Jump to content

Talk:Fiat money

Page contents not supported in other languages.
From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by 99.254.75.46 (talk) at 19:03, 27 June 2008 (wikiproject classification). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

WikiProject iconNumismatics B‑class High‑importance
WikiProject iconThis article is within the scope of WikiProject Numismatics, a collaborative effort to improve the coverage of numismatics and currencies on Wikipedia. If you would like to participate, please visit the project page, where you can join the discussion and see a list of open tasks.
BThis article has been rated as B-class on Wikipedia's content assessment scale.
HighThis article has been rated as High-importance on the project's importance scale.
WikiProject iconEconomics Start‑class Mid‑importance
WikiProject iconThis article is within the scope of WikiProject Economics, a collaborative effort to improve the coverage of Economics on Wikipedia. If you would like to participate, please visit the project page, where you can join the discussion and see a list of open tasks.
StartThis article has been rated as Start-class on Wikipedia's content assessment scale.
MidThis article has been rated as Mid-importance on the project's importance scale.

See also Talk:Fiat money whose article redirects to this article

Common Sense

Federal Reserve Notes (FRN's) represent US Obligations, not US wealth. Currency does not necessarily have to be based on a "Gold" or "Silver" standard. The evolution of paper and coin currency in America was born of convenience, as individuals would deposit wealth (gold, silver, etc) at a bank for safe keeping. Banks would offer "Warehouse Receipts" in the sum of the deposit. Individuals would trade the receipts rather than withdrawing their wealth, paying their dues, only to have the recipient of said wealth redeposit the wealth back into the bank. By definition currency is a substitute for wealth, and required to be backed by a commodity that is universal and liquid. Federal Reserve Notes are neither, rather they are IOU's to be redeemed against future production. Additionally the Federal Reserve System also keeps reserves of foreign currencies, bonds, and other such assests, none of which are commodities, and are difficult to liquidate. Most Foreign currencies, bonds, like Federal Reserve Notes are not backed by a commodity thus their value is questioned.

Franklin Roosevelt, along with the Federal Reserve Bank, stole wealth from US citizens by way of Presidential Executive Order 6102 which outlawed the ownership of gold by private citizens. Essentially this can be looked at as a form of slavery as FRN's are symbolic of debt, not wealth. The collateral on said debt is the future productivity of the nation, i.e. its citizens. Citizens thus are required to pay the interest of said debt in the form of taxes through labor. After World War I England and most of Europe moved away from the Gold Standard and instead kept reserves of foreign currencies, especially FRN's. This in part is symbolic of our National Debt.

Start again?

In general, the Wikipedia articles (gold standard, fiat currency, related ones) need to attribute beliefs to the relevant economic schools of thought. Many of the statements in the current articles appear to be statements of faith, not fact, and they don't, in general, acknowledge which school of thought they are from. This BIG problem kind of overwhelms a lot of the little problems.

This article is one of the most biased, propaganda-filled articles on Wikipedia, and should probably be completely re-written. It is full of arguments and rhetorical questions, rather than a simple statement of facts and information. One would hope that the article presents different viewpoints equally, instead of one viewpoint, the opposing viewpoint, and then why the opposing viewpoint is wrong. Information on this articleis controlled by people who feel strongly about one position on the subject, and they are the only ones who bother to write and edit the article. In short: this article is what's wrong with Wikipedia.

Yes, this article is FULL of propaganda. It's pretty disturbing... Someone needs to overhaul this... ask123 (talk) 19:51, 26 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

several problems here

Andrew Jacksons destruction of the "Bank of the United States", was not -at all- a declaration that government backed currency was illegal -you may have been deceived by the name of the bank, as many are. The "Bank of the United States" was actually a privately owned bank which, through fractional reserve banking, was sucking the lifeblood out of the economy -then and today through the falsely named "federal reserve bank" and banking in general (again via fractional reserve banking).

What most people fail to realize when contemplating banking is that banks aren't earning 5-10% interest based on their loans, they earn vastly more than this (in an expanding economy) because the fractional reserve system allows them to issue 10 times what they hold in reserves, functionally allowing them to 'earn' 50-100% on reserves. As most 'money' in the economy comes through bank loans and as repayment of interest is often far more than the principal, banks functional drain money from the economy UNLESS the economy is growing INFINITELY (and subsequently destructively consuming the FINITE resources of the planet). This means that with fractional reserve banking, FIAT money can never be functional unless the economy is self-destructive i.e. a pyramid/ponzi scheme.

Further, the US dollar, while not backed by metal gold, is backed via the saudi bourse, by black gold. This is the reason why the US economy can maintain such high trade deficits, as so many of the US trade partners must buy their oil with US dollars. i.e. if they revalued their currency against the US dollar, the price of oil would naturally go much higher and they'd have to pay far more while simultaneouly losing business as the deficits rebalanced.

If you have any questions for me about these points, email me:

tyler (at) earthsociety.org

You neglect to consider the liabilities of banks (ie deposits) which multiply under fractional reserve banking and return the bulk of the income to broader society. Banks manage credit not money. Every business has limited cash reserves.
Terjepetersen 20:54, 28 February 2006 (UTC)----[reply]

Your arguement needs more detail, I do not know what your point is. It seems as though you disagree with my statement above, but you do not lay out specifics. The liabilities of the bank is primarily the deposits, the deposits make up the bulk of the reserve. The bank pays interest on that reserve (and that reserve alone). The bank, however, loans out, around 10 times the reserve (fractional reserve banking) and earns interest on every bit of it. Hence, at 5-10% interest, they earn 50-100% interest, yet they only pay back interest -to their depositors an amount approximate to 5-10% again. This is why banks often have the largest buildings in town. Further, as the total sum of principle plus interest is more than the principle lent out initially, and as most of the money in an economy comes from bank loans, the economy can only exist if it grows at an ever accelerating pace (more loans going out than being paid in at any one time), as otherwise the banks would suck up every last dollar in the economy and the economy would collapse (this is soon to happen as growth is about to peak on this planet (finite resources). If you have a specific argument, please email me directly and we can discuss it.

