malinvaud]], the issue does arise because of Malinvaud's explicit inclusion of a so-called "transversality condition" (which Malinvaud calls Condition I) in his paper. At the end of the presentation, Koopmans asks Malinvaud whether it is not the case that Condition I simply guarantees that solutions to the Euler equations that do not converge to the optimal steady-state hit a boundary in finite time. Malinvaud replies that this is not the case, and suggests that Koopmans look at the example with log utility functions and Cobb-Douglas production functions.
Line 58: Line 58:
From the ''Macroeconomic Dynamics'' interview with Cass, it is clear that Koopmans met with Cass' thesis advisor, [[Hirofumi Uzawa]], at the winter meetings of the [[Econometric Society]] in January 1964, where Uzawa advised him that his student [Cass] had solved this problem already. Uzawa must have then provided Koopmans with the copy of Cass' thesis chapter, which he apparently sent along in the guise of the IMSSS Technical Report that Koopmans cited in the published version of his paper. The word "guise" is appropriate here, because the TR number listed in Koopmans' citation would have put the issue date of the report in the early 1950s, which it clearly was not.
From the ''Macroeconomic Dynamics'' interview with Cass, it is clear that Koopmans met with Cass' thesis advisor, [[Hirofumi Uzawa]], at the winter meetings of the [[Econometric Society]] in January 1964, where Uzawa advised him that his student [Cass] had solved this problem already. Uzawa must have then provided Koopmans with the copy of Cass' thesis chapter, which he apparently sent along in the guise of the IMSSS Technical Report that Koopmans cited in the published version of his paper. The word "guise" is appropriate here, because the TR number listed in Koopmans' citation would have put the issue date of the report in the early 1950s, which it clearly was not.


In the published version of Koopmans' paper, he imposes a new Condition Alpha in addition to the Euler equations, stating that the only admissible trajectories among those satisfying the Euler equations is the one that converges to the optimal steady-state equilibrium of the model. This result is derived in Cass' paper via the imposition of a transversality condition that Cass deduced from relevant sections of a book by [[Lev Pontryagin]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Pontryagin |first=Lev |last2=Boltyansky |first2=Vladimir |last3=Gamkrelidze |first3=Revaz |last4=Mishchenko |first4=Evgenii |title=The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes |location=New York |publisher=John Wiley |edition= |year=1962 |isbn= }}</ref> Spear and Young conjecture that Koopmans took this route because he did not want to appear to be "borrowing" either Malinvaud's or Cass' transversality technology.
In the published version of Koopmans' paper, he imposes a new Condition Alpha in addition to the Euler equations, stating that the only admissible trajectories among those satisfying the Euler equations is the one that converges to the optimal steady-state equilibrium of the model. This result is derived in Cass' paper via the imposition of a transversality condition that Cass deduced from relevant sections of a book by [[Lev Pontryagin]].<ref>{{cite book |last=Pontryagin |first=Lev |last2=Boltyansky |first2=Vladimir |last3=Gamkrelidze |first3=Revaz |last4=Mishchenko |first4=Evgenii |title=The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes |location=New York |publisher=John Wiley |year=1962 }}</ref> Spear and Young conjecture that Koopmans took this route because he did not want to appear to be "borrowing" either Malinvaud's or Cass' transversality technology.


Based on this and other examination of Malinvaud's contributions in 1950s—specifically his intuition of the importance of the transversality condition—Spear and Young suggest that the neo-classical growth model might better be called the Ramsey–Malinvaud–Cass model than the established Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans honorific.
Based on this and other examination of Malinvaud's contributions in 1950s—specifically his intuition of the importance of the transversality condition—Spear and Young suggest that the neo-classical growth model might better be called the Ramsey–Malinvaud–Cass model than the established Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans honorific.
Line 69: Line 69:


