Jump to content

Monetary base: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
m v2.04b - Bot T20 CW#61 - Fix errors for CW project (Reference before punctuation)
Monkbot (talk | contribs)
m Task 18 (cosmetic): eval 6 templates: hyphenate params (6×);
Line 44: Line 44:
| last = Brunner
| last = Brunner
| first = Karl
| first = Karl
| authorlink = Karl Brunner (economist)
| author-link = Karl Brunner (economist)
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
Line 54: Line 54:
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.2726
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.2726
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* {{Cite book
* {{Cite book
| last = Goodhart
| last = Goodhart
| first = Charles
| first = Charles
| authorlink = Charles Goodhart
| author-link = Charles Goodhart
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| editor = Newman, Peter K. |editor2=Eatwell, John |editor3=Palgrave, Robert Harry Inglis |editor4=Milgate, Murray
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
| title = The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics
Line 69: Line 69:
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| isbn=0-935859-10-1
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.3102
| doi = 10.1057/9780230226203.3102
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* {{Cite book
* {{Cite book
| last = Cagan
| last = Cagan
| first = Phillip
| first = Phillip
| authorlink = Phillip Cagan
| author-link = Phillip Cagan
| title = Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960
| title = Determinants and Effects of Changes in the Stock of Money, 1875-1960
| publisher = National Bureau of Economic Research
| publisher = National Bureau of Economic Research
Line 83: Line 83:
| pages = 45–117
| pages = 45–117
| isbn = 0-87014-097-3
| isbn = 0-87014-097-3
| accessdate = 8 February 2011
| access-date = 8 February 2011
}}
}}
* [http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current/h3.htm Aggregate Reserves Of Depository Institutions And The Monetary Base (H.3)]
* [http://www.federalreserve.gov/releases/h3/Current/h3.htm Aggregate Reserves Of Depository Institutions And The Monetary Base (H.3)]

Revision as of 04:32, 10 January 2021

Euro monetary base

In economics, the monetary base (also base money, money base, high-powered money, reserve money, outside money, central bank money or, in the UK, narrow money) in a country is the total amount of bank notes and coins. This includes:

The monetary base should not be confused with the money supply, which consists of the total currency circulating in the public plus certain types of non-bank deposits with commercial banks.

Management

U.S. Monetary base

Open market operations are monetary policy tools which directly expand or contract the monetary base.

The monetary base is manipulated during the conduct of monetary policy by a finance ministry or the central bank. These institutions change the monetary base through open market operations: the buying and selling of government bonds. For example, if they buy government bonds from commercial banks, they pay for them by adding new amounts to the banks’ reserve deposits at the central bank, the latter being a component of the monetary base.

Typically, a central bank can also influence banking activities by manipulating interest rates and setting reserve requirements (how much money banks must keep on hand instead of loaning out to borrowers). Interest rates, especially on federal funds (ultra-short-term loans between banks), are themselves influenced by open market operations.

The monetary base has traditionally been considered high-powered because its increase will typically result in a much larger increase in the supply of demand deposits through banks' loan-making, a ratio called the money multiplier.[3] However, for those that do not agree with the theory of the money multiplier, the monetary base can be thought of as high powered because of the fiscal multiplier instead.

Monetary policy

Monetary Policy is generally presumed to be the policy preserve of Reserve Banks, who target an interest rate. Control of the amount of Base Money in the economy is then lost, as failure by the Reserve Bank to meet the reserve requirements of the banking system will result in banks who are short of reserves bidding up the interest rate. Interest rates are manipulated by the Reserve bank to maintain an inflation rate which is considered neither too high or too low. This is usually determined using a Taylor Rule. The quantity of reserves in the banking system is supported by the open market operations performed by the Reserve Banks, involving the purchase and sale of various financial instruments, commonly Government debt (bonds), usually using "repos". Banks only require enough reserves to facilitate interbank settlement processes. In some countries, Reserve Banks now pay interest on reserves. This adds another lever to the interest rate control mechanisms available to the Reserve Bank. Following the 2008 financial crisis, Quantitative Easing raised the amount of reserves in the banking system, as the Reserve Banks purchased bad debt from the banks, paying for it with Reserves. This has left the banking system with an oversupply of reserves. This increase in reserves has had no effect on the level of interest rates. Note that reserves are never lent out by banks.

Accounting

Following IFRS standards, base money is registered as a liability of the central banks' balance sheet,[4] implying base money is by nature a debt from the central bank. However, given the special nature of central bank money – which cannot be redeemed in nothing else than base money – numerous scholars such as Michael Kumhof have argued it should rather be recorded as a form of equity.[5]

See also

References

  1. ^ See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulations at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1) and 12 C.F.R. section 204.2.
  2. ^ See, e.g., U.S. Federal Reserve System regulation at 12 C.F.R. section 204.5(a)(1)(i).
  3. ^ Mankiw, N. Gregory (2002), "Chapter 18: Money Supply and Money Demand", Macroeconomics (5th ed.), Worth, pp. 482–489
  4. ^ Archer, David; Moser-Boehm, Paul (29 April 2013). "Central bank finances". {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  5. ^ Kumhof, Michael; Allen, Jason G.; Bateman, Will; Lastra, Rosa M.; Gleeson, Simon; Omarova, Saule T. (14 November 2020). "Central Bank Money: Liability, Asset, or Equity of the Nation?". Rochester, NY. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)