tyler at earthsociety.org

The amount of wrong in your argument is incredible. First of all banks earn nothing on reserves, reserves are a percentage (I believe its around 10 or so percent) of demand deposits that banks must keep as cash in the Federal Reserve. Mean while they can lend out the rest of what they take in (the remaining 90 or so percent of demand deposits, and everything they take in as savings deposits and certificates of deposit). The bank doesn't magically make more money, basically savers lend money to the bank who then lends it to loan applicants. If the bank lends more then it has and accidentally dips into its reserves, then it must borrow money from other banks or the Federal Reserve, or face being closed down by the Fed during the Fed's nightly audit of the bank.
Fiat money does actually exist its what just about every major currency in the world is now a days, the thought that US currency is backed by Saudi oil is absurd, if you must think of it being backed by anything its backs by the US GDP and its Government. The US, and all countries that buy oil from Saudi Arabia, don't buy it in US dollars, its bought in Saudi Riyals, though it may appear to be bought in other currency other then that since the comparative values of every countries currency is well know and exchanging currency is an incredibly simple task.
And to answer your third point, that "i.e. if they revalued their currency against the US dollar, the price of oil would naturally go much higher and they'd have to pay far more while simultaneouly(sic) losing business as the deficits rebalanced." thats pretty wrong too, the reason why other countries don't revalue themselves against the dollar is simple, they have a lot of US dollars, and if they revalue those US dollars that they have in their vaults will be survey says... worth less then they were before. In cases like China who have a whole mess of US dollars, a revaluing would mean a big loss for them. There are other factors too, the US is the worlds largest importer, if a country revalues and says now our money is worth twice as much as the dollar, the dollar buys less, the US shops elsewhere.
roger3 (at) mtaonline (dot) net
Thank you to those who bring factual information to this discussion. This is not a banking conspiracy or an oil conspiracy. Believe it or not, there are smart people in this world who would realize the scheme. This article DESPERATELY needs balance. ask123 (talk) 19:57, 26 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Bad start

I have several problems with this article but let's just start with the first sentence:

Fiat currency or fiat money, is money that is current or legal tender as satisfaction for money debts simply and only by government fiat i.e. by arbitrary order or decree, by nothing more than law.
  1. To define currency in terms of the word "current" is reflexive and therefore not helpful.
  2. Not all forms of a fiat money are legal tender. Legal tender refers to the lawful (i.e. legal) forms of payment (the meaning of the word "tender") in a particular currency. What constitutes legal tender depends upon (a) the currency, (b) the jurisdiction, (c) what the payment is for, and (d) the amount of the payment. In some jurisdictions only certain coins of a currency are legal tender for that currency, in others only the bank notes, etc etc. Not more than a small number of coins can be used in some places, for some things. So the term "legal tender" is used incorrectly here.
  3. Again and again in WP we find the assertion that all debts can be satisfied by the payment of "legal tender". No. Legal tender is simply a form of a currency which MUST be accepted in discharge of a debt denominated in that same currency. If I owe pounds sterling I cannot legally tender (see where the term comes from?) US dollars. And vice versa.

OK. I'll stop there, for now. Paul Beardsell 04:15, 6 January 2006 (UTC)[reply]

I agree with all your points. Fiat Currency is merely currency that is created by a government and is accepted in a community as money proper. The reason for the acceptance may vary from coercion, prohibition of alternatives, superior stability or some other form of superior utility. Fiat Currency is characterised by the fact that it is not redeemable for anything (ie it is not a promisory note). As such it is one form of money proper (there are other forms such as commodity money) and it is not merely a credit substitute. Terjepetersen 10:15, 7 January 2006 (UTC)[reply]

What if, on the currency, it's stated THIS NOTE IS LEGAL TENDER AT MCHAPPY'S BURGER STAND, here is example of legal tender where no gov't is required, before it is considered legal to tender. Marvelous marvin (talk) 16:21, 1 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

@Marvin - If the government isn't involved than it isn't LEGAL tender. This would more or less be called... a coupon. The word legal is usually indicative of government or "law" involvement. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 206.253.186.23 (talk) 12:57, 12 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Bad example

I find this statement deceiving:

"One recent example was the Argentine bust which followed the unravelling of its “currency board”. Instead of being linked to gold, the peso was linked to the U.S. dollar, which served as the hard money basis. When an economic crisis hit, dollar reserves fled the country, causing the monetary basis to collapse."

How can "dollar reserves flee the country", I think what must have happened is that they were spent. This hardly seems like a problem with the monetary system, but rather simply a reflection of a collapsed economy. If you spend all the money, you've spent all the money! In effect, wouldn't this be a testament to the success of the system, the government was not able to pretend that they hadn't spent all by simply printing more money, ensuring that the money did not inflate?


___________________________________________


Answer to "How can dollar reserves flee the country?"

If a central bank (in this case, Argentina) stands to exchange 1 - 1 with the US dollar, they issue pesos and hold dollars in reserve (to "Back" their currency).

If someone with a lot of pesos doesn't believe that the central bank has enough dollars to back their currency, or believe that the peso is overvalued (which is the same thing) they can engaged in a speculative attack. Basically, they sell pesos to the central bank and receive dollars. This drains the reserves in the central bank and often causes a devaluation in the currency. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 74.232.140.88 (talk) 03:21, 14 February 2008 (UTC)[reply]

OK, this example is meaningless

"A further illustration of the irrelevance of physical convertibility can be seen by supposing that a bank issues two kinds of paper dollars: one redeemable for one ounce of silver throughout the year and another redeemable for the same amount of silver, but only at the end of a year. If the market interest rate is 5%, and if it is costless to issue paper dollars, then the inconvertible dollar must start the year worth about .95 ounces, rise to about .97 ounces at mid-year, and finish the year worth exactly 1 ounce. Any other values would result in arbitrage opportunities. For example, if the inconvertible dollar started the year worth .96 ounces, then each time the bank received .96 ounces of silver in exchange for a newly-issued dollar, it could lend the .96 ounces at 5% interest, be repaid 1.01 ounces at year-end, pay off the paper dollar with 1 ounce, and earn a free lunch of .01 ounces.