==Further reading==
==Further reading==
* {{cite book |first=Daron |last=Acemoglu|authorlink=Daron Acemoglu |chapter=The Neoclassical Growth Model |title=Introduction to Modern Economic Growth |location=Princeton |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-691-13292-1 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/DsPH5fWNdrsC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA287 |pages=287–326 }}
* {{cite book |first=Daron |last=Acemoglu|author-link=Daron Acemoglu |chapter=The Neoclassical Growth Model |title=Introduction to Modern Economic Growth |location=Princeton |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-691-13292-1 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/DsPH5fWNdrsC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA287 |pages=287–326 }}
* {{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |authorlink1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |authorlink2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |chapter=Growth Models with Consumer Optimization |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/jD3ASoSQJ-AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA85 |pages=85–142 }}
* {{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |author-link1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |author-link2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |chapter=Growth Models with Consumer Optimization |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/jD3ASoSQJ-AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA85 |pages=85–142 }}
* {{cite book |first=Jean-Pascal |last=Bénassy |authorlink=Jean-Pascal Bénassy |chapter=The Ramsey Model |title=Macroeconomic Theory |location=New York |publisher=Oxford University Press |edition= |year=2011 |isbn=978-0-19-538771-1 |pages=145–160 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/8SHtW0BCK2AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA145 }}
* {{cite book |first=Jean-Pascal |last=Bénassy |author-link=Jean-Pascal Bénassy |chapter=The Ramsey Model |title=Macroeconomic Theory |location=New York |publisher=Oxford University Press |year=2011 |isbn=978-0-19-538771-1 |pages=145–160 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/8SHtW0BCK2AC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA145 }}
* {{cite book |first=Olivier Jean |last=Blanchard |authorlink=Olivier Blanchard |first2=Stanley |last2=Fischer |authorlink2=Stanley Fischer |chapter=Consumption and Investment: Basic Infinite Horizon Models |title=Lectures on Macroeconomics |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |year=1989 |isbn=978-0-262-02283-5 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/j_zs7htz9moC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA37 |pages=37–89 }}
* {{cite book |first=Olivier Jean |last=Blanchard |author-link=Olivier Blanchard |first2=Stanley |last2=Fischer |author-link2=Stanley Fischer |chapter=Consumption and Investment: Basic Infinite Horizon Models |title=Lectures on Macroeconomics |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |year=1989 |isbn=978-0-262-02283-5 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/j_zs7htz9moC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA37 |pages=37–89 }}
* {{cite book |first=Jianjun |last=Miao |authorlink=Jianjun Miao |chapter=Neoclassical Growth Models |title=Economic Dynamics in Discrete Time |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |year=2014 |isbn=978-0-262-02761-8 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/mByEBAAAQBAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA353 |pages=353–364 }}
* {{cite book |first=Jianjun |last=Miao |author-link=Jianjun Miao |chapter=Neoclassical Growth Models |title=Economic Dynamics in Discrete Time |location=Cambridge |publisher=MIT Press |year=2014 |isbn=978-0-262-02761-8 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/mByEBAAAQBAJ?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA353 |pages=353–364 }}
* {{cite book |first=Alfonso |last=Novales |authorlink=Alfonso Novales |first2=Esther |last2=Fernández |first3=Jesús |last3=Ruíz |chapter=Optimal Growth: Continuous Time Analysis |title=Economic Growth: Theory and Numerical Solution Methods |location=Berlin |publisher=Springer |edition= |year=2009 |isbn=978-3-540-68665-1 |chapterurl=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/EpZzFRa3exgC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA101 |pages=101–154 }}
* {{cite book |first=Alfonso |last=Novales |author-link=Alfonso Novales |first2=Esther |last2=Fernández |first3=Jesús |last3=Ruíz |chapter=Optimal Growth: Continuous Time Analysis |title=Economic Growth: Theory and Numerical Solution Methods |location=Berlin |publisher=Springer |year=2009 |isbn=978-3-540-68665-1 |chapter-url=https://www.google.com/books/edition/_/EpZzFRa3exgC?hl=en&gbpv=1&pg=PA101 |pages=101–154 }}
* {{cite book |first=David |last=Romer |authorlink=David Romer |chapter=Infinite-Horizon and Overlapping-Generations Models |title=Advanced Macroeconomics |edition=Fourth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2011 |pages=49–77 |isbn=978-0-07-351137-5 }}
* {{cite book |first=David |last=Romer |author-link=David Romer |chapter=Infinite-Horizon and Overlapping-Generations Models |title=Advanced Macroeconomics |edition=Fourth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2011 |pages=49–77 |isbn=978-0-07-351137-5 }}


