Jump to content

User:WillZ8800/sandbox

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia

This is an old revision of this page, as edited by WillZ8800 (talk | contribs) at 07:43, 6 May 2020 (major changes). The present address (URL) is a permanent link to this revision, which may differ significantly from the current revision.

Monetary reform of the Soviet Union 1922-24
New Economic Policy Propaganda
LocationSoviet Union
TypeEconomic program
CauseRussian Revolution Russian Civil War World War One
Organized byPremier Vladimir Lenin
OutcomeReturn to the gold pegged monetary system; end of hyperinflation in Soviet Union; stabilization of the Soviet economy

The monetary reform of the Soviet Union 1922-1924 was a set of monetary policies implemented in the Soviet Union as a part of the Soviet government’s New Economic Policy. Principal objectives of this reform included the easing the effects of hyperinflation, establishing a unified medium of exchange and the creation of a more independent central bank. [1]The results of the reform were overall mixed; some modern-day economists label the new policies as a successful transition towards state capitalism, while others describe it was problematic from the very start. [2]Economists including Keynes often categorise the reform as an aggregation of short-term monetary expansion experiments which fundamentally defined the intertemporal nature between Soviet monetary and fiscal policies where the state peruses a more active role in dictating the growth of the economy.[3]


Introduction of Monetary Reforms (July 1922)[edit source]

A 50000 Russian Sovznak issued in 1921

Having to endure a budget deficit since the start of World War I (1914), by the end of the Russian Civil War (1918-1921), the Russian economy was in a state of excessive recession. Both the wartime economic policy of War Communism and the communist ideology drift in questioning the long-term necessity of a monetary system triggered a massive increase in the issuance of money which prolonged the continuous rise in the domestic inflation rate. [4] In 1921 the national monthly inflation rate averaged around 50% and the quantity of currency circulation within the Soviet economy increased by 164.20 times.  According to Soviet achieves, 10,000 Soviet sovznaks in 1921 was only worth the equivalent of 0.59 Russian imperial chervonets of 1914. [4]

The initial reforms began in July 1922 after the Soviet Central bank, Gosbank, was granted by the Soviet State Planning Committee, Gosplan, with a certain degree of autonomy. Not only was the central bank given the monopoly to issue national banknotes, it also had the power to restrict the government’s access to capital. A more independent central bank also became a natural economic oversight mechanism used in fighting inflation and geared the Soviet economy with the flexibility to counter both domestic and global economic fluctuations. [5]Direct outcomes from this policy monetary power distribution were the Soviet economy’s return to the gold standard, introduction of a separate national currency, elimination of the government’s budget deficit and the restoration of a centrally administered legal tax system. By the end of 1922, a dual currency system was in place where gold pegged Russian chervonets were brought back as a unit of account while Soviet printed money, sovznaks, were commissioned as the nationalised medium of exchange and means of payment for the domestic market.[4]

Monetary reform and the Introduction a Dual Currency System (1922~1923)[edit source]

A 5 chervonet note issued in 1923

By June 1923, the first round of policies surrounding the creation of a more independent central bank have lowered the Soviet government’s fiscal expenditure against the nation’s currency circulation from the 1920s 85% to 1923’s 26.6%. As the nationalised market traded with gold-backed chervonets, the privatised markets operated under the more liquid, government monitored sovznaks. [6]As chervonets and sovznaks were convertible and foreign trade institutions only accepted chervonets as the means of payment, the dual currency system became a transaction channel connecting the sovznak orientated Soviet economy with the gold pegged international monetary system. With the dual currency system functioning as a direct monetary transaction channel the Soviet economy reopened to both international exports and imports resulting into both a steady growth in trade surplus and the rapid stabilisation of domestic commodity prices. Liberal Keynesians, including Keynes himself, praised the Soviet monetary reform as “pioneering the foundation of a more progressive monetary system” that effectively incorporates the power of state led fiscal policies without harming the fundamental flexibility required for a functioning market economy.” [1]In contrast, majority of western economists at that time maintained the position in which any degree of state intervention would make it impossible to maintain long-term growth and the Soviet planned economy was simply not functionable.

Stabilisation was the central theme behind the monetary reform policies of 1923. The common pursuit to accomplish this goal of stabilisation gave rise to a series of monetary experiments which to a great extent contradicted the collective ownership structure that was embodied as a core principle of the Soviet planned economy. Separate government agencies proposed a collection of monetary policies for the central government to select upon. Gosbank, the newly established Soviet central bank, proposed to issue banknotes based on short-term obligations which were backed by gold while Gosplan, the Soviet central planning committee argued for the elimination of the gold standard and encouraged a full transition into a commodity oriented monetary system.[7] More liberal government agencies such as the Ministry for Trade advocated for policies including the acceptance of loans from foreign banking institutions and temporarily integrate into monetary systems controlled by foreign central banks. The result was an aggregation of proposed policies where foreign long-term and short-term loans backed by a variety of mineral commodities were accepted but the government controlled dual currency system remained in place as to protect Soviet monetary sovereignty.[7]

In 1923, the Soviet dual currency monetary system, was structured with 25% of chervonets backed by a collection of precious metals alongside a reserve of stable foreign currencies pegged to the gold standard. [4]The remaining 75% of chervonets were backed by short-term commodity loans given by foreign banks. On the other side of the spectrum, 100% of all sovznaks derived their value from chervonets and were governed by Gosbank. In theory, under an official exchange rate, chervonets and sovznaks were convertible, yet no clear channel was established until 1924, and thus most economic activities conducted within the Soviet domestic market were conducted in sovznaks[4].