What is the value of the convertible dollar? A little reflection will convince the reader that it too must start the year at .95 ounces, reach .97 ounces at mid-year, and finish the year at exactly 1 ounce. That is, the issuing bank must actually raise the amount of silver it will pay for a dollar over the course of the year, or arbitrage opportunities will result. For example, suppose that at the start of the year, customers can deposit .95 ounces and get one paper dollar in exchange — a physically convertible dollar that can be returned to the bank for .95 ounces if the customer desires. If that dollar remained at .95 ounces over the whole year, then at the end of the year the bank will have received a free lunch of .05 ounces — a free lunch that will attract rival bankers willing to pay 5% interest to the holders of their dollars."


How can any logic be derived from this example without specifying how the notes are issued to start with? They don't just get issued, they get sold, but at what price? How much silver is paid for these two notes to start with? Obviously at the begining of the year, one would pay the bank a full ounce for the note that is convertible (back to 1 ounce), but only .95 ounces for the one that wasn't! This example is therefore bogus.


I agree, I am going to remove those two paragraphs as it is more confusing (and erroneous I believe) than it is informative over what I see is something quite simple. A physically convertible currency is affected by the interest rate of the specie or commodity that is backing it. And by the way, no one knows what the actual interest rate for anything will be for the year. That would be the same thing as predicting the future. Also, a 5% interest rate would not increase 0.95 to 1; it would increase to 0.9975. 5% interest would raise 1 to 1.05.--Acefox 00:10, 25 November 2006 (UTC)[reply]

Currency as a brand

I've wondered for a long time why people are willing to accept a currency that is not physcially convertible. And "financially convertible" sounds to me too much like "bootstrapping", which is worrysome to me as a mathematician.

So I rescently discovered some important fact of the media / ad industry, namely that adverts often promote something other than the owner of the relevant trademark. For example, shop owners will seldom put up a sign saying "Ice cold softdrinks available here". Instead they'd rather put up a "Coca-cola" sign, giving "Coca-cola" free media exposure.

Now many ads include prices e.g. "Coca-cola now only $1". Therefore currencies gets free media exposure almost everywhere you look. My guess is that this media exposure is of the order of a hunderd of billion of dollars every year (based on global adspend). This means that the dollar is the largest brand to ever exist. It also means the brand equity of the dollar rivals the value of the gold backing the dollar.

I'm sure someone figured all this out before me, but why does the article not mention any of this ? -- Nic Roets 13:49, 6 August 2006 (UTC)[reply]

To elborate : Paper carrying the signature of the central bank president trade at a premium to a blank piece of paper, just like an official FIFA soccer ball will command a premium over an unbranded soccer ball. -- Nic Roets 19:28, 10 August 2006 (UTC)[reply]

NPOV/ factual accuracy

I put the warning due to this:

The importance of financial convertibility can be seen by imagining that people in a community one day find themselves with more paper currency than they wish to hold — for example, when the Christmas shopping season has ended. If the dollar is physically convertible (for one ounce of silver, let us suppose), people will return the unwanted dollars to the bank in exchange for silver, but the bank could head off this demand for silver by selling some of its own bonds to the public in exchange for its own paper dollars. For example, if the community has $100 of unwanted paper money, and if people intend to redeem the unwanted $100 for silver at the bank, the bank could simply sell $100 worth of bonds or other assets in exchange for $100 of its own paper dollars. This will soak up the unwanted paper and head off peoples’ desire to redeem the $100 for silver.
Thus, by conducting this type of open market operation — selling bonds when there is excess currency and buying bonds when there is too little — the bank can maintain the value of the dollar at one ounce of silver without ever redeeming any paper dollars for silver. In fact, this is essentially what all modern central banks do, and the fact that their currencies might be physically inconvertible is made irrelevant by the maintenance of financial convertibility. Note that financial convertibility cannot be maintained unless the bank has sufficient assets to back the currency it has issued. Thus, it is an illusion that any physically inconvertible currency is necessarily also unbacked.

It doesn't make any sense and seems to assert as fact that whether or not there is a gold standard "doesn't really matter". In the example, what is going on? The customers deposited silver for a warehouse receipt entitling them to silver. Now, how does issuing bonds head off the run? The bank still has to pay those bonds with interest, despite doing nothing to increase its reserves. The passage would imply that I can start a storage facility for some asset, then pocket the asset for myself, and nobody would mind. If someone doesn't clarify what this passage is saying, I'm going to have to delete it. MrVoluntarist 16:26, 15 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]

Let me state right off that I have little familiarity with monetary theory, so feel free to ignore me. However the example seems fairly clear to me. The issuing of bonds in the example has nothing to do with heading off a run, but offering "financial convertability" as an alternative to "physical convertitibility". The bank pays the interest owed with the interest paid on loans (not in example). It works for money and not other assets because it is not the actual "thing" (gold, silver, etc) that is desired in the case of money, but its purchasing power. --T. Mazzei 02:21, 24 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]
I understand that the passage is explaining the relative importance of physical or financial convertibility, but it quite clearly does have to do with heading off a run. Like it says right here: "If the dollar is physically convertible (for one ounce of silver, let us suppose), people will return the unwanted dollars to the bank in exchange for silver, but the bank could head off this demand for silver by selling some of its own bonds to the public in exchange for its own paper dollars." Nor will the incoming loan money cover it, because the incoming loan money is already allocated to pre-existing obligations. The passage implies I can start e.g. a gold warehouse, issue receipts, steal the gold, and then keep issuing bonds to get new gold receipts to get people to go away. MrVoluntarist 03:21, 24 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]

I agree that it not neutral. Any suggestions on how to improve it? --Benn Newman 16:27, 21 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]

Well, as it stands, it seems to be both false, and POV, so I'd like to remove it in it's entirety. However, I have seen the same argument elsewhere, so I think it's trying to convey an important idea, so I'd prefer a rewrite to a removal. So, first I want to understand what the passage is trying to say so I can better clarify the idea it's presenting here. It sounds like a statement of the Real bills doctrine, except that, even accepting the validity of RBD, it's applying it incorrectly. That's why I first want to hear from someone who wrote or agreed with that passage. MrVoluntarist 20:50, 21 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]
The whole thing needs to be rewritten. Making it one-tenth as long wouldn't be a bad start. Demanding references on anything added after that would be even better. Smallbones 17:54, 29 October 2006 (UTC)[reply]


I wrote the section on physical vs. financial convertibility (sproulmike@yahoo.com). Everyone agrees about physical convertibility--one dollar can be redeemed for one ounce. Financial convertibility seems to be misunderstood. It only means that a bank stands ready to use its bonds to buy back the dollars it has issued. For example, if the Fed believes there is too much cash in the hands of the public (usually evidenced by a low federal funds rate), it will sell bonds, thus soaking up the excess dollars. The importance of financial convertibility is to correct the common misconception that if a currency is not physically convertible, it is unbacked. A currency can in fact be physically inconvertible but still backed by the bank's assets, and the more diligent the bank is in maintaining financial convertibility, the less physical convertibility matters.