==External links==
==External links==

Revision as of 13:54, 7 December 2020

The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model, or Ramsey growth model, is a neoclassical model of economic growth based primarily on the work of Frank P. Ramsey,[1] with significant extensions by David Cass and Tjalling Koopmans.[2][3] The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model differs from the Solow–Swan model in that the choice of consumption is explicitly microfounded at a point in time and so endogenizes the savings rate. As a result, unlike in the Solow–Swan model, the saving rate may not be constant along the transition to the long run steady state. Another implication of the model is that the outcome is Pareto optimal or Pareto efficient.[note 1]

Originally Ramsey set out the model as a social planner's problem of maximizing levels of consumption over successive generations.[4] Only later was a model adopted by Cass and Koopmans as a description of a decentralized dynamic economy with a representative agent. The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model aims only at explaining long-run economic growth rather than business cycle fluctuations, and does not include any sources of disturbances like market imperfections, heterogeneity among households, or exogenous shocks. Subsequent researchers therefore extended the model, allowing for government-purchases shocks, variations in employment, and other sources of disturbances, which is known as real business cycle theory.

Mathematical description

The Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model starts with an aggregate production function that satisfies the Inada conditions, often specified to be of Cobb–Douglas type, , with factors capital and labour . Since this production function is assumed to be homogeneous of degree 1, one can express it in per capita terms, . The amount of labour is equal to the population in the economy, and grows at a constant rate , i.e. where was the population in the initial period.

The first key equation of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model is the state equation for capital accumulation:

a non-linear differential equation akin to the Solow–Swan model, where is capital intensity (i.e., capital per worker), is shorthand in Newton's notation for change in capital intensity over time, is consumption per worker, is output per worker for a given , and is the depreciation rate of capital. Under the simplifying assumption that there is no population growth, this equation states that investment, or increase in capital per worker is that part of output which is not consumed, minus the rate of depreciation of capital. Investment is, therefore, the same as savings.

The second equation of the model is the solution to the social planner's problem of maximizing a social welfare function, , that consists of the stream of exponentially discounted instantaneous utility from consumption, where is a discount rate reflecting time preference. It is assumed that the economy is populated by identical individuals, such that the optimal control problem can be stated in terms of an infinitely-lived representative agent with time-invariant utility: . The utility function is assumed to be strictly increasing (i.e., there is no bliss point) and concave in , with ,[note 2] where is short-hand notation for the marginal utility of consumption . Normalizing the initial population to one, the problem can be stated as:

where an initial non-zero capital stock is given. The solution to this problem, usually found by using a Hamiltonian function,[note 3][note 4] is a non-linear differential equation that describes the optimal evolution of consumption,

which is known as the Keynes–Ramsey rule.[5] The term , where is short-hand notation for the marginal product of capital , reflects the marginal return on net investment. The expression reflects the curvature of the utility function; its reciprocal is known as the (intertemporal) elasticity of substitution and indicates how much the representative agent wishes to smooth consumption over time. It is often assumed that this elasticity is a positive constant, i.e. .

Phase space graph (or phase diagram) of the Ramsey model. The blue line represents the dynamic adjustment (or saddle) path of the economy in which all the constraints present in the model are satisfied. It is a stable path of the dynamic system. The red lines represent dynamic paths which are ruled out by the transversality condition.

The two coupled differential equations for and form the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans dynamical system. Its steady state, which is found by setting and equal to zero, is given by the pair implicitly defined by

A qualitative statement about the stability of the solution requires a linearization by a first-order Taylor polynomial

where is the Jacobian matrix evaluated at steady state,[note 5] given by

which has determinant since is always positive, is positive by assumption, and only is negative since is concave. Since the determinant equals the product of the eigenvalues, the eigenvalues must be real and opposite in sign.[6] Hence by the stable manifold theorem, the equilibrium is a saddle point and there exists a unique stable arm, or “saddle path”, that converges on the equilibrium, indicated by the blue curve in the phase diagram. The system is called “saddle path stable” since all unstable trajectories are ruled out by the “no Ponzi scheme” condition:[7]

implying that the present value of the capital stock cannot be negative.[note 6]

History

Spear and Young re-examine the history of optimal growth during the 1950s and 1960s,[8] focusing in part on the veracity of the claimed simultaneous and independent development of Cass' "Optimum growth in an aggregative model of capital accumulation" (published in 1965 in the Review of Economic Studies), and Tjalling Koopman's "On the concept of optimal economic growth" (published in Study Week on the Econometric Approach to Development Planning, 1965, Rome: Pontifical Academy of Science).