Under the dual currency system, Soviet trade surplus gradually rose to the point where short-term foreign loans were largely paid off and the national current account became positive by the end of 1923.[4] Backed by gold, chervonets naturally held a higher monetary value than government priced sovznaks and were also internationally recognised, this disorientation in value between the two currencies proved to be a growing problem for the domestic economy. Since the government determines the value of sovznaks against the central bank’s supply of chervonets, the dual currency form a dependent relationship which causes a monetary disorientation considering the market naturally prefers the more valuable legal tender. As the primary purpose of sovznaks was to function as a back-up currency under the scenario where the value of chervonets was indirectly controlled by the foreign loans which initially backed 75% of chervonets’ value, the repayment of these loans by the end of 1923 meant this contingency plan was no longer essential. [5]Thus during the 12th Soviet Congress (1923) the conceptual pursuit for a “peaceful coexistence” between the two currencies was removed, and a gradually monetary shift towards a single currency system began. Soviet literature started labelling chervonets as the “stable currency,” whereas the sovznak was prescribed as “a declining currency.” [3]On the 7th of July 1924, the Soviet Central Executive Committee decided to limit the issue of sovznaks and initiate a controlled elimination of the dual currency system.

The return of a single currency monetary system (1923~1924)[edit source]

With the government’s favour leaning towards chervonets yet the Soviet economy largely functioned around sovznaks, the effects of price scissors became more prevalent in the winter of 1923. [6]High industrial prices and low agricultural prices led to an excessive transfer of resources across the sovznak orientated country side into the chervonet dominated state urban industrialised centres. This price imbalance accelerated the depreciation of sovznaks, and by October 1923, sovznaks, once again began experiencing extreme daily inflation rates up to 4.4%.[6]

Although the sovznak orientated Soviet population found it harder to conduct daily transactions, the chervonets dominated government expenditure experienced no shortage of funds and the national balance sheet continued to remain cash flow positive. State enterprises either have endured minimised losses or in some instances been able to gain a profit. By the end of 1923’s fiscal year, a surplus in the Soviet Union’s current account signified the successful transition into an export-driven economy.[4]

On the 14th of February 1924, the issue of sovznaks came to a complete halt. Under an exchange rate of 1 gold rouble to 50,000 1923 sovznaks and one gold rouble to 50 billion 1922 sovznaks, the entire circulation of sovznaks within the Soviet economy was bought outright in between 7th of March 1924 to 10th of May 1924. With the formal end to the dual currency system, the Soviet monetary reform of 1922~1924 was complete. As a result, the nation’s currency circulation was optimised and the Soviet chervonet, later defined as the rouble, was once again pegged to gold, the universal storage of value before the adoption of the Bretton-Woods system.[6]


Influence of the Reform[edit source]

The Soviet Monetary Reform of 1922~1924 was one of the first economic initiatives implemented across the Soviet Union. Liberal economists often describe this reform as the first successful establishment of state capitalism. In contrast, Austrian school economists refer to the reform as Russia’s “jagged return” to a market-orientated economy. [2]As the first communist-led economic reform, the Soviet monetary reform of 1922~1924 demonstrated an ideological shift where the proposal to eliminate money was at first replaced with a dual currency system, and later a stable gold pegged monetary regime. Pioneering along with other components of the New Economic Policy, the Soviet monetary model became a widely adopted exemplar for the late 20th-century economic reforms in nations like China and Vietnam. [4]

  1. ^ a b Birman, Igor; Clarke, Roger A. (1985-10). "Inflation an the money supply in the Soviet economy". Soviet Studies. 37 (4): 494–504. doi:10.1080/09668138508411605. ISSN 0038-5859 – via JSTOR. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  2. ^ a b Wolverton Jr, Robert E. (2013-10-18). "Electronic Theses and Dissertations". doi:10.4324/9781315877655. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  3. ^ a b Ellman, Michael (1991-12). "Convertibility of the rouble". Cambridge Journal of Economics. 15 (4): 481–497. doi:10.1093/oxfordjournals.cje.a035185. ISSN 1464-3545. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  4. ^ a b c d e f g h Nakamura, Yasushi. (2017). Monetary policy in the Soviet Union : empirical analyses of monetary aspects of Soviet economic development. New York: Palgrave Macmillan US. ISBN 978-1-137-49418-4. OCLC 1000453406.
  5. ^ a b Pickersgill, Joyce E. (1968-09). "Hyperinflation and Monetary Reform in the Soviet Union, 1921-26". Journal of Political Economy. 76 (5): 1037–1048. doi:10.1086/259466. ISSN 0022-3808. {{cite journal}}: Check date values in: |date= (help)
  6. ^ a b c d Gregory, Paul R. (1982). Russian national income, 1885-1913. Cambridge [Cambridgeshire]: Cambridge University Press. ISBN 0-521-24382-3. OCLC 8034722.
  7. ^ a b Nenovsky, Nikolay; Rizopoulos, Yorgos (2005). "Measuring the Institutional Change of the Monetary Regime in a Political Economy Perspective". SSRN Electronic Journal. doi:10.2139/ssrn.665145. ISSN 1556-5068.