This is, as you said, similar to the real bills doctrine. There is a further discussion in a UCLA working paper entitled "There's No Such Thing as Fiat Money". I forget the number, but that's why we have google.

Mike Sproul, you're the one I remembered from elsewhere claiming this. From what you've said, it sounds like original research. We'll need something better than a working paper to support this. At the very least, it needs to remove the references to bonds, which merely confuse the issue. I can see what it's saying about the money still being "backed", but that has nothing to do with the possibility of selling bonds.
Anyway, I still see a difference in btw, financial and physical convertibility. Let's say a bank takes 100 silver ounces and issues 100 notes entitling the user to an ounce of silver. You say that if the bank adds a house to its assets, worth 10,000 silver ounces (say), it can issue 10,000 more notes, without affecting the financial convertibility or value of the notes. That's wrong. If one day the real estate market crashed, and the house becomes worth only 5,000 silver ounces, there are notes outstanding that stake a claim to 10,100 ounces of silver, while the bank only has 5,100 silver ounces' worth of assets. Oops. Now how does the bank get out of this? MrVoluntarist 18:14, 16 November 2006 (UTC)[reply]


My suggestion

Okay, I'm going to take a stab at rewriting this section to say what I *think* was meant and without being POV or adding unnecessary suppositions. Here goes...


A distinction should be made between the differt kinds of convertibility:
Physical convertibility: A dollar can be redeemed at the issuing bank for a set amount of silver.
Financial convertibility: A dollar can be traded somewhere on the market (not necessarily the issuing bank) for assets equal in value to the dollar's quotal share of the issuing bank's assets.
In practice, if a bank maintains financial convertibility, no one will ever care about physical convertibility because they can already trade the dollar on the market for the same amount that a physical conversion would yield. It is possible to maintain financial convertibility without physical convertibility, which is seen in the following example: Assume a bank issues 100 dollars and maintains assets of 100 ounces of silver. Assume then that dollar holders find that merchants demand more than one dollar for an ounce of silver. In this case, the bank can sell its own silver at market prices until silver ounces trade for one dollar. The fact that the bank will not, on demand, redeem notes thus does not keep the notes from maintaining a value of one ounce of silver. In practice, this is how central banks maintain the value of their currencies, through such "open market operations".

Thoughts? MrVoluntarist 02:11, 8 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]


While banks can mantain the value of the currency with "open market operations" almost making physical convertability redundent. Requiring them to allow physcial convertability forces them not to endlessly inflate the money supply. Geoffsmith82 01:41, 15 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

What does that have to do with what I posted?

Financial convertibility means that a dollar is redeemable for a dollar's worth of stuff at the issuing bank--not that it is just acceptable in the market. If the bank didn't maintain financial convertibility then the money would lose value in the market. I don't think ths rewrite is an improvement. (Preceding unsigned comment by 67.49.42.239 aka Mike Sproul)

Okay, first of all, and I know I should have said this before, but "a dollar is redeemable for a dollar's worth of stuff" is tautological. A dollar will always be redeemable, anywhere, for a dollar's worth of assets, because that is what it means for an asset to be worth a dollar. And that is why I thought it meant the dollar's quotal share of assets. Second, the whole point of distinguishing financial convertibility (which you added) was that it does *not* need to be redeemable at the issuing bank on demand, in order to have value on the market. That's the whole point of the example. Make sense. MrVoluntarist 00:10, 10 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

If a dollar is issued by a bank in exchange for a bond worth a dollar, then if that dollar is no longer wanted by the public, that dollar can be returned to the bank in exchange for a bond worth one dollar. That dollar is financially convertible. If the dollar cannot be returned to the bank for a bond worth one dollar, then the dollar is financially inconvertible. Obviously a dollar will buy a dollar's worth of stuff on the market, but that is not what financial convertibility means. For example, if the bank wants to maintain the value of a dollar at one ounce of silver, then if it sees the value of the dollar starting to fall, it can sell a dollar's worth of bonds for paper dollars, thus soaking up the unwanted dollar and keeping the dollar equal to one ounce. Thus, by conducting ordinary open market operations, the issuing bank can make physical convertibility unnecessary. (Preceding unsigned comment by 67.49.42.239 aka Mike Sproul)

Do you see, though, how my complaint about the tautology affects this? The bank could publicly destroy all of its assets. Then the dollars (we assume) are worthless. And surprise surprise, a dollar will get you nothing at the bank -- a dollar's worth of assets. Is this what you mean by "maintaining financial convertibility"? Basically, having a recursive definition confuses the issue.MrVoluntarist 02:48, 15 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

It is tautological to say "a dollar is worth a dollar", but not to say "a dollar is worth an ounce of silver". Saying that the bank uses financial convertibility to maintain the dollar at one ounce is equivalent to saying that the bank uses open market operations to maintain the dollar at one ounce. In conducting those open market operations, the bank is continually exchanging paper dollars for a dollar's worth of bonds, but that does not mean the value of the dollar is indeterminate; it remains at one ounce. If, as you say, the bank threw away its assets, then of course the dollar would lose its value. A dollar would be worth zero ounces, though a dollar would also still be worth a dollar. (This seems to be what GeoffSmith was getting at above.) BTW: Are you adding my name to these posts on purpose? It's no big deal, but if I were worried about my privacy it might be. I assume you go by "MrVoluntarist" because you also don't want your name displayed.