Over their lifetimes, neither Cass nor Koopmans ever suggested that their results characterizing optimal growth in the one-sector, continuous-time growth model were anything other than "simultaneous and independent". That the issue of priority ever became a discussion point was due only to the fact that in the published version of Koopmans' work, he cited the chapter from Cass' thesis that later became the RES paper. In his paper, Koopmans states in a footnote that Cass independently obtained conditions similar to what Koopmans finds, and that Cass also considers the limiting case where the discount rate goes to zero in his paper. For his part, Cass notes that "after the original version of this paper was completed, a very similar analysis by Koopmans came to our attention. We draw on his results in discussing the limiting case, where the effective social discount rate goes to zero". In the interview that Cass gave to Macroeconomic Dynamics, he credits Koopmans with pointing him to Frank Ramsey's previous work, claiming to have been embarrassed not to have known of it, but says nothing to dispel the basic claim that his work and Koopmans' were in fact independent.

Spear and Young dispute this history, based upon a previously overlooked working paper version of Koopmans' paper,[9] which was the basis for Koopmans' oft-cited presentation at a conference held by the Pontifical Academy of Sciences in October 1963.[10] In this Cowles Discussion paper, there is an error. Koopmans claims in his main result that the Euler equations are both necessary and sufficient to characterize optimal trajectories in the model because any solutions to the Euler equations which do not converge to the optimal steady-state would hit either a zero consumption or zero capital boundary in finite time. This error was apparently presented at the Vatican conference, although at the time of Koopmans' presenting it, no participant commented on the problem. This can be inferred because the discussion after each paper presentation at the Vatican conference is preserved verbatim in the conference volume.

In the Vatican volume discussion following the presentation of a paper by Edmond Malinvaud, the issue does arise because of Malinvaud's explicit inclusion of a so-called "transversality condition" (which Malinvaud calls Condition I) in his paper. At the end of the presentation, Koopmans asks Malinvaud whether it is not the case that Condition I simply guarantees that solutions to the Euler equations that do not converge to the optimal steady-state hit a boundary in finite time. Malinvaud replies that this is not the case, and suggests that Koopmans look at the example with log utility functions and Cobb-Douglas production functions.

At this point, Koopmans obviously recognizes he has a problem, but, based on a confusing appendix to a later version of the paper produced after the Vatican conference, he seems unable to decide how to deal with the issue raised by Malinvaud's Condition I.

From the Macroeconomic Dynamics interview with Cass, it is clear that Koopmans met with Cass' thesis advisor, Hirofumi Uzawa, at the winter meetings of the Econometric Society in January 1964, where Uzawa advised him that his student [Cass] had solved this problem already. Uzawa must have then provided Koopmans with the copy of Cass' thesis chapter, which he apparently sent along in the guise of the IMSSS Technical Report that Koopmans cited in the published version of his paper. The word "guise" is appropriate here, because the TR number listed in Koopmans' citation would have put the issue date of the report in the early 1950s, which it clearly was not.

In the published version of Koopmans' paper, he imposes a new Condition Alpha in addition to the Euler equations, stating that the only admissible trajectories among those satisfying the Euler equations is the one that converges to the optimal steady-state equilibrium of the model. This result is derived in Cass' paper via the imposition of a transversality condition that Cass deduced from relevant sections of a book by Lev Pontryagin.[11] Spear and Young conjecture that Koopmans took this route because he did not want to appear to be "borrowing" either Malinvaud's or Cass' transversality technology.

Based on this and other examination of Malinvaud's contributions in 1950s—specifically his intuition of the importance of the transversality condition—Spear and Young suggest that the neo-classical growth model might better be called the Ramsey–Malinvaud–Cass model than the established Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans honorific.