Okay, I think you and I are saying the same thing, but you're unnecessarily adding a lot of suppositions. The point of the example, I thought, was to show that the bank could maintain the value of its currency even if it fully suspends convertibility, and merely buys and sells at its pleasure. I agreed with you that when the bank conducts open market operations, it is buying/selling its dollars at whatever it can get, i.e., the market price. But since you agree with me that it's preferable to refer to "a dollar is worth an ounce of silver" as opposed to "a dollar is worth a dollar", I don't understand why you keep wanting to refer to "a dollar's worth of assets" in the definition. If there are 100 notes and 100 ounces, and it's possible for the bank to maintain a market price of 1 note per ounce, the probper way to describe that would be to say that "the note can be traded for assets equal in value to the dollar's quotal share of the bank's assets. (i.e., if there are a hundred dollars, each dollar's quotal share is one hundredth) And that's why I already have in my rewrite. Further, I don't like how you suppose that the assets are bonds. Since the bonds themselves are claims on future dollars, that adds another recursive step that makes it harder for the reader to understand what's going on. So that's why I replaced bonds with silver in the example, referred to financial convertibility as a market (rather than bank) condition, and referred to a dollar's "quotal share" of asset value, instead of being, tautologically, "worth a dollar". Now, what part do you object to? It seems you're in agreement.
As for the name issue, you identified your email address above, which suggested you were "Mike Sproul", so I though you were confortable being so named. I recommend registering. Even if you don't, it would help the flow of discussion if you would sign with your IP address, using four tildes (~~~~). Thanks. MrVoluntarist 21:53, 15 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

Real banks back their dollars with "a dollars' worth" of assets, so in the interest of realism I listed the assets partly as silver and partly as dollar-denominated bonds. The trick about dollar-denominated assets is that they present the possibility of inflationary feedback: Let's say the bank is robbed of some of its silver, and the dollars fall in value as a result. But now the dollar-denominated bonds fall too, which leads to a further fall in the value of the dollar, etc. This can be described algebraically as follows: Let E=the exchange value of the dollar (oz./$), and suppose the bank has issued 300 paper dollars, worth E oz. each, and backs those dollars with 100 oz of silver, plus bonds worth $200. Since assets must equal liabilities, we get 100+200E=300E, which yields E=1 oz./$. But if, as above, the bank is robbed of 50 oz., this becomes 50+200E=300E, or E=.5 oz./$. Note that if the bank had held 300 oz as its assets, the same loss would have yielded E=250/300.

As for bonds being denominated in future dollars, it is a simple matter to suppose that the bank holds bonds that promise $220 in 1 year. At 10% interest the bonds are worth $200 today. I know some people worry about what happens if there aren't enough dollars to pay the interest in dollars, but any rational lender would accept his interest payment in silver or something else.(Preceding unsigned comment by 67.49.42.239 aka Mike Sproul)

I see your point, but I still think it's confusing to list bonds as assets in the initial example like that for the reasons above related to recursion. If it's important to mention how claims on future dollars can themselves provide real backing for dollars, I recommend adding to the example I gave rather than changing it. Once the reader understands how the silver is backing the dollars, then go on and introduce how claims on future dollars can count as assets. It's just a matter of avoiding confusion on a notoriously confusing issue. Also, do you have any objection to my explanation of the dollar's values as being equal to a quotal share of the bank's assets; or to saying that financial convertibility doesn't require the bank to redeem on demand? MrVoluntarist 18:53, 17 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

Looking back at the article, it does not directly mention the "dollars' worth" problem. I'm open to suggestions, but my first reaction is that this would just take the discussion too far afield. Since, as you say, this is a notoriously confusing issue, maybe some discussion is warranted, but that's why wikipedia has this discussion page. As for the quotal share point: First, the phrase is so rarely used as to be nearly Greek to the average reader. Second, it glosses over the inflationary feedback problem. I'm fine with saying that financial convertibility doesn't require the bank to redeem (for silver) on demand. It is, however, wrong to say that financial convertibility means that a dollar can be redeemed somewhere other than the issuing bank. The defining characteristic of a financially convertible currency is that it can be redeemed for a dollar's worth of assets AT the issuing bank. Put another way: it is the issuing bank that conducts open-market operations, not the general public.

In the order of your responses: The article does mention the "dollars' worth" problem -- it's in the very definition of "financial convertibility" currently given that led to my complaint to begin with! Second, I don't think "quotal share" is confusing, as it can be inferred from content. Even if not, that would mean using a different term like "dollar's proportional share", or define "quotal share" in a footnote. I don't see how it glosses over the inflationary feedback problem -- the dollar's quotal share is exactly what your formula says the dollar's value will be. On the issue of redemption, I think it's apparent now there is a problem with the two definitions: in the first one (physical), "can be redeemed" means "can be redeemed on demand" (I know, I know, with the obvious caveats about bank hours, size of redemptions, and time waiting in line). In the second one (financial), "can be redeemed" means "the bank can buy its dollars back at its pleasure". And note that I didn't say the dollar can be redeemed on the market; I said the dollar can be traded on the market. There's a reason I used those words: because I was claiming that financial convertibility simply means that the prevailing market price is such that the dollar buys on the market, something of the same value as its quotal share of the bank's assets. But then, now you've confused me: are you saying that under your definition of financial convertibility, the bank redeems notes on demand in some form of assets? Because that would mean US dollars are not financially convertible, because the Fed picks and chooses who may sell dollars to it. Furthermore, it would make no sense to talk about a bank "maintaining financial convertibility" after refusing to redeem anything. MrVoluntarist 02:36, 20 December 2006 (UTC)[reply]

As long as quotal share means what the formula says, I don't have a problem with it. Normally financial convertibility is exercised at the bank's option. The bank sees the value of the dollar dropping and so it sells bonds. But two things occur to me: 1) In principle, physical convertibility could also be at the bank's option, and (2) If people borrowed money from the bank, and they chose when to pay it back, then financial convertibility is at the customer's option. You're correct that if a bank refuses financial convertibility, then the value of the dollar would drop--to the discounted present value of the expected eventual payoff--which might be zero.

wikipedia is full of comunists

Quotal share means nothing, and is easily the most confusing pair of words on this page. 'Quotal' does not appear in dictionaries, and is apparently some kind of neologistic wiki-jargon. The phrase 'open market operations', on the other hand, has a well known meaning, with respect to central (currency-issuing) banks. Open market bond sales are the mechanism by which the Fed maintains its target interest rates, by draining the financial system of excess reserves which would otherwise be lent out at lower rates. Go read a book, and stop drinking the free market koolaid. —The preceding unsigned comment was added by 24.22.108.122 (talk) 08:39:38, August 19, 2007 (UTC)

I think this article is misusing a term "dollar" in a large scale. For example: "A unit of paper or credit money (a “dollar”)" in convertibility section. 'Dollar' is NOT a unit of money, dollar is a NAME of US (and few other countries') currency unit. Article like this should use more general terms. Daddy32 —Preceding comment was added at 12:51, 21 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

I agree with Daddy32 that when the price of something is stated, use the ratio of goods it's denominating. Also, in terms of issuing bonds to 'back' the currency - the only reason a bank would do this is because its reserve ratio is less than 100% and it uses its goodwill with customers to make up the difference. If the example is under 100% reserve, the person returning the fiat notes would just be selling his silver in return for a bond. If the bank issued notes at 1 note=1 oz silver, and issued 100, the person who didn't want 1 note would give it back, and that 1 oz silver would go back to him. Then, he could buy a bond at whatever rate for 1 oz of silver, and the bank would have to find a way to make a return higher than the yield. Under a 100% reserve system these two operations would be completely separate, which the reserve ratio could be determined by an audit. If the bank does not have physical possession of what is backing the notes, then the bank has counterfitted. The bond operation would have to back its products with something other than the reserve of the bank, because all that money is spoken for. 143.115.159.54 (talk) 17:20, 3 March 2008 (UTC)D-Unit[reply]

Synthesis tag on Credit money section

The article as a whole, and this section in particular, is massively short of citation and attribution. This section reads like a debate between opposing contributors and is a synthesis of their views. (The SYN tag usually applies to an editor drawing his own inferences from cited material. Since no citations have been provided, one could argue that it is not the best tag, but it is better than NPOV). Frankly I'm astonished that this article was awarded GA. --John Maynard Friedman 16:55, 15 August 2007 (UTC)[reply]

The worse problem is not lack of citations, but the fact that this section is mostly irrelevent to the article. We need a discussion of the difference between fiat money and credit money (which is given in the previous section). Basically credit money is the type issued by banks (as banknotes), and fiat money is where a governent backs the notes of a bunch of national central banks, insures their debt with the additional power of the government to collect taxes from the population by force, and declares it will accept these notes as payments of debts to the government, and all its citizens are required to do this also.

However, the next section which follows is a bunch of Marxist and anti-Marxist rants about whether or not this extra layer of government guarantee is a good thing or not (Marxists, who love government, apparently think it is). But whether these things are "good" or not, or even most of the debate about whether they are "good" is outside the scope of this article. Summarize shortly and put it in the article on Marxist economic theory, or something. We don't need the whole debate. The types of money are what they are, and nothing but a pointer needs to go to other article(s) debating on the utility or "trueness" or helpfulness or goodness of each of them.

[And by the way, if credit money is a giant hoax perpetrated by capitalists, then show me the Marxist or Communist State which isn't glad to get credit from the rest of the world. If they can't get it, and their fiat money is worthless (see Cuba) it's only because they have tended to be theives about investment from other countries, and now nobody trusts them. That's what happens with credit: if you're not credible, nobody trusts you.] SBHarris 22:36, 29 October 2007 (UTC)[reply]

While I agree with most of your analysis, I'm surprised that you find reds under the bed. It has been my impression that the leading oponents are those who want to restore the gold standard (and who are mainly US citizens). --John Maynard Friedman 13:21, 30 October 2007 (UTC)[reply]
Not at all. Read the first paragraph of this section: Both Marxian economists and Green economists view the evolution from fiat-centric to credit-centric regimes as fundamental to global capitalism, as direct imperialism and colonialism is replaced by more local intermediaries, and relations between rich and poor are defined more by debt. Neither this nor most of the rest of the section is written by anybody who is interested in the gold standard. This section is rather an argument about the relative goodness of fiat money vs. credit money (i.e., the last being a sort of representative money backed by private promise of repayment in goods and services, rather than government promise of the same). The idea being argued (advanced and refuted) is that this nasty "new" credit money is part of the global capitalist plot. How dare individuals or businesses dare to issue their own promisory notes! Unmentioned is that this was the way it was always done, before central banking. Fiat money is the later development, so credit money can hardly be said to be part of the some modern Marx-prophesied movement of the world toward global capitalism, in latter days. Credit money is old-style, not new-style, whatever you think of it. SBHarris 01:52, 6 November 2007 (UTC)[reply]

Liberty Dollar Section

Why is there a few lines devoted to the Liberty Dollar, with obvious bias no less. Why has it stood for so long? If a contributor really cares about the Liberty Dollar they should make a new article and include a link to that article. I am removing those lines for the moment. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 209.240.89.251 (talk) 02:38, 3 November 2007 (UTC)[reply]

Use of language

1) Try sticking to common language usage when explaining something. "Quotal", if it is a word, is very rare. If you must use it, define it or link it.