Notes

  1. ^ This result is due not just to the endogeneity of the saving rate but also because of the infinite nature of the planning horizon of the agents in the model; it does not hold in other models with endogenous saving rates but more complex intergenerational dynamics, for example, in Samuelson's or Diamond's overlapping generations models.
  2. ^ The assumption that is in fact crucial for the analysis. If , then for low values of the optimal value of is 0 and therefore if is sufficiently low there exists an initial time interval where even if , see Nævdal, E. (2019). "New Insights From The Canonical Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans Growth Model". Macroeconomic Dynamics. doi:10.1017/S1365100519000786.
  3. ^ The Hamiltonian for the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans problem is
    where is the costate variable usually economically interpreted as the shadow price. Because the terminal value of is free but may not be negative, a transversality condition similar to the Karush–Kuhn–Tucker “complementary slackness” condition is required. From the first-order conditions for maximization of the Hamiltonian one can derive the equation of motion for consumption, see Ferguson, Brian S.; Lim, G. C. (1998). Introduction to Dynamic Economic Models. Manchester University Press. pp. 174–175. ISBN 978-0-7190-4997-2, or Gandolfo, Giancarlo (1996). Economic Dynamics (3rd ed.). Berlin: Springer. pp. 381–384. ISBN 978-3-540-60988-9.
  4. ^ The problem can also be solved with classical calculus of variations methods, see Hadley, G.; Kemp, M. C. (1971). Variational Methods in Economics. New York: Elsevier. pp. 50–71. ISBN 978-0-444-10097-9.
  5. ^ The Jacobian matrix of the Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans system is
    See Afonso, Oscar; Vasconcelos, Paulo B. (2016). Computational Economics : A Concise Introduction. New York: Routledge. p. 163. ISBN 978-1-138-85965-4.
  6. ^ It can be shown that the “no Ponzi scheme” condition follows from the transversality condition on the Hamiltonian, see Barro, Robert J.; Sala-i-Martin, Xavier (2004). Economic Growth (Second ed.). New York: McGraw-Hill. pp. 91–92. ISBN 978-0-262-02553-9.

References

  1. ^ Ramsey, Frank P. (1928). "A Mathematical Theory of Saving". Economic Journal. 38 (152): 543–559. doi:10.2307/2224098. JSTOR 2224098.
  2. ^ Cass, David (1965). "Optimum Growth in an Aggregative Model of Capital Accumulation". Review of Economic Studies. 32 (3): 233–240. doi:10.2307/2295827. JSTOR 2295827.
  3. ^ Koopmans, T. C. (1965). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth". The Economic Approach to Development Planning. Chicago: Rand McNally. pp. 225–287.
  4. ^ Collard, David A. (2011). "Ramsey, saving and the generations". Generations of Economists. London: Routledge. pp. 256–273. ISBN 978-0-415-56541-7.
  5. ^ Blanchard, Olivier Jean; Fischer, Stanley (1989). Lectures on Macroeconomics. Cambridge: MIT Press. pp. 41–43. ISBN 978-0-262-02283-5.
  6. ^ Beavis, Brian; Dobbs, Ian (1990). Optimization and Stability Theory for Economic Analysis. New York: Cambridge University Press. p. 157. ISBN 978-0-521-33605-5.
  7. ^ Roe, Terry L.; Smith, Rodney B. W.; Saracoglu, D. Sirin (2009). Multisector Growth Models: Theory and Application. New York: Springer. p. 48. ISBN 978-0-387-77358-2.
  8. ^ Spear, S. E.; Young, W. (2014). "Optimum Savings and Optimal Growth: The Cass–Malinvaud–Koopmans Nexus". Macroeconomic Dynamics. 18 (1): 215–243. doi:10.1017/S1365100513000291.
  9. ^ Koopmans, Tjalling (December 1963). "On the Concept of Optimal Economic Growth" (PDF). Cowles Foundation Discussion paper 163.
  10. ^ McKenzie, Lionel (2002). "Some Early Conferences on Growth Theory". In Bitros, George; Katsoulacos, Yannis (eds.). Essays in Economic Theory, Growth and Labor Markets. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. pp. 3–18. ISBN 978-1-84064-739-6.
  11. ^ Pontryagin, Lev; Boltyansky, Vladimir; Gamkrelidze, Revaz; Mishchenko, Evgenii (1962). The Mathematical Theory of Optimal Processes. New York: John Wiley.

Further reading