2) Talking about '1 dollar = 1 oz silver' can be confusing in a theoretical example, because silver really has been used as a commodity. Try dumbing down the GDP/productivity guarantee to something like '50 cows and 500 sheep', so each of the 100 dollars is 'worth' 0.5 cow + 5 sheep (BTW, this neatly leads to a discussion of specie exchange rates, where 1 cow = 10 sheep) -- 72.1.212.20 21:41, 21 September 2007 (UTC)[reply]

Wording of Critiques of credit money expansion

Wouldn't this read better if written in the form of "An argument is/can be" instead of "They argue"? The way it is written now it reads as though the arguments are false. 85.165.222.180 (talk) 19:50, 19 November 2007 (UTC)[reply]

No, it reads as though it is their position. Wikipedia cannot be the arbiter of what is true and what is false: it can only record what specific people have said and produce the objective evidence (if any - if none, say so) for that opinion. Readers must decide for themselves or consult an opinionated text. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 13:51, 20 November 2007 (UTC)[reply]
This whole section is going to be deleted in January anyway, if none of the citations and attributions can be produced. At the moment it reads like a poor undergraduate debate. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 13:59, 20 November 2007 (UTC)[reply]
It's January and no citations have been provided. Off with its head. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 14:02, 3 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Expert attention

This is an important article and, as remarked above, does not do justice to the subject. The entire article needs a thorough review by an expert. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 14:04, 7 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Chopped this out

I chopped the following text out of the article, it seems to be more appropriate in a general history of currency, rather than this article which focuses on fiat currency:


Historically, the names of the individual coins and the names of the unit of account were identical, e.g. a shilling was both a type of coin and a unit of account. The law would therefore recognize tender of those coins as legal satisfaction for debts denominated in that unit of account. Different-mass coins of the same metal could explicitly be recognized as being legally valued at fixed multiples of each other in their names (e.g. in the case of the crown and half-crown) or simply by reference to their legal masses (e.g. the legal mass of a florin is twice that of a shilling). A government could legislate for the minting of a system of metallic currency, including the fineness of the metal and the legal and original masses of the coins, without legislating for legal tender or legal values of the coins themselves — they can be discovered or implied by the ratios of legal masses of fine metal in each species of coin.

Coins of different metals naturally resist incorporation into a common unit of account, and therefore of a common legal tender value system. Governments have historically attempted to fix the legal values of different metallic coins to create a unified unit of account and standard of legal tender for payments large and small. Two mechanisms have been used in this connection: multi-metalism and token coinage. The former took the form of bimetallism, where both gold and silver coins were given legal values in terms of each other. e.g. gold coin was legally valued by nominal mass at 15 times silver coin. As market forces changed the actual value of gold in relation to silver, one coin would become overvalued in reference to the other. For example, suppose there were two coins, a shilling being 6 grams of fine silver, and a sovereign being 8 grams of fine gold. If the unit of account were the shilling, then the legal value of a sovereign would be 20 shillings, and a debtor could discharge a debt of 100 shillings with five sovereign coins or 100 shilling coins, at his option. Debtors will nearly always choose the cheapest way to discharge their debts, and this results in the constant threat of demonetization of a legally over-valued metal. Token coinage adopts the coins of the higher value metal as the monetary standard, and limits the lower value metal coins to fractional currency. This is done by deliberately over-valuing the legal tender value of the lower value metal coins and limiting the total amount for which they can be legal tender in any one payment. For example in 1816 the English silver currency was lightened by 6% and the limit of the legal tender of 40 shillings per payment was imposed. Such token currency is clearly fiat currency, as it is only by government fiat that the coin can be received at its legal value.

Over time multi-metallism was replaced by gold mono-metalism, via composite standards where gold coin was unlimited legal tender and silver and copper coins were lightened, limited and converted into tokens.

Bank notes as legal tender by government fiat originate from the advent of central banking. Central banks are banks of issue that are owned, sponsored or favoured by the government. Bank notes are negotiable instruments, being promissory notes issued by a bank and payable to bearer on demand. Central banks are generally favoured with monopoly rights to issue bank notes, and/or for these notes to have the status of legal tender. Alternatively, currency notes can be issued directly by the government or its non-bank agencies, and/or the government can favour selected commercial banks by making their notes legal tender (as in Hong Kong). It is important to note that paper money and fiat currency are not the same. For example, Scottish commercial banknotes act as money, but are not legal tender and therefore not fiat currency.


Aatombomb (talk) 19:27, 7 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Removed from Lead

The whole lead seems overloaded and much of this is addressed elsewhere in the article.

Without government demand for certain kinds of paper as legal tender, such as bank notes, only specie is unlimited legal tender. However this is not universally true, as some currencies, (notably sterling issued by Scottish banks[1]), are not legal tender but are accepted by longstanding confidence (Scotland technically has no note of legal tender and thus no fiat money-- see Pound Scots).

A bank of issue whose notes enjoy legal tender status by government fiat can use its own notes, making their redemption in specie optional — a matter of the 'monetary policy' of the bank in question. Historically, the institution of fiat currency has preceded and enabled the demonetisation of specie, via a monetary policy decision not to offer payment in specie at par, e.g. by suspension, devaluation or redemption in bullion or foreign currency instead. Eventually this leads to no form of payment, redemption or exchange whatsoever being offered by the issuer and a system of freely floating national currencies, none of which is "redeemable" by fixed amounts of specie or any given commodity.

Aatombomb (talk) 20:11, 7 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

The suggested length for the LEAD of a reasonably long article, is 3 to 4 paragraphs, and for one of medium size as this one is, perhaps 2 paragraphs (15 kB). See WP:LEAD. You've now cut it to two sentences--too much. I'm not arguing about the direction you're going, but am simply adding that those who cut beyond the recommended amount, are under an obligation to restore those sections with fresh summary material of the rest of the article's content, in accord with policy and the manual of style. Deletion is easy; writing is hard. So please attend to both tasks if you edit, not just the one. Thanks. SBHarris 02:36, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
I intend to, after the article itself takes better shape. If you would feel more comfortable putting it back in for now, please go ahead. Aatombomb (talk) 04:07, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
I shall wait till you're satisfied with your rewrite. Glad you intend to finish the job! SBHarris 04:38, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
Thanks! I'm trying to do some research on it over the next week or so. Aatombomb (talk) 16:52, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Emperor Norton

I'd like to add Josua A. Norton in here somewhere. He is a notable case of an individual who issued fiat money that was apparently actually accepted as currency by some residents of San Francisco.

Aatombomb (talk) 17:10, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

I'd say not to. While an interesting curiosity, there are so many cases of fiat currency, they should not all be included in this article.--Gregalton (talk) 17:14, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
On further scrutiny, it's an example of representative currency - so never mind. Aatombomb (talk) 17:24, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
If you're talking about the artist, the notes he makes are not even representative money, but commodity money. The value is in the money-object itself, rather like Picasso making a minimalist sketch on his napkins and signing them, to pay for a meal (which he was known to do).

Some of the careful distinctions between these kinds of money (and examples of them) have been removed from this article. Er, not to be impolite, but in some cases, by YOU. SBHarris 17:41, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

I wasn't talking about the artist. I didn't find the distinctions too careful, myself. I don't own the article, so please add back in anything you think I shouldn't have taken out, especially if you have more expertise on this subject. Aatombomb (talk) 17:46, 11 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
Oh, you mean Joshua A. Norton. Arguably a performance artist, if you get my drift. And the bills are (and even were) taken as being worth something for their own sake (as works), not in representation of specie or anything ELSE valuable. But not actual fiat money because Norton lacked any governmental authority. Yes, I know "authority" is a tricky concept. Usually it's connected with divisions and weapons, though, and Norton didn't have any. SBHarris 04:53, 12 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
Coupons have "value" inasmuch as they are acknowledged and honoured. Norton's "currency" is no different than old trading stamps or Canadian Tire money Coloneldoctor (talk) 02:10, 22 June 2008 (UTC)ColonelDoctor[reply]

Expert wanted

Wikipedia is designed to reject and expel experts in favor of the nonsense promulgated by the administrators and bureaucrats. I'm not helping the inmates run the asylum they've built for themselves out of compressed particle board and barbed wire. —Preceding unsigned comment added by 67.101.123.88 (talk) 17:03, 23 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]

In some articles that is unfortunately true (and in my experience it is caused by obsessive editors, not admins) but many editors are trying to fix it - witness this article. But even experts have to cite their sources: some self-styled experts consider themselves above such petifogging details. If you provide the citations, nobody can repel or expel you. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 13:22, 24 January 2008 (UTC)[reply]
The problem is that flat currency is such a controversial concept, especially politically charged since many Americans still believe the gold reserves at Fort Knox underwrite the American dollar. The problem with experts in the field of economics is, they are as divided in opinion (depending on political affiliation) as any other group of arguing reprobates, arrogantly insisting their way is correct. What the Wikipedia needs is referee-ism to allow multiple schools of thought to be heard in the same article, even though that means it will sound like a CNN screamfest. Which, incidently, is how democracy is often characterised when it is functioning correctly.Coloneldoctor (talk) 02:15, 22 June 2008 (UTC)ColonelDoctor[reply]

My understanding is that the "fiat" requires a law, aka government mandate

The article now says that fiat money can be issued on authority of a bank, without the government having an opinion. I don't think that's right. The last is "credit money", an important concept in itself. Fiat money is a SUBSET of credit money, in which the government has become creditor(lender)-of-last-resort. In otherwords, it's the government's credit, not the bank's alone. These things should be carefully spelled out here. Fiat currency appeared in the US only during the American Civil War, in the form of greenbacks, backed by US bonds. Before that, in the period between failures of the US bank (back to Jackson) all paper currency was banknotes from state or private banks and was credit money only. SBHarris 21:13, 29 February 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Error in lead section

The lead section says:

There has never been a form of money that has retained its value as fiat money once the backing government's tax enforcement powers have waned

Easily disproven by the counter-example of the Swiss dinar:

During this period the Swiss dinar was endorsed by no central authority or government (in fact it was a disendorsed currency) and was not redeemable by any issuing agent, or backed by any commodity. Its persistent and sustained market value derived purely from its utility as a culturally accepted medium of exchange. As such it is often cited in economic discussions about money and the origin of money's value.

Do you agree with me that this is wrong, and that we need to change the lead section? — Ksero (talk | contribs) 19:58, 17 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Is this an isolated exception that doesn't disprove the general rule? If so, then it is just a foot note that begins "Well hardly ever:". If not, it should certainly be changed. Either way, a bold statement like "There has never been" certainly reads as WP:OR without a citation. So at the very least, it needs a {{fact}} tag. --John Maynard Friedman (talk) 13:10, 18 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]
I've added a paragraph to the lead using this excellent example. The old dinar in Iraq contined to function as a perfectly good credit money, even after the government withdrew support as creditor of last resort. With a government losing power, and in fact behaving irresponsibly money-wise, an old credit money can retain buying power better than a (new) inflating fiat money. The only thing that matters, is whose credit is good. Here's a good example which can be used to show the difference. The Pound Scots is also a good example of credit money which has strong enough backing that no "fiat" is necessary. SBHarris 21:31, 26 March 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Controversy, Flags, & The State of This Entry

I think that this has become a rather controversial topic(at least in the United States, with the elections and whatnot; esp. Ron Paul & Stances) and i just wanted to hark on the fact that the primary portion, the "bulk", of this article seems to have remained unchanged since before most, if not all of the article flags (NPOV, Expert needed, etc.) were posted. I think this is controversial(as i said) (&part of the reason this probably became flagged) and that although most of the data is unverified and isn't exactly NPOV, it IS good data and shouldn't be tossed aside carelessly. Heavily re-worded, and cited, but not thrown out. 137.49.222.44 (talk) 20:05, 7 May 2008 (UTC)[reply]

It can't become controversial, this issue is controversial. We should welcome the controversy, however, and work to clarify it so the truth of how flat currency affects global economies becomes better understood. Maybe people would stop blaming the Jews. —Preceding unsigned comment added by Coloneldoctor (talkcontribs) 02:27, 22 June 2008 (UTC)[reply]
This isn't actually controversial at all, really. Most Americans have no idea what "fiat currency" means and it isn't a part of the mainstream political debate, while economists really agree on it, by and large. Titanium Dragon (talk) 05:31, 22 June 2008 (UTC)[reply]

Currency Competition

Just as a heads up to those who edit this article regularly. I have created a separate page on currency competition, a topic that is extremely under-represented in essentially every avenue of cultural signficance. Anyone who wants to help bring this article up (and eventually to featured status) is welcome to do so. JHMM13(Disc) 20:17, 11 May 2008 (UTC)[